Next Article in Journal
On the Risk Spillover from Bitcoin to Altcoins: The Fear of Missing Out and Pump-and-Dump Scheme Effects
Next Article in Special Issue
Balance of Risks and the Anchoring of Consumer Expectations
Previous Article in Journal
Investment Decision and Firm Value: Moderating Effects of Corporate Social Responsibility and Profitability of Non-Financial Sector Companies on the Indonesia Stock Exchange
Previous Article in Special Issue
Global Spillovers of a Chinese Growth Slowdown
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Money Market Fund Reform: Dealing with the Fundamental Problem †

by
Huberto M. Ennis
1,*,
Jeffrey M. Lacker
2 and
John A. Weinberg
1
1
Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Richmond, VA 23219, USA
2
Independent Researcher, Richmond, VA 23220, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
The views expressed in this article are the authors’own and do not represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2023, 16(1), 42; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16010042
Submission received: 31 August 2022 / Revised: 3 January 2023 / Accepted: 4 January 2023 / Published: 9 January 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Central Banking and Financial Stability)

Abstract

:
After the events in March 2020, it became clear to U.S. policymakers that the 2014 reform of the money market funds (MMFs) industry had not successfully addressed the stability concerns associated with surges in withdrawals. In December 2021, the SEC proposed a new set of rules governing how money market funds can operate. A fundamental problem behind the instability of money market funds is the expectation that backstop liquidity support will be provided by the government in the event of financial distress, along with the government’s inability to credibly commit to not provide such support. This expectation dampens funds’ incentives to take steps ahead of time to mitigate the risk of sudden withdrawals. The newly proposed reforms are aimed at constraining withdrawals or penalizing them with “swing pricing”. We argue that if the commitment problem is the fundamental issue, it would be more useful to reduce expectations of ex-post support by requiring MMFs to have contractual commitments in place, ex-ante, for liquidity support from private parties.

1. Introduction

Short-term lending markets have been the focus of concerns about financial stability for much of the last two decades. In particular, turbulence among prime money market mutual funds has repeatedly prompted emergency responses from the government and the Fed, as well as proposals to reform these markets. In both 2008, during the global financial crisis, and in 2020, at the outset of the COVID pandemic, lending facilities were created to ease concerns about money funds’ ability to redeem shares.
As a response to the events of the financial crisis, in 2014 the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) implemented a series of reforms intended to address vulnerabilities in prime funds. Those reforms were not fully effective at containing the challenges faced during the pandemic. As a result, many market observers and policymakers renewed their calls for further reforms. In fact, Eric Rosengren, then president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, went as far as to say: “the money-market fund reform that occurred after the last crisis actually made things worse and so far there has not been a solution”. He went on to argue that prime money market funds needed to be “cleaned up” (Marte 2021).1
On December 2021, the SEC again introduced a new set of proposed reforms to the rules governing money market funds. The proposal abandons the liquidity fees and redemption gates that were introduced in 2014. In their place, the proposal intends to implement an alternative valuation method for institutional prime and tax-exempt money market funds: swing pricing. The basic idea is to require funds to adjust floating net asset values (NAVs) by a swing factor reflecting transaction costs that would result from selling proportional amounts (a “vertical slice”) of the various assets in the fund. Finally, the proposal increases the minimum liquidity requirements serving as buffers for money market funds in times of large, unexpected redemptions.
In this article, we argue that this series of reforms does not directly address the fundamental problem created by prime institutional money funds. We describe this problem as arising from the propensity of the government and/or the central bank to provide emergency credit and liquidity to these funds in times of stress. The expectation of such support weakens funds’ incentives to prepare for such contingencies themselves.
Accordingly, we propose an approach to regulation that directly addresses the way funds provide for contingent liquidity in times of stress. Money funds should be required to enter contractual commitments for the provision of lines of credit that can be used in periods of high investor outflows. These credit lines are a close substitute for the support that otherwise the government feels compelled to provide at those times. The contractual approach allows for explicit recognition of the costs of backup support, which creates the right ex-ante incentives for investors when allocating funding across various alternatives.
An important aspect of the proposed approach is who in the private sector should provide contingent support to prime money market funds. We think that in the current U.S. regulatory environment, large stress-tested banks are the most appropriate entities to provide such support. Significant progress has been made in regulating large, systemically important banks in the U.S., including robust capital and liquidity requirements and regular sophisticated stress testing procedures. We propose to leverage that progress, which has resulted in a more accurate recognition of the risks and costs associated with liquidity provision in times of financial instability (Acharya et al. 2016). Given that those banks recognize the relevant costs more accurately, they will price them in on their dealings with prime funds. Managers and investors of prime funds, then, will need to decide whether their investments are viable taking into account, explicitly, the need for contingent liquidity support, which before was indirectly and implicitly provided by taxpayers.
We do not intend to argue here that the alternative proposed eliminates all trade-offs and costs present in the business model of prime funds. We aim, instead, at creating a more appropriate allocation of costs which moves the economy closer to an ideal, efficient state. Some of the costs, however, seem inescapable if prime funds are to stay a meaningful segment of the money market. We think, though, that by further removing the taxpayer as the ultimate provider of liquidity, the resulting allocation of risk and costs will be closer to optimal.
The paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we briefly describe the main features of money market funds, how they originated, and their link to the commercial paper market. In Section 3, we discuss the reforms that were implemented after the 2008 financial crisis and the recent SEC proposals to amend those reforms. In Section 4, we describe what we view as a fundamental problem behind the instability of prime institutional funds and propose an approach to address that problem. We also discuss its merits relative to other components of the reform under consideration. Section 5 provides a brief conclusion.

2. Prime Money Market Funds in the U.S.

Money market mutual funds provide investors with a highly liquid form of savings that acts similarly to a bank account. Shareholders have ready access to their funds if needed for expenditures or other investments. The funds, in turn, hold exclusively short-term assets. Some funds (government MMFs) hold only assets issued by the US Treasury or government-sponsored entities. Others—the so-called prime funds—also hold short-term debt (commercial paper) of large corporations. A further distinction involves the investors in funds. “Retail” funds draw investments mainly from households and small businesses, while “institutional” funds are an important money management tool for financial institutions and other large corporations. Most of the regulatory attention in the U.S.—both in the 2014 reforms and in the current proposals—has been on prime institutional funds.
An important aspect of the development of money market funds is an accounting practice that under SEC rules is not available to other investment funds. Money market funds have historically been allowed to maintain a stable share price (typically one dollar), which enhances their usefulness to shareholders as a tool for money management. The most common method for maintaining a stable share price is the “amortized cost” method of valuation, under which individual securities are valued at acquisition cost.2 Interest earned is accrued uniformly over the remaining maturity of the security and is paid to shareholders in the form of additional shares. In exchange for being able to offer a stable net asset value, money market funds must satisfy restrictions on their portfolio—essentially requiring them to hold only relatively safe, short-term securities. Funds can further protect against losses by securing backstop support from a bank or another party, although this practice varies among funds.3
Money market funds became a significant part of the US financial system in the 1970s. After the first public issuance of shares in 1972, these funds saw their greatest early growth in periods when short-term market interest rates rose above the regulatory limits that capped the rates paid on bank deposits at the time (Reg. Q). Toward the end of the decade and into the 1980s, growth in money funds accelerated—again, during a period of high and volatile interest rates. From the start, then, it was apparent that the main purpose of these funds was as a substitute for bank deposits that could provide similar services to investors with fewer regulatory constraints (Cook and Duffield 1979). Money market funds continued to grow even after the repeal of Reg. Q interest rate caps because of cost differences that were—and to a large extent continue to be—attributable to differences in their regulatory treatment as compared to bank deposits.
The evolution of prime money market funds in the U.S., especially beginning in the late 1970s, is closely linked to developments in the commercial paper (CP) market (See Cook and Laroche 1994, chp. 9). Commercial paper is short-term debt issued by large firms—often, but not exclusively, bank holding companies and nonbank financial firms. As money funds attracted increasingly large sums of investors’ dollars away from bank accounts, they created a ready market for CP, and highly-rated issuers typically found borrowings in that market less costly than bank loans. Additionally, since CP is typically issued in large, indivisible offerings, money funds proved to be a convenient way for investors to make smaller, diversified investments in those instruments. At the beginning of 2020, commercial paper accounted for more than a quarter of the asset holdings of prime institutional funds (see Figure 1).
So, on both “end-user” sides of financial markets—ultimate savers and borrowers—CP and MMFs saw big increases in activity at a time when a combination of regulatory constraints and volatile market conditions hampered banks’ ability to provide a close substitute. During the 1980s and 1990s, the arbitrage of regulatory differences continued to drive the growth and evolution of these investment vehicles. The financing of financial and commercial firms through the issuance of commercial paper bought by money market funds exemplifies what has come to be known as “shadow banking” and can be thought of as a means of bypassing the banking system and its prudential regulation.

2.1. Fund Instability

Similar to many short-term financial arrangements, money funds can experience large demands for withdrawals if investors suddenly lose their appetite for this form of savings. In the case of prime funds, outflows may arise due to a broader loss of confidence in their holdings of commercial paper. The potential for sudden outflows is exacerbated if a money fund maintains a stable share value to make itself attractive to investors who are averse to taking losses on the balances they use, among other things, for cash management purposes (Ennis 2012). This motivated the SEC’s 2014 rule requiring prime institutional money funds to adopt floating NAVs.
When investors request redemption of their money fund shares, funds may first meet those requests by selling the assets that can be sold most easily. In an environment of falling confidence, risk premia rise, even on short-term debt such as CP, in which case the easy-to-sell assets are unlikely to be CP. Yet if redemptions continue, funds may ultimately have to liquidate their CP holdings, as well. If they do so at a loss, they may be unable to live up to their commitment to redeem shares at a stable value. That is, late-coming redeemers may suffer a loss on their shares. Knowing this, when there is a loss of confidence in the underlying assets, fund investors may rush to withdraw as quickly as possible, further increasing the stress on the fund (and the CP market).
At times of economic and financial stress, it is also the case that funding can shift quickly away from prime funds and into other money-market instruments, including government funds. Government funds, for example, cannot invest in commercial paper and, hence, such shifts can exacerbate any sudden withdrawal of available funding for the CP market.
In principle, other intermediaries that invest in CP directly, such as large banks, could respond by selling government securities to government funds and using the proceeds to make loans to CP issuers or to buy their commercial paper, effectively re-channeling the funding in the system back to where it is needed. When this does not happen and funding problems persist, those initial withdrawals from prime institutional funds can be interpreted as a reflection of a more general desire of sophisticated investors to reduce their exposure to commercial paper in response to deterioration in the creditworthiness of issuers (not just a flight from prime funds).
Indeed, investors’ desire to move out of prime money funds often reflects a broader move in the market to reduce exposure to the credit risk inherent in commercial paper. The contrasting behavior of balances in prime funds and government funds during periods of stress, as reflected in Figure 2, supports this interpretation. While prime funds lose investors, government funds gain them.
The bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers in September 2008 provides an example of how a sharp movement of investors away from commercial paper can affect the prime money funds industry. Investors in prime funds, who in normal times may not pay much attention to the particular assets held by the funds they hold, became understandably concerned about exposure to commercial paper and other obligations of Lehman. One particular fund, Reserve Primary, had a large enough exposure to Lehman paper that marking those assets down made them unable to maintain a stable one-dollar share value. Instead, it placed its share value at 97 cents, thereby, “breaking the buck”. Reserve Primary was particularly vulnerable, because, unlike many other funds, it did not have a large sponsor that could provide financial support in the event of such stresses.4

2.2. Emergency Liquidity Support

In principle, a fund can protect itself from liquidity-driven disruption by arranging a backup line of credit or other contingent support (see, for example, Brady et al. 2012; Parlatore 2016).5 Similarly, an issuer of CP can take similar actions to enhance the credit quality of their paper. Securing such protection, however, is costly and eats into the cost advantage that this shadow banking segment typically enjoys over traditional banking.
Implicit sponsor support for money funds has been common over the years. For example, a Moody’s Investor Service (2010) report identified 145 instances prior to August 2007 where a U.S. MMF would have broken the buck absence sponsor support; of these, only just one fund was liquated at less than 100 cents on the dollar. From August 2007 through December 2009, the report estimates that all but two of the 62 MMFs that were at risk of breaking the buck received sponsor support—the two exceptions being funds issued by Reserve Fund (Moody’s Investor Service 2010).

2.3. Lines of Credit from Banks

In principle, banks could also increase their provision of lines of credit to money market funds. Figure 3 shows the total dollar amount of unused lines of credit provided by U.S. domestic banks. These are off-balance sheet commitments. However, to gain some perspective on their size, in the last ten years, they are roughly about 40 percent of the value of total assets in these institutions. A large portion of these commitments, though, is accounted for by credit card lines of credit or are associated with residential real estate. Other unused commitments include those related to C&I lending and a very small portion of those other unused commitments are, in fact, lines of credit to financial institutions.
Another pattern worth noticing from Figure 3 is the significant drawdowns of unused commitments triggered by the 2008 financial turmoil. Clearly, lines of credit from banks played a role during that time, and to a lesser extent, while still noticeable, during the early months of the pandemic in 2020 (Li et al. 2020). Interestingly, even in those extreme events, a significant proportion of the existing lines of credit from banks remain unused (as is clear from the figure).

2.4. Implicit Public Support

With limited liquidity commitments from the private sector, turmoil among money funds commonly induces a public sector reaction and often leads to support for money funds and the CP market from the Fed, the Treasury, or both. When the Reserve Primary fund broke the buck in September 2008 and fears arose of a broad retreat from money funds, the Treasury stepped in to provide a temporary guarantee for all funds’ net assets values, and the Federal Reserve implemented lending programs to aid the CP market. When the onset of the pandemic in 2020 brought on a sharp increase in economic and financial uncertainty, the Fed again put in place credit facilities to support money market funds and commercial paper.6 The prompt intervention in this instance may help explain the relatively modest decline in prime institutional funds, as seen in Figure 2, while significant funding flowed into government funds as part of a broad flight to safety and liquidity.
This type of government reaction has a long history. The Federal Reserve was founded, in part, with the aim of providing backstop support to the CP market (See Wicker 2015, p. 63; Lacker 2013). More recently, after the Fed and the administration resisted entreaties to rescue the failing Penn Central railroad in 1970, their subsequent bankruptcy and commercial paper default roiled the CP market, making it difficult for other issuers to roll over maturing issues on accustomed terms. The Fed responded by encouraging banks to lend to enable their customers to pay off maturing commercial paper and signaling willingness to allow banks to borrow at the discount window to do so.7

3. Money Market Fund Reform in the U.S.

Rule 2a-7 of the SEC is the basic regulatory framework for MMFs in the U.S. Different types of MMFs are subject to different requirements. In particular, the rule distinguishes between government, tax-exempt, and prime MMFs; and between institutional and retail funds.
Before the 2014 reform, all MMFs were allowed to use the stable NAV approach for portfolio valuation, a method that disregards small variations in the value of assets. MMFs were thereby able to offer a stable share price that made them attractive for short-run money management purposes. Stable NAVs are partly behind the pernicious dynamics inducing a rush from investors to withdraw from funds during stress episodes. This is particularly relevant for institutional prime funds, where investors tend to be more responsive to valuation differentials. For this reason, the 2014 reform mandated that institutional prime funds stop using stable NAV and, instead, adjust their NAV based on current market-based values of the securities in their portfolios (see Ennis and Haltom 2014).8
While floating NAVs help avoid artificial incentives to withdraw from a fund in times of stress, timely market-based valuation of fund assets can be challenging. Many of the investments of money market funds trade in thin markets and can experience sharp fluctuations in price. In many cases, the prices are not readily available and fund managers have to impute an estimated price. These complications motivate the combination of floating NAVs with other preventive measures. In particular, the 2014 reform required funds to hold buffer stocks of liquid assets and allowed funds to impose redemption fees and gates when those liquidity buffers fell below certain thresholds.
That stable NAVs and weak liquidity provisioning was benefiting the riskier prime funds seems clear from the reaction to the 2014 reform reflected in Figure 2. Around the time when the 2014 reform took effect in October 2016, prime institutional money market funds quickly lost ground while, simultaneously, assets under management in government funds increased substantially.

The 2022 Re-Reform

The shocks to financial markets following the outbreak of the pandemic in March 2020 provided a test of the new regulatory configuration for MMFs. That experience suggests that the possibility of funds imposing fees and gates created incentives for investors to withdraw even sooner, before the relevant thresholds were crossed (Li et al. 2021). Furthermore, fund managers were reluctant to draw on their liquidity buffers to avoid the need to impose fees and gates; apparently breaching their liquidity requirements was seen as less desirable. In a nutshell, the liquidity-based fees and gates did not have their intended consequences.
The SEC’s 2022 reform proposal removes the ability of institutional prime money market funds to impose liquidity fees or redemption gates. The proposal also requires that institutional prime and tax-exempt MMFs use swing pricing as their asset valuation method in order to mitigate the dilution that may occur when investors redeem shares during periods of market stress.9
Under swing pricing, fund managers adjust the NAV by a swing factor that reflects transaction costs and liquidity demands attributable to redemptions. Concretely, the swing factor reflects spreads and transaction costs that would be associated with selling a vertical slice of the fund’s portfolio, even if the fund is initially only selling the most liquid assets to fulfill redemptions. Swing pricing, then, involves estimating the costs of liquidating a representative selection of the fund’s assets and allocating those costs over all shareholders, including those attempting to avoid them by redeeming early. As a result, implementation is likely to involve some significant challenges.
To complement these valuation enhancements, the proposed rule also includes an increase in the daily and weekly liquidity requirements for funds from 10 and 30 percent in the current rule to 25 and 50 percent, respectively. Liquidity requirements are a natural way to address systemic risks posed by MMFs. Illiquidity is at the root of the issues and dealing directly with it makes good sense. When MMFs are required to hold more liquidity, their business model suffers (Figure 2). Less liquid assets have higher returns and, since the funds are partly in the business of liquidity transformation (Ennis 2012), these restrictions over asset allocation limit their ability to perform that function. In fact, it seems likely that higher liquidity requirements will further reduce the size of the prime sector of the MMFs industry, possibly to a level where they no longer represent a policy concern.
A cautionary note is worth laying out at this point: There is a long-recognized tension created by liquidity requirements for financial intermediaries. Specifically, the moments when such requirements bind are likely to be the moments when the liquid holdings of the affected intermediaries are in greatest need. This can create a dilemma for both the firms and their regulators; the buffers are set aside for a purpose, but how does one decide it is time to make use of them rather than preserve them for some even more dire circumstance immediately ahead? This is a long-standing question with no simple answer.10

4. Government Lack-of-Commitment and a Path to Address It

At the heart of the challenge of crafting appropriate rules for prime money funds is the attractiveness, to both borrowers and lenders, of short-term debt. Investors who desire ready access to their funds will accept a lower yield in exchange for increased liquidity. The liquidity of longer-term debt instruments depends on how easy it is to sell before maturity. This can be difficult for bonds and other loans that do not trade in active secondary markets. The commercial paper provides liquidity in a more automatic fashion as well—simply let the note mature and receive the proceeds. From an investor’s point of view, liquidity is further enhanced by bundling commercial paper into mutual funds that are redeemable on demand. Borrowers, in turn, find the relatively low yields at which they can issue short-term debt attractive for obvious reasons. Short-term debt can also provide a sort of discipline for borrowers, if they need to repeatedly go to the market to roll their debt over (Diamond 1993, 2004). So, under normal conditions, the reliance of firms on short-term borrowing through money market funds appears to be a win-win.11
But the very feature that makes investors willing to hold short-term debt at low yields—the ability to leave easily—can create strains in abnormal times. If a loss of appetite for credit risk makes it hard for borrowers to roll over their short-term borrowings, then defaults on commercial paper become a possibility.

4.1. Government Liquidity Support

The prospect of widespread defaults has often prompted government or Fed officials to intervene. Furthermore, that history is bound to affect market participants’ beliefs about the likelihood of similar interventions in the future. Such expectations can have pernicious effects. First, they can make short-term debt even less expensive for borrowers, encouraging excessive issuance (Keister 2016). Additionally, expected implicit support dampens the extent to which the pricing of such debt differentiates between borrowers with different credit risk characteristics, offsetting (at least partially) the disciplinary benefits of short-term debt. More generally, it reduces the incentives of all participants to take costly actions to mitigate risk (Dam and Koetter 2012; Duchin and Sosyura 2014).
If investors believe that money funds benefit from support similar to that of large banking companies, the distortion of competition between these substitute forms of short-term investing is exacerbated—creating two alternatives with similar perceived government backing but very different regulatory frameworks. The result is likely to be the overuse of the less regulated alternative.

4.2. Lack of Commitment

Containing moral hazard effects is difficult. One approach is to simply refrain from intervening to protect investors and issuers (Goodfriend and Lacker 1999). This requires commitment on the part of the institutions prone to intervene, such as the Treasury or the Federal Reserve, but their ability to commit in this realm appears to be limited. Ex post, when markets are in turmoil and some participants find themselves in difficult straits, intervention can be hard to resist; an example of the Samaritan’s Dilemma (Buchanan 1975), where empathy at the moment conflicts with following through on a plan designed ex-ante to encourage self-reliance. Anticipation of a robust commitment to not intervene can provide the proper incentives for agents to modulate and reduce risk appropriately. When this is not possible, though, regulating arrangements ex-ante to try to replicate self-reliance may be the next-best alternative.
From this perspective, liquidity regulations for MMFs serve to constrain the moral hazard effects of expectations of official intervention in the event of a surge in the demand for withdrawals. Such expectations naturally intensified after the precedents set by the Treasury and the Fed in 2008 (but have been present, arguably at least since 1970, as we explained earlier). In the absence of any attempt to disavow future interventions (perhaps due to the limited ability of any one administration to speak credibly for future administrations or recognition of the Samaritan’s Dilemma), beefing up ex-ante regulations made sense.
This limited commitment framework further suggests that efforts to limit the incidence of withdrawal-induced distress in money funds by constraining those withdrawals or penalizing them with swing pricing will not directly address the fundamental issue. Instead of suppressing the incentives to withdraw early, they accelerate the effects. Instead of preventing the Samaritan’s Dilemma, they alter its timing. Official support is likely to remain a factor.12

4.3. A Role for Private Lines of Credit

A fundamental incentive distortion in the current environment comes, then, from the belief that backstop credit provision will be provided by the official sector. Yet line-of-credit facilities able to perform a similar function are readily available in the private sector, a point emphasized by Goodfriend and Lacker (1999). This suggests for regulators to focus on ensuring that MMFs have contractual commitments in place, in advance, for liquidity support from reliable private third parties, with the expectation that those are drawn on before any official support is forthcoming. The existence of such pre-arranged liquidity support is likely to enhance the ability of the official sector to resist intervening. It is important, of course, to include provisions that make those private commitments irrevocable, even if that increases their cost. More generally, the cost to a fund of obtaining contingent support should depend on the fund’s risk management practices. This, in turn, would provide appropriate independent incentives for funds to properly manage risk and possibly expand their liquidity buffers.
As we have argued here, the problem of MMF liquidity is closely related to the behavior of the CP market. Indeed, interventions to support MMF liquidity typically have been accompanied by interventions in the CP market. Some interventions aimed at supporting MMFs amount to taking the commercial paper off their hands on advantageous terms. The limited commitment perspective suggests that it might be most useful if the regulation of prime MMFs portfolios were to encourage holding commercial paper for which the issuer had contractual commitments of third-party liquidity support, such as a backup line of credit at a bank. Regulations that push MMF holdings toward such paper would incentivize issuers to obtain lines of credit and reduce the likelihood of falling CP prices inducing crises and intervention.
In short, reform should partly aim at replacing the public backup support of MMFs and commercial paper with pre-arranged backup support from other private investors, with all costs duly recognized in the ex-ante market transactions and pricing.

4.4. Private Providers of Contingent Liquidity

It is crucial for the arguments being advanced here that the private providers of liquidity are, in turn, not subject to the same problems faced by money funds. Under current conditions the U.S., large, systemically important banks are a natural candidate for this task. The regulatory framework for these banks has evolved in promising ways in the recent past—with the passing of the Dodd-Frank Act as a reaction to the 2008 global financial crisis. Capital and liquidity regulations are now quite robust. Importantly, capital regulations have been adapted to account explicitly for the on and off-balance sheet risks created by contingent obligations.13 Furthermore, these large banks are subject to periodic stress-tests that assess their ability to go through with all their commitments to creditors, with no expectation of any meaningful government support.
These enhanced regulations, of course, create additional costs for banks. Those extra costs are the counterpart of removing the need for taxpayers’ support in certain crucial contingencies. In turn, the extra cost should be properly reflected in the price of any contractual commitments between the banks and money funds. This resulting impact on the prices of contracts is, in fact, the way that appropriate incentives regarding liquidity allocation are transmitted to fund managers, and investors more generally.14
Leveraging the regulatory framework of large stress-tested domestic banks is also particularly important to minimize potential feedback loops between money funds and the banking system during a liquidity event. Between 70 and 80 percent of the CP held by MMFs (mainly, prime) is debt issued by financial firms (including banks). Similarly, close to 70 percent of U.S. commercial paper is issued by foreign borrowers, many of them branches of foreign banks. As a result, MMFs are significant providers of dollar funding to large foreign global banks. Furthermore, regulatory frameworks across jurisdictions differ on important details and can create anomalies in the way that foreign banks interact with the rest of the U.S. financial system (see, for example, Aldasoro et al. 2022). For these reasons, money funds should be required to secure lines of credit from banks that are not exposed to the commercial paper market. To increase robustness, the regulatory framework of large, stress-tested banks should recognize, and appropriately limit, the reliance on short-term funding from money market funds. While we realize that these are complex problems, the stress testing approach to large-bank regulation currently provides the best chance of successfully addressing them.

4.5. Parallels with Traditional Banking

The fact that as financial intermediaries MMFs serve a function that closely parallels the banking system suggests broader perspectives on the regulatory issues. First, a similar limited commitment problem has beset the banking system—the Fed, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), and other regulators have traditionally struggled with the temptation to rescue bank creditors. The deposit insurance system provides a legislative mandate for insured depositors, of course, but uninsured depositors and other creditors have often been rescued as well. This has led to the problem known as “too big to fail” (TBTF)—creditors believe support will be forthcoming, reliance on which leads to fragile funding arrangements, such as very short-term debt, that make nonintervention more damaging and thus increase the likelihood of intervention (Stern and Feldman 2004).
Counteracting the resulting incentive distortion through constraints on risk-taking is a costly endeavor. The Dodd-Frank Act meaningfully stiffened such constraints, but also included a provision that addresses the fundamental limited commitment problem in a fashion similar to our proposal for dealing with MMFs and commercial paper. Large, systemically important financial institutions are required to submit to regulators’ resolution plans—so-called “living wills”—that detail how they will be resolved in various failure scenarios. The Fed and the FDIC can reject plans they do not view as credible and can “impose more stringent capital, leverage, or liquidity requirements, or restrictions on the growth, activities, or operations of the company”.15 Plans include specification of sources of liquidity in the event of financial distress. Mandating ex-ante third-party liquidity support for MMFs would parallel the fruitful approach of living wills.

4.6. Capital Regulations and Other Considerations

An alternative approach to enhancing the stability of prime institutional funds, which has been proposed by some experts (Squam Lake Group 2010), is to create a capital requirement for them similar to bank capital regulation.16 This seems a natural route to consider, given the similarities between the financial intermediation done by the two types of entities. Yet creating a capital regime for money funds would be a nontrivial exercise. Similarly to all mutual funds, money funds have a simple capital structure—they issue ownership shares. The intent of a capital requirement is to have claims that are junior to the claims at risk of a run—shares, in the case of MMFs—in order to absorb losses before senior claimants. This would be especially complicated in the case of MMFs. Creating a junior class of loss-absorbing claimants would fundamentally alter the nature of shareholders’ claims; they would no longer be pro rata portfolio interests but would become debt-like instruments that are invariant across a range of asset values. Such a financial structure would reinforce the expectation of shareholders that they will be protected from losses and arguably only strengthen the pressure for ex-post support when shareholders losses loom.
It is worth emphasizing that concerns about instability in money funds—both in 2008 and 2020—have been almost exclusively focused on prime institutional funds. That is, the propensity of the largest and most sophisticated money managers to quickly move out of these funds and the commercial paper they hold has created the anxiety that has led to government support for these funds in the past. In the episodes that have prompted discussions of money fund reform, retail funds and government-only funds have generally remained quite stable (see Figure 2). So, while reform discussions have rightly focused on the prime institutional side of the market, one might be tempted to ask a broader question. If these funds repeatedly threaten instability that induces government intervention, have we misjudged the net social value of prime money funds? Perhaps money funds should be restricted to holding only government securities, as proposed by Anadu and Sanders (2021).

4.7. Regulatory Bypass and Stablecoins

The many parallels between MMFs and the banking system suggest a cautionary note. The evolution of banking regulation—particularly its increasing scope and rigor—has arguably contributed to the growth of intermediation arrangements such as MMFs that bypass the banking system. As banking regulations have become more elaborate and costly to implement, intermediation through the banking system has become more costly as well. Alternative financial arrangements with similar properties—such as flexible short-term investment and funding—thereby become more attractive. Those arrangements will be additionally attractive to the extent that they also benefit from an implicit commitment of official support, the same type of support which, ironically, motivated the stiffening of the regulation of the formal banking sector after various past crises.
While strengthening MMF regulations seems well advised, if stronger pre-commitment not to intervene is unavailable, policymakers should be aware that doing so is likely to enhance the incentive for further bypass, using arrangements beyond the banking system and MMFs. Just such an attempt seems to be underway, in the form of stablecoin cryptocurrencies: intermediation arrangements promising investors fixed nominal dollar payoffs, similar to the fixed NAV offered by MMFs. The backing of these arrangements is in some cases opaque (Yellen 2022), and some arrangements have broken the buck in dramatic fashion (Wong 2022).
Thus far, official intervention to rescue stablecoin investors has been absent. The regulatory world is at something of a crossroads, however. Officials have suggested that consumer protection and prudential regulation may be warranted, under the presumption that consumers are entitled to expect fixed payoff commitments to be satisfied with higher probability.17 Regulation aimed at ensuring those fixed payoffs might broadly resemble historic MMF and banking regulations, possibly restricting portfolio holdings or constraining redemption opportunities. A challenge with implementing such regulations lies in that they may create expectations of government financial support to ensure payouts of the established commitments. That path is fraught with difficulties, of course, as the banking and money funds history in the U.S. reflects. Alternatively, officials might want to advocate in favor of the principle of caveat emptor, warning consumers to be aware that these arrangements are outside of the familiar world of regulated financial intermediaries and that heightened prudence is warranted.

5. Conclusions

Ideally, we want financial dealings to be determined by the true economic costs and benefits of alternative instruments and contractual agreements. Yet when a set of financial arrangements benefit from an expectation that government resources will be deployed to rescue participants in the event of distress, that assessment is distorted. We can no longer trust private market participants to choose based solely on the true economic benefits and costs. Financial sectors benefitting from a perceived promise of support will overexpand. Moreover, they will underweight risks that may induce that support and overweight arrangements that make them vulnerable in the event of distress.
While we might be better off in a world in which the relevant authorities can credibly commit ex-ante to not providing support ex-post, that world may not be available to us at present. If so, then, MMFs should be required to have contractual commitments in place, in advance, for liquidity support from reliable private third parties in the event of financial distress. Such requirements would enhance the ability of the official sector to resist intervening and provide market-based incentives for MMFs to mitigate funding risks.
To be clear, we are not suggesting here to go back to the situation pre-2014 reforms. On the contrary, our suggestion is to complement those regulatory enhancements by introducing explicit private liquidity support, the pricing of which effectively acknowledges the cost that such support entails. Taxpayers should not be residual bearers of oversized liquidity risk taken by financial institutions partially responding to distorted incentives.
The approach we are advocating to address this limited commitment problem is, we believe, applicable more broadly, beyond just prime MMFs. The idea is to put in place mechanisms that reduce the perceived need for official intervention in the event of financial distress. We are guided by the nature of the typical official intervention, and we propose to ask MMFs to contract ex-ante with other private parties for the type of contingent liquidity support that would be provided by the government in the case of lost funding. In a different context, living wills work in a similar fashion; they specify private sector funding to take the place of government funding that would otherwise be provided if a bank finds itself in trouble, and in this way, should reduce the need for official support. We believe this general principle could be used productively to address many of the issues that arise from the government’s inability to commit to not intervening in stressed financial markets.

Author Contributions

All authors contributed to all aspects of the paper. Writing—original draft, H.M.E., J.M.L. and J.A.W. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

All data presented and discussed in this article are publicly available.

Acknowledgments

The authors thank the editor, Ricardo Correa, for comments and suggestions, as well as Sheila Bair, John Cochrane, Doug Diamond, Esther George, Bob Hetzel, Jeff Huther, Todd Keister, and Steve Williamson. All remaining errors are the responsibility of the authors.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Notes

1
See also the report of the President’s Working Group on Financial Markets from December 2020.
2
The 2014 reforms made this stable value accounting practice no longer available to prime institutional funds.
3
For a useful description and history of money market mutual funds, see Cook and Laroche (1994, chp. 12).
4
See Schmidt et al. (2016) for a detail study of cash flow dynamics in prime MMFs during September 2008.
5
Kacperczyk and Schnabl (2013) and La Spada (2018) study the role of sponsor reputation in driving risk decisions at MMFs.
6
7
The Fed notified member banks that “as they made loans to enable their customers to pay off maturing commercial paper and thus needed more reserves, the Federal Reserve discount window would be available”. Calomiris (1994, p. 41), quoting Treiber (1970).
8
A related approach is to allow a contractual share-reduction mechanism that deducts shares from investors’ accounts to accommodate any fall in the value of assets, without changing the par value of shares (White 2020).
9
10
Irving Fisher pointed out this problem in 1913, likening rigid bank reserve requirements to “a rule that on shipboard there must be at least 25 life preservers nailed to the deck, so that they will always be there”. See U.S. Congress. Senate. Committee on Banking and Currency. 1913. Hearings Before the Committee on Banking and Currency, United States Senate, Sixty-Third Congress, First Session, on H.R. 7837 (S. 2639). 3 vols. Washington, D.C. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/title/429#7309 (accessed on 3 October 2022).
11
The impact of the maturity of debt on the incentives of creditors to monitor the borrower is a complicated matter (Park 2000). Long-term debt may give creditors extra incentives to monitor the medium to long run performance of the borrower, for example.
12
The limited commitment perspective also has implications for the appropriate determination of swing prices. Intervention is likely needed to address the incentive of funds to understate the needed adjustments in share prices in anticipation of contingent support from the government. See Keister and Mitkov (2021) for formal treatment of this and related issues.
13
The importance for regulation of accounting properly for these contingent commitments is crucial. Arteta et al. (2020) document in detail the perils of having ABCP-sponsor banks be the providers of emergency liquidity when regulations do not appropriately account for the resulting off-balance sheet exposure, as was the case before the global financial crisis.
14
Implicit sponsor support is not uncommon in the money funds industry. There are, however, clear allocative benefits from making that support explicit and hence recognizing the costs that it entails. See Moody’s Investor Service (2010) for a discussion of this issue and the role that implicit support played prior to the 2008 financial crisis.
15
Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act. 12 U.S.C. § 5365(d)(5)(A). See also Jarque and Price (2014) for a detailed discussion of the role of living wills in bank regulation.
16
Our reading of the Squam Lake proposal is that they have in mind “buffering” more generally, not just capital buffers. Under this more general interpretation, our approach seems entirely consistent with the general principle advanced by the Squam Lake group. Relatedly, in their discussion of the 2022 SEC’s reform proposal, Cecchetti and Schoenholtz (2022) also argue in favor of a capital-like requirement in which money funds issue claims that are subordinate to ordinary shares.
17

References

  1. Acharya, Viral V., Deniz Anginer, and A. Joseph Warburton. 2016. The End of Market Discipline? Investor Expectations of Implicit Government Guarantees. New York: NYU Stern. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1961656 (accessed on 3 October 2022).
  2. Adrian, Tobias, Karin Kimbrough, and Dina Marchioni. 2011. The Federal Reserve’s Commercial Paper Funding Facility. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review May: 25–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Aldasoro, Iñaki, Torsten Ehlers, and Egemen Eren. 2022. Global banks, dollar funding, and regulation. Journal of International Economics 137: 103609. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Anadu, Kenechukwu, and Siobhan Sanders. 2021. Money Market Mutual Funds: Runs, Emergency Liquidity Facilities, and Potential Reforms. Supervisory Research and Analysis Notes No. 03. Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. [Google Scholar]
  5. Arteta, Carlos, Mark Carey, Ricardo Correa, and Jason Kotter. 2020. Revenge of the Steamroller: ABCP as a Window on Risk Choices. Review of Finance 24: 497–528. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Brady, Steffanie, Kenechukwu Anadu, and Nathaniel Cooper. 2012. The Stability of Prime Money Market Mutual Funds: Sponsor Support from 2007 to 2011. Supervisory Research and Analysis Working Paper No. 12-3. Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. [Google Scholar]
  7. Buchanan, James M. 1975. The Samaritan’s Dilemma. In Altruism, Morality, and Economic Theory. Edited by Edmund S. Phelps. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 71–86. Available online: http://www.jstor.org.proxy.library.vcu.edu/stable/10.7758/9781610446792.10 (accessed on 3 October 2022).
  8. Calomiris, Charles W. 1994. Is the Discount Window Necessary? A Penn-Central Perspective. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review June: 31–55. [Google Scholar]
  9. Cecchetti, Stephen, and Kermit L. Schoenholtz. 2022. SEC Money Market Fund Reform Proposals Fall Far Short, Again. Money, Banking and Financial Markets. January 28. Available online: https://www.moneyandbanking.com/commentary/2022/1/28/sec-money-market-fund-reform-proposals-fall-far-short-again (accessed on 3 October 2022).
  10. Cook, Timothy Q., and Jeremy G. Duffield. 1979. Money Market Mutual Funds: A Reaction to Government Regulations or a Lasting Financial Innovation? Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review July/August: 15–31. [Google Scholar]
  11. Cook, Timothy Q., and Robert K. Laroche, eds. 1994. Instruments of the Money Market. Richmond: Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. [Google Scholar]
  12. Dam, Lammertjan, and Michael Koetter. 2012. Bank bailouts and moral hazard: Evidence from Germany. Review of Financial Studies 25: 2343–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Diamond, Douglas W. 1993. Seniority and maturity of debt contracts. Journal of Financial Economics 33: 341–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Diamond, Douglas W. 2004. Presidential address, committing to commit: Short-term debt when enforcement is costly. Journal of Finance 59: 1447–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Duchin, Ran, and Denis Sosyura. 2014. Safer ratios, riskier portfolios: Banks’ response to government aid. Journal of Financial Economics 113: 1–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Ennis, Huberto M. 2012. Some theoretical considerations regarding net asset values for money market funds. FRB Economic Quarterly 98: 231–54. [Google Scholar]
  17. Ennis, Huberto M., and Renee Courtois Haltom. 2014. Reforming Money Market Mutual Funds: A Difficult Assignment. Richmond Fed Economic Brief. February. Available online: https://www.richmondfed.org/publications/research/economic_brief/2014/eb_14-02 (accessed on 3 October 2022).
  18. Goodfriend, Marvin, and Jeffrey M. Lacker. 1999. Limited Commitment and Central Bank Lending. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 85: 1–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  19. Jarque, Arantxa, and David A. Price. 2014. Living Wills: A Tool for Curbing “Too Big to Fail”. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Annual Report. pp. 5–17. Available online: https://www.richmondfed.org/-/media/RichmondFedOrg/publications/research/annual_report/2014/pdf/article.pdf (accessed on 3 October 2022).
  20. Kacperczyk, Marcin, and Philipp Schnabl. 2013. How safe are money market funds? Quarterly Journal of Economics 128: 1073–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Keister, Todd. 2016. Bailouts and Financial Fragility. Review of Economic Studies 83: 704–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Keister, Todd, and Yuliyan Mitkov. 2021. Allocating Losses: Bail-Ins, Bailouts and Bank Regulation. Discussion Paper No. 091, Collaborative Research Center Transregio 224. Bonn: Universities of Bonn and Mannheim, December. [Google Scholar]
  23. La Spada, Gabriele. 2018. Competition, reach for yield, and money market funds. Journal of Financial Economics 129: 87–110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Lacker, Jeffrey M. 2013. A Look Back at the History of the Federal Reserve. Newport News: Christopher Newport University, August, Available online: https://www.richmondfed.org/press_room/speeches/jeffrey_m_lacker/2013/lacker_speech_20130829 (accessed on 3 October 2022).
  25. Li, Lei, Philip E. Strahan, and Song Zhang. 2020. Banks as Lenders of First Resort: Evidence from the COVID-19 Crisis. Review of Corporate Finance Studies 9: 472–500. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Li, Lei, Yi Li, Marco Macchiavelli, and Xing Zhou. 2021. Liquidity restrictions, runs, and central bank interventions: Evidence from money market funds. Review of Financial Studies 34: 5402–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Marte, Jonnelle. 2021. Fed’s Rosengren Says Central Bank Needs to Keep Eye on Financial Stability Risks. Reuters.com. Available online: https://www.reuters.com/business/feds-rosengren-says-central-bank-needs-keep-eye-financial-stability-risks-2021-06-23/ (accessed on 3 October 2022).
  28. Moody’s Investor Service. 2010. Sponsor Support Key to Money Market Funds. Special Comment. Available online: https://www.alston.com/files/docs/Moody’s_report.pdf (accessed on 3 October 2022).
  29. Park, Cheol. 2000. Monitoring and structure of debt contracts. Journal of Finance 55: 2157–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Parlatore, Cecilia. 2016. Fragility in money market funds: Sponsor support and regulation. Journal of Financial Economics 121: 595–623. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. President’s Working Group on Financial Markets, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency. 2021. Report on Stablecoins. Available online: https://home.treasury.gov/system/files/136/StableCoinReport_Nov1_508.pdf (accessed on 3 October 2022).
  32. Schmidt, Lawrence, Allan Timmermann, and Russ Wermers. 2016. Runs on money market mutual funds. American Economic Review 106: 2625–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Squam Lake Group. 2010. The Squam Lake Report: Fixing the Financial Sector. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
  34. Stern, Gary H., and Ron J. Feldman. 2004. Too Big to Fail: The Hazards of Bank Bailouts. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press. [Google Scholar]
  35. Treiber, William F. 1970. Problems of Financial Community Under Constant Scrutiny. American Banker, October 13, 16. [Google Scholar]
  36. U.S. Department of the Treasury. 2022. Crypto-Assets: Implications for Consumers, Investors, and Businesses. Available online: https://home.treasury.gov/system/files/136/CryptoAsset_EO5.pdf (accessed on 30 November 2022).
  37. White, Lawrence H. 2020. Recent Trouble Among Money-Market Mutual Funds, and the Way Forward. Alt-M Blog, March. [Google Scholar]
  38. Wicker, Elmus. 2015. The Great Debate on Banking: Reform Nelson Aldrich and the Origins of the Fed. Columbus: Ohio State University Press. [Google Scholar]
  39. Wong, Russell. 2022. Why Stablecoins Fail: An Economist’s Post-Mortem on Terra. Richmond Fed Economic Brief. July. Available online: https://www.richmondfed.org/publications/research/economic_brief/2022/eb_22-24 (accessed on 30 November 2022).
  40. Yellen, Janet. 2022. On Digital Assets. Speech at American University’s Kogod School of Business Center for Innovation, Washington, DC, USA, April 7. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. U.S. Prime Money Market Funds’ Investments by Instrument (as a proportion of assets under management). Source: Federal Reserve. Definitions: ABCP is asset-backed commercial paper, Unsec CP is unsecured commercial paper, CDs are certificates of deposit; repo are repurchase agreements; T. repo are Treasuries repurchase agreements.
Figure 1. U.S. Prime Money Market Funds’ Investments by Instrument (as a proportion of assets under management). Source: Federal Reserve. Definitions: ABCP is asset-backed commercial paper, Unsec CP is unsecured commercial paper, CDs are certificates of deposit; repo are repurchase agreements; T. repo are Treasuries repurchase agreements.
Jrfm 16 00042 g001
Figure 2. U.S. Money Market Funds Assets under Management (USD Billions). Source: Federal Reserve.
Figure 2. U.S. Money Market Funds Assets under Management (USD Billions). Source: Federal Reserve.
Jrfm 16 00042 g002
Figure 3. Unused Commitments for U.S.-Chartered Depository Institutions (USD Billions). Source: Federal Reserve. Notes: “Other unused commitments: to financial institutions” is part of “other unused commitments”. The components of “other unused commitments” are only available starting in 2010.
Figure 3. Unused Commitments for U.S.-Chartered Depository Institutions (USD Billions). Source: Federal Reserve. Notes: “Other unused commitments: to financial institutions” is part of “other unused commitments”. The components of “other unused commitments” are only available starting in 2010.
Jrfm 16 00042 g003
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Ennis, H.M.; Lacker, J.M.; Weinberg, J.A. Money Market Fund Reform: Dealing with the Fundamental Problem. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2023, 16, 42. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16010042

AMA Style

Ennis HM, Lacker JM, Weinberg JA. Money Market Fund Reform: Dealing with the Fundamental Problem. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2023; 16(1):42. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16010042

Chicago/Turabian Style

Ennis, Huberto M., Jeffrey M. Lacker, and John A. Weinberg. 2023. "Money Market Fund Reform: Dealing with the Fundamental Problem" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 16, no. 1: 42. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16010042

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop