Next Article in Journal
Multi-Objective Optimization of an Elastic Rod with Viscous Termination
Next Article in Special Issue
Global Stability of Multi-Strain SEIR Epidemic Model with Vaccination Strategy
Previous Article in Journal
A New Material Model for Agglomerated Cork
Previous Article in Special Issue
HIV Dynamics with a Trilinear Antibody Growth Function and Saturated Infection Rate
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Stochastic Capital–Labor Lévy Jump Model with the Precariat Labor Force

Laboratory of Systems Modelization and Analysis for Decision Support, National School of Applied Sciences, Hassan First University of Settat, Berrechid 26100, Morocco
Math. Comput. Appl. 2022, 27(6), 93; https://doi.org/10.3390/mca27060093
Submission received: 14 October 2022 / Revised: 4 November 2022 / Accepted: 9 November 2022 / Published: 10 November 2022
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Ghana Numerical Analysis Day)

Abstract

:
In this work, we study a capital–labor model by considering the interaction between the new proposed and the confirmed free jobs, the precariat labor force, and the mature labor force by introducing Brownian motion and Lévy noise. Moreover, we illustrate the well-posedness of the solution. In addition, we establish the conditions of the extinction of both the free jobs and labor force; subsequently, we prove the persistence of only the free jobs, and we also show the conditions of the persistence of both the free jobs and labor force. Finally, we validate our theoretical finding by numerical simulation by building a new stochastic Runge–Kutta method.

1. Introduction

It is widely believed that the world’s income inequality has increased over past decades [1,2]. Many different theories seek to explain this phenomenon, such as the evolution of the shares of capital–labor [3], changing returns to human capital and skill-driven technological change [4,5,6,7], and market concentration resulting from corporate market power and oligopoly [8,9]. Other work has concentrated more on the relationships between employers and workers and changing institutions [1,10,11,12,13]. Still others have focused on the potential changes to the economic class structure and the importance of economic class [1,14,15,16]. The evolution of institutions and the evolution of class structure can be seen as related rather than concurrent phenomena. The relation of workers to their work focused on a transformation of an old working class into a new working class, the precariat. The precariat is different from the old working class by its instability; they are a source of flexible labor, dependent on money wages due to a loss of labor rights and a weakened ability to access the welfare state, and without long-term stable employment [15,17,18]. In [19], Greenstein showed how the precarious class diagram can be applied empirically to data for the US labor force to help understand the changing nature of working-class jobs and who occupies those jobs. Moreover, he also explored to what extent this class structure can explain rising income inequality in the United States. Wage employment has also been on a downward trend in rich economies [20]. In [21], Breman et al. suggest that a trend of casualization in the rich world is inevitable due to a stagnant economy, a dismantled welfare state, and the decline of labor unions, among other causes.
The mathematical modeling of dynamics of capital–labor is an important tool to understand and study the behavior of interaction between free jobs and the labor force; for example, in [22], Riad et al. gave a deterministic model with logistic growth rate to established the condition of the existence and the stability of the equilibrium. More recently, in a stochastic study of the interaction between the free jobs and the labor force by introducing the white noise [23], also they found some conditions of the persistence and the extinction of labor force.
Motivated by the previous studies, we proposed the following capital–labor model with a Lévy jump:
d u 1 ( t ) = δ u 2 ( t ) μ 1 u 1 ( t ) κ u 1 ( t ) d t + σ 1 u 1 ( t ) d W 1 ( t ) + U Π 1 ( u ) u 1 ( t ) N ( d t , d u ) , d u 2 ( t ) = κ u 1 ( t ) μ 2 u 2 ( t ) τ 1 u 2 2 ( t ) c u 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 d t + σ 2 u 2 ( t ) d W 2 ( t ) + U Π 2 ( u ) u 2 ( t ) N ( d t , d u ) , d v 1 ( t ) = c u 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 μ 3 v 1 ( t ) θ v 1 ( t ) d t + σ 3 v 1 ( t ) d W 3 ( t ) + U Π 3 ( u ) v 1 ( t ) N ( d t , d u ) , d v 2 ( t ) = θ v 1 ( t ) μ 4 v 2 ( t ) τ 2 v 2 2 ( t ) d t + σ 4 v 2 ( t ) d W 4 ( t ) + U Π 4 ( u ) v 2 ( t ) N ( d t , d u ) ,
where u 1 represents the new proposed jobs, u 2 the confirmed free jobs, v 1 the labor force in the training period and the precariat individuals (or the prematuration labor force), v 2 the maturation labor force, δ is the rate of new proposed free jobs, κ is the rate of confirmed free jobs, μ 1 is the loss rate of new free jobs, μ 2 is the loss rate of confirmed free jobs, τ 1 is the competition rate between confirmed free jobs, θ is the maturity rate of the immature labor force, μ 3 is the loss rate of the jobs of the prematuration labor force, μ 4 is the loss rate of the jobs of the mature labor force, τ 2 is the competition rate between a mature labor force, c is the rate that a labor force hunts a free job, and α is the effects of the recruitment rate on free jobs.
On a complete probability space Ω , F , ( F t ) t 0 , P , we define W i ( t ) as the standard Brownian motion, with the filtration ( F t ) t 0 satisfying the classical conditions. Note that u 1 ( t ) , u 2 ( t ) , v 1 ( t ) , and v 2 ( t ) , respectively, are the left limits of u 1 ( t ) , u 2 ( t ) , v 1 ( t ) , and v 2 ( t ) ; N ( d t , d u ) = N ( d t , d u ) ν ( d u ) d t , with N ( d t , d u ) is a Poisson count measurement with the stationary compensator ν ( d u ) d t , and on a measurable subset U of the positive half-line we define ν under the assumptions ν ( U ) < and the intensity of W i ( t ) is σ i , q i ( u ) represents the jump intensities for i = 1 , , 4 .
The organization of our study as follows. In the Section 2, we prove the well-posedness of the solution of the model (1). The extinction of both free jobs and the labor force is shown in Section 3. In Section 4, we show the persistence of free jobs and the extinction of the labor force. The stochastic persistence of both the free jobs and the labor force is studied in Section 5. Section 6 gives some numerical results in order to validate our theoretical findings.

2. Properties of the Solution

2.1. The Global Positive Solution Existence and Uniqueness

In this subsection, we will prove that the solution of the model in (1) exists and is unique.
Theorem 1. 
If the initial value u 1 ( 0 ) , u 2 ( 0 ) , v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 ) R + 4 , then the model (1) admits a unique global solution u 1 ( t ) , u 2 ( t ) , v 1 ( t ) , v 2 ( t ) R + 4 for t 0 a . s .
Proof. 
The diffusion and the drift are locally Lipschitz, so for any initial data u 1 ( 0 ) , u 2 ( 0 ) , v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 ) R + 4 , for t [ 0 , τ e ) the system (1) admits a unique local solution u 1 ( t ) , u 2 ( t ) , v 1 ( t ) , v 2 ( t ) , where τ e represents the explosion time.
For the purpose of proving that this solution is global, we must show that τ e = a . s . First, we demonstrate that for a finite time, u 1 ( t ) , u 2 ( t ) , v 1 ( t ) , v 2 ( t ) do not tend to infinity. Let a sufficiently large number n 0 > 0 , such that u 1 ( 0 ) , u 2 ( 0 ) , v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 ) belong to the interval [ 1 n 0 , n 0 ] . For each integer n n 0 , the stopping time is defined as follows:
τ n = inf { t [ 0 , τ e ) / u 1 ( t ) 1 n , n or u 2 ( t ) 1 n , n or v 1 ( t ) 1 n , n or v 2 ( t ) 1 n , n } ,
with τ n , when n , is an increasing number. Let τ = lim n τ n , where τ τ e a . s . If we prove that τ = then τ e = and u 1 ( t ) , u 2 ( t ) , v 1 ( t ) , v 2 ( t ) R + 4 a . s . Suppose the contrary case is verified, i.e., τ < a . s . Therefore, there are two constants T > 0 and 0 < ϵ < 1 such that P ( τ T ) ϵ .
Now, consider the functional
V u 1 ( t ) , u 2 ( t ) , v 1 ( t ) , v 2 ( t ) = i = 1 i = 2 u i 1 log u i + i = 1 i = 2 v i 1 log v i ,
Using ItÔ’s formula, we obtain
d V x , y , z = L V d t + i = 1 i = 2 σ i ( u i 1 ) d W i + i = 1 i = 2 σ i + 2 ( v i 1 ) d W 2 + σ 3 ( z 1 ) d W i + 2 + U Π 1 ( u ) u 1 log 1 + Π 1 ( u ) N ( d t , d u ) + U Π 2 ( u ) u 2 log 1 + Π 2 ( u ) N ( d t , d u ) + U Π 3 ( u ) v 1 log 1 + Π 3 ( u ) N ( d t , d u ) + U Π 4 ( u ) v 2 log 1 + Π 4 ( u ) N ( d t , d u ) ,
with
L V = 1 1 u 1 δ u 2 ( t ) μ 1 u 1 ( t ) κ u 1 ( t ) + σ 1 2 2 + 1 1 u 2 κ u 1 ( t ) μ 2 u 2 ( t ) τ 1 u 2 2 ( t ) c u 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 + σ 2 2 2 + 1 1 v 1 c u 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 μ 3 v 1 ( t ) θ v 1 ( t ) + σ 3 2 2 + 1 1 v 2 θ v 1 ( t ) μ 4 v 2 ( t ) τ 2 v 2 2 ( t ) + σ 4 2 2 + U Π 1 ( u ) log 1 + Π 1 ( u ) ν ( d u ) + U Π 2 ( u ) log 1 + Π 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) + U Π 3 ( u ) log 1 + Π 3 ( u ) ν ( d u ) + U Π 4 ( u ) log 1 + Π 4 ( u ) ν ( d u ) ,
then, we have
L V τ 1 u 2 2 ( t ) + ( δ + τ 1 + c ) u 2 + p + μ 1 + μ 2 + μ 3 + μ 4 τ 2 v 2 2 + ( c + τ 2 ) v 2 + 4 C L V ( δ + τ 1 + c ) 2 4 τ 1 + κ + μ 1 + μ 2 + μ 3 + μ 4 + ( τ 2 + c ) 2 4 τ 2 + 4 C L V C ,
with
C = max { U Π 1 ( u ) log 1 + Π 1 ( u ) ν ( d u ) , U Π 2 ( u ) log 1 + Π 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) , U Π 3 ( u ) log 1 + Π 3 ( u ) ν ( d u ) , U Π 4 ( u ) log 1 + Π 4 ( u ) ν ( d u ) } .
and
C = ( δ + τ 1 + c ) 2 4 τ 1 + κ + μ 1 + μ 2 + μ 3 + μ 4 + ( τ 2 + c ) 2 4 τ 2 + 4 C .
Then, Equation (2) implies that
0 E V u 1 ( τ n T ) , u 2 ( τ n T ) , v 1 ( τ n T ) , v 2 ( τ n T ) V u 1 ( 0 ) , u 2 ( 0 ) , v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 ) + C T .
For any h > 0 , we define
H ( h ) = inf { V ( x 1 , x 2 , x 3 , x 4 ) , x i h or x i 1 h , i = 1 , , 4 } ,
where x 1 = u 1 , x 2 = u 2 , x 3 = v 1 and x 4 = v 2 . Therefore, we obtain
lim h H ( h ) = .
Then, letting n , we find
> V u 1 ( 0 ) , u 2 ( 0 ) , v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 ) + C T = ,
which is a contradiction with the previous assumption. Therefore τ = . Moreover, our model admits a unique global solution ( u 1 ( t ) , u 2 ( t ) , v 1 ( t ) , v 2 ( t ) ) a.s. □

2.2. Stochastic Ultimately Boundedness

In the previous subsection, we have proven that the solution of the model (1) is positive. Nevertheless, this non explosion property in a dynamical system is often insufficient. Therefore, the stochastic ultimate boundedness is more desired.
Theorem 2. 
If we have the following conditions
σ 1 2 + U Π 1 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 1 2 κ + 1 < 0 , σ 2 2 + U Π 2 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 2 + 1 < 0 , σ 3 2 + U Π 3 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 3 2 θ + 1 < 0 , σ 4 2 + U Π 4 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 4 + 1 < 0 .
Then, for an initial data u 1 ( 0 ) , u 2 ( 0 ) , v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 ) R + 4 , the solution of model (1) is stochastic ultimately bounded.
Proof. 
Define the following function:
V u 1 , u 2 , v 1 , v 2 = i = 1 i = 2 u i 2 + i = 1 i = 2 v i 2
By ItÔ’s formula, we get
d V u 1 , u 2 , v 1 , v 2 = L V d t + 2 σ 1 2 u 1 2 d W 1 ( t ) + 2 σ 2 2 u 2 2 d W 2 ( t ) + 2 σ 3 2 v 1 2 d W 3 ( t ) + 2 σ 4 2 v 2 2 d W 4 ( t )
+ U ( 2 Π 1 ( u ) + Π 1 2 ( u ) ) u 1 2 N ( d t , d u ) + U ( 2 Π 2 ( u ) + Π 2 2 ( u ) ) u 2 2 N ( d t , d u )
+ U ( 2 Π 3 ( u ) + Π 3 2 ( u ) ) v 1 2 N ( d t , d u ) + U ( 2 Π 4 ( u ) + Π 4 2 ( u ) ) v 2 2 N ( d t , d u ) ,
with
L V = 2 u 1 δ u 2 μ 1 u 1 κ u 1 + 2 u 2 κ u 1 μ 2 u 2 τ 1 u 2 2 c u 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 + 2 v 1 c u 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 μ 3 v 1 θ v 1 + 2 v 2 θ v 1 μ 4 v 2 τ 2 v 2 2 + σ 1 u 1 2 + σ 2 u 2 2 + σ 3 v 1 2 + σ 4 v 2 2 + U Π 1 2 u 1 2 ν ( d u ) + U Π 2 2 u 2 2 ν ( d u ) + U Π 3 2 v 1 2 ν ( d u ) + U Π 4 2 v 2 2 ν ( d u ) ,
so,
L V = 2 τ 1 u 2 3 2 τ 2 v 2 3 + σ 1 2 + U Π 1 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 1 2 κ + 1 u 1 2 + σ 2 2 + U Π 2 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 2 + 1 u 2 2 + σ 3 2 + U Π 3 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 3 2 θ + 1 v 1 2 + σ 4 2 + U Π 4 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 4 + 1 v 1 2 + 2 ( a + p ) u 1 u 2 + 2 θ v 1 v 2 + 2 c u 2 v 1 v 2 1 + α u 2 2 c u 2 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 u 1 2 + u 2 2 + v 1 2 + v 2 2 ,
then,
L V σ 1 2 + U Π 1 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 1 2 κ + 1 u 1 2 + σ 2 2 + U Π 2 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 2 + 1 u 2 2 + σ 3 2 + U Π 3 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 3 2 θ + 1 v 1 2 + σ 4 2 + U Π 4 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 4 + 1 v 2 2 + 2 ( a + p ) u 1 u 2 + 2 ( h + c ) v 1 v 2 u 1 2 + u 2 2 + v 1 2 + v 2 2 ,
we denote
f ( u 1 , u 2 , v 1 , v 2 ) = σ 1 2 + U Π 1 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 1 2 κ + 1 u 1 2 + σ 2 2 + U Π 2 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 2 + 1 u 2 2 + σ 3 2 + U Π 3 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 3 2 θ + 1 v 1 2 + σ 4 2 + U Π 4 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 4 + 1 v 2 2 + 2 ( a + p ) u 1 u 2 + 2 ( h + c ) v 1 v 2 .
Since we have condition (3), we obtain that the function f ( u 1 , u 2 , v 1 , v 2 ) admits an upper bound. We put
M = sup ( u 1 , u 2 , v 1 , v 2 ) R + 4 f ( u 1 , u 2 , v 1 , v 2 ) and L = M + 1 .
Since f ( 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 ) = 0 , then L > 0 . Formula (4) implies that
d V L ( u 1 2 + u 2 2 + v 1 2 + v 2 2 ) d t + 2 σ 1 2 u 1 2 d W 1 ( t ) + 2 σ 2 2 u 2 2 d W 2 ( t ) + 2 σ 3 2 v 1 2 d W 3 ( t ) + 2 σ 4 2 v 2 2 d W 4 ( t ) + U ( 2 Π 1 ( u ) + Π 1 2 ( u ) ) u 1 2 N ( d t , d u ) + U ( 2 Π 2 ( u ) + Π 2 2 ( u ) ) u 2 2 N ( d t , d u ) + U ( 2 Π 3 ( u ) + Π 3 2 ( u ) ) v 1 2 N ( d t , d u ) + U ( 2 Π 4 ( u ) + Π 4 2 ( u ) ) v 2 2 N ( d t , d u ) ,
therefore, we use ItÔ’s formula to get
d e t V = e t V d t + e t d V N e t d t + 2 σ 1 2 u 1 2 d W 1 ( t ) + 2 σ 2 2 u 2 2 d W 2 ( t ) + 2 σ 3 2 v 1 2 d W 3 ( t ) + 2 σ 2 2 v 2 2 d W 4 ( t ) + U ( 2 Π 1 ( u ) + Π 1 2 ( u ) ) u 1 2 N ( d t , d u ) + U ( 2 Π 2 ( u ) + Π 2 2 ( u ) ) u 2 2 N ( d t , d u ) + U ( 2 Π 3 ( u ) + Π 3 2 ( u ) ) v 1 2 N ( d t , d u ) + U ( 2 Π 4 ( u ) + Π 4 2 ( u ) ) v 2 2 N ( d t , d u ) ,
then,
e t E [ V ( X ) ] V u 1 ( 0 ) , u 2 ( 0 ) , v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 ) + L e t L .
with X = ( u 1 , u 2 , v 1 , v 2 ) .
Therefore
lim sup t E [ V ( X ) ] L .
We know that V ( X ) = i = 1 i = 2 u i 2 + i = 1 i = 2 v i 2 , then
lim sup t E [ | ( X ) | 2 ] L .
By Chebyshev’s inequality, for any η > 0 , let B = L η . we get
P | ( X ) | > B E [ | ( X ) | 2 ] B 2 L L η = η .

3. Stochastic Extinction of Free Jobs and the Labor Force

Now, we prove that free jobs and the labor force becomes extinct with probability one.
We put
c 1 = 2 μ 1 + p σ 1 2 U Π 1 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) , c 2 = 2 μ 2 σ 2 2 U Π 2 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) δ κ , c 3 = 2 μ 3 + h σ 3 2 U Π 3 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) c α , c 4 = 2 μ 4 σ 4 2 U Π 4 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) c α θ .
Theorem 3. 
For any initial data u 1 ( 0 ) , u 2 ( 0 ) , v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 ) R + 4 , we obtain
lim sup t 1 t E + u 1 2 + u 2 2 + v 1 2 + v 2 2 L 1 ϱ ,
when, min { c 1 , c 2 , c 3 , c 4 } > 0 .
Proof. 
We define
F u 1 , u 2 , v 1 , v 2 = i = 1 i = 2 u i 2 + i = 1 i = 2 v i 2 + u 1 + u 2 + v 1 ,
By ItÔ’s formula, we get
d F = L F d t + σ 1 2 ( 2 u 1 2 + u 1 ) d W 1 ( t ) + σ 2 2 ( 2 u 2 2 + u 2 ) d W 2 ( t ) + σ 3 2 ( 2 v 1 2 + v 1 ) d W 3 ( t ) + 2 σ 4 2 v 2 2 d W 4 ( t ) + U ( 2 Π 1 ( u ) + Π 1 2 ( u ) ) u 1 2 + Π 1 u 1 N ( d t , d u ) + U ( 2 Π 2 ( u ) + Π 2 2 ( u ) ) u 2 2 + Π 2 u 2 N ( d t , d u ) + U ( 2 Π 3 ( u ) + Π 3 2 ( u ) ) v 1 2 + Π 3 v 1 N ( d t , d u ) + U ( 2 Π 4 ( u ) + Π 4 2 ( u ) ) v 2 2 N ( d t , d u ) ,
where
L F = 2 u 1 δ u 2 μ 1 u 1 κ u 1 + 2 u 2 κ u 1 μ 2 u 2 τ 1 u 2 2 c u 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 + 2 v 1 c u 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 μ 3 v 1 h v 1 + 2 v 2 θ v 1 μ 4 v 2 τ 2 v 2 2 + δ u 2 τ 1 u 2 2 μ 1 u 1 μ 2 u 2 ( μ 3 + θ ) v 1 + σ 1 u 1 2 + σ 2 u 2 2 + σ 3 v 1 2 + σ 4 v 2 2 + U Π 1 2 u 1 2 ν ( d u ) + U Π 2 2 u 2 2 ν ( d u ) + U Π 3 2 v 1 2 ν ( d u ) + U Π 4 2 v 2 2 ν ( d u ) ,
so,
L F = 2 τ 1 u 2 3 2 τ 2 v 2 3 + σ 1 2 + U Π 1 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 1 2 κ u 1 2 + σ 2 2 + U Π 2 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 2 u 2 2 + σ 3 2 + U Π 3 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 3 2 θ v 1 2 + σ 4 2 + U Π 4 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 4 v 1 2 + 2 ( δ + κ ) u 1 u 2 + 2 θ v 1 v 2 ( μ 3 + θ ) v 1 + 2 c u 2 v 1 v 2 1 + α u 2 2 c u 2 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 + δ u 2 τ 1 u 2 2 μ 1 u 1 μ 2 u 2 ,
then,
L F σ 1 2 + U Π 1 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 1 2 κ u 1 2 + σ 2 2 + U Π 2 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 2 u 2 2 + σ 3 2 + U Π 3 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 3 2 θ v 1 2 + σ 4 2 + U Π 4 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 4 v 1 2 + ( δ + κ ) u 1 2 + ( δ + κ ) u 2 2 + θ v 1 2 + θ v 2 2 + c α v 1 2 + c α v 2 2 + a 4 τ 1 ,
this fact implies that,
L F σ 1 2 + U Π 1 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 1 κ u 1 2 + σ 2 2 + U Π 2 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) + δ + κ 2 μ 2 u 2 2 + σ 3 2 + U Π 3 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) + c α 2 μ 3 θ v 1 2 + σ 4 2 + U Π 4 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) + c α + θ 2 μ 4 v 1 2 + L 1 ,
with L 1 = δ 4 τ 1 . Then
L F c 1 u 1 2 c 2 u 2 2 c 3 v 1 2 c 4 v 2 2 + L 1 ,
Equation (8) implies that
0 E F u 1 ( t ) , u 2 ( t ) , v 1 ( t ) , v 2 ( t ) E 0 t c 1 u 1 2 c 2 u 2 2 c 3 v 1 2 c 4 v 2 2 + L 1 t + F u 1 ( 0 ) , u 2 ( 0 ) , v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 )
let ϱ = min { c 1 , c 2 , c 3 , c 4 } , so
E 0 t u 1 2 + u 2 2 + v 1 2 + v 2 2 L 1 ϱ t + u 1 ( 0 ) , u 2 ( 0 ) , v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 ) ϱ .
Then,
lim sup t 1 t E 0 t u 1 2 + u 2 2 + v 1 2 + v 2 2 L 1 ϱ .

4. Stochastic Extinction of Capital Labor

In this section, we established some conditions to proving the extinction of the labor force with probability one.
First, we denote
c 3 = 2 μ 3 + θ σ 3 2 U Π 3 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) c α , c 4 = 2 μ 4 τ 2 σ 4 2 U Π 4 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) c α h , N 1 = i = 1 i = 2 σ i 2 2 + 2 N 1 ( μ 1 + κ + μ 2 ) ,
where
N 1 = min U Π 1 ( u ) ln ( 1 + Π 1 ( u ) ) , U Π 2 ( u ) ln ( 1 + Π 2 ( u ) ) .
Theorem 4. 
For any initial data u 1 ( 0 ) , u 2 ( 0 ) , v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 ) R + 4 , when min { c 3 , l c 4 , N 1 } > 0 and v 2 u 1 α p c , we obtain
lim sup t 1 t E v 1 2 + v 2 2 L 2 ϱ 1
then, all the prey persistence in the mean. Moreover, we have
1 t 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η N 1 τ 1 a . s . 1 t 0 t u 1 ( η ) d η δ N 1 τ 1 ( μ 1 + κ ) a . s .
Proof. 
We consider
F 1 v 1 , v 2 = i = 1 i = 2 v i 2 + v 2 ,
by ItÔ’s formula, we obtain
d F 1 v 1 , v 2 = L F 1 d t + σ 3 2 ( 2 v 1 2 + v 1 ) d W 3 ( t ) + 2 σ 4 2 v 2 2 d W 4 ( t ) + U ( 2 Π 3 ( u ) + Π 3 2 ( u ) ) v 1 2 + Π 3 v 1 N ( d t , d u ) + U ( 2 Π 4 ( u ) + Π 4 2 ( u ) ) v 2 2 N ( d t , d u ) ,
with
L F 1 = 2 v 1 c u 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 μ 3 v 1 θ v 1 + 2 v 2 θ v 1 μ 4 v 2 τ 2 v 2 2 + c u 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 ( μ 3 + h ) v 2 + σ 3 v 1 2 + σ 4 v 2 2 + U Π 3 2 v 1 2 ν ( d u ) + U Π 4 2 v 2 2 ν ( d u ) ,
so,
L F 1 = 2 τ 2 v 2 3 + σ 3 2 + U Π 3 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 3 2 θ v 1 2 + σ 4 2 + U Π 4 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 4 v 1 2 + 2 θ v 1 v 2 + 2 c u 2 v 1 v 2 1 + α u 2 c u 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 ( μ 3 + θ ) v 2 ,
Therefore,
L F 1 σ 3 2 + U Π 3 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 3 2 θ v 1 2 + σ 4 2 + U Π 4 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) 2 μ 4 v 1 2 + h v 1 2 + τ 2 v 2 2 + c α v 1 2 + c α v 2 2 ( μ 3 + θ ) v 2 ,
then,
L F 1 σ 3 2 + U Π 3 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) + c α 2 μ 3 θ v 1 2 + σ 4 2 + U Π 4 2 ( u ) ν ( d u ) + τ 2 2 μ 4 v 1 2 + L 2 ,
with L 2 = α ( μ 3 + θ c α ) 2 4 c . Therefore,
L F 1 c 3 v 1 2 c 4 v 2 2 + L 2 ,
Using Equation (9), we obtain
0 E F 1 v 1 ( t ) , v 2 ( t ) E 0 t c 3 v 1 2 c 4 v 2 2 + L 2 t + F 1 v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 ) ,
Noting ϱ 1 = min { c 3 , c 4 } , so
E 0 t v 1 2 + v 2 2 L 2 ϱ 1 t + F 1 v 1 ( 0 ) , v 2 ( 0 ) ϱ 1 ,
then,
lim sup t 1 t E 0 t v 1 2 + v 2 2 L 2 ϱ 1
Let
G 1 ( u 1 , u 2 ) = ln ( u 1 u 2 ) ,
by ItÔ’s formula, we get
d G 1 = L G 1 d t + i = 1 i = 2 σ i d W i + U q i ( u ) u i ln ( 1 + q i ( u ) ) N ( d t , d u ) ,
with
L G 1 = δ u 2 u 1 ( μ 1 + κ ) + κ u 1 u 2 μ 2 τ 1 u 2 c v 2 1 + α u 2 + i = 1 i = 2 σ i 2 2 + U q i ( u ) ln ( 1 + q i ( u ) ) ν ( d u ) .
We know v 2 u 1 α κ c . Therefore,
L G 1 τ 1 u 2 ( μ 1 + κ + μ 2 ) + i = 1 i = 2 σ i 2 2 + 2 N 1
where N 1 = min U Π 1 ( u ) ln ( 1 + Π 1 ( u ) ) , U Π 2 ( u ) ln ( 1 + Π 2 ( u ) ) , so
L G 1 τ 1 u 2 + N 1
with
N 1 = i = 1 i = 2 σ i 2 2 + 2 N 1 ( μ 1 + κ + μ 2 ) .
Therefore,
ln ( u 1 ( t ) u 2 ( t ) ) ln ( u 1 ( 0 ) u 2 ( 0 ) ) τ 1 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η + K 1 t + i = 1 i = 2 0 t σ i d W i ( η ) + U q i ( u ) u i ln ( 1 + q i ( u ) ) N ( d η , d u ) .
Therefore,
ln ( u 1 ( t ) u 2 ( t ) ) t ln ( u 1 ( 0 ) u 2 ( 0 ) ) t τ 1 1 t 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η + K 1 + i = 1 i = 2 1 t 0 t σ i d W i ( η ) + U q i ( u ) u i ln ( 1 + q i ( u ) ) N ( d η , d u ) .
The strong law of large numbers for local martingales implies that
0 τ 1 1 t 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η + N 1 ,
then,
1 t 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η N 1 τ 1 a . s .
The first equation of system (1) implies that
d u 1 ( t ) = δ u 2 ( t ) μ 1 u 1 ( t ) κ u 1 ( t ) d t + σ 1 u 1 ( t ) d W 1 ( t ) + U Π 1 ( u ) u 1 ( t ) N ( d t , d u ) ,
so,
u 1 ( t ) u 1 ( 0 ) = δ 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η ( μ 1 + κ ) 0 t u 1 ( η ) d η + 0 t σ 1 u 1 ( η ) d W 1 ( η ) + 0 t U Π 1 ( u ) u 1 ( η ) N ( d η , d u ) ,
then,
u 1 ( t ) u 1 ( 0 ) t = δ 1 t 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η ( μ 1 + κ ) 1 t 0 t u 1 ( η ) d η + 1 t 0 t σ 1 u 1 ( η ) d W 1 ( η ) + 1 t 0 t U Π 1 ( u ) u 1 ( η ) N ( d η , d u ) .
Since 1 t 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η N 1 τ 1 , so
u 1 ( t ) u 1 ( 0 ) t δ N 1 τ 1 ( μ 1 + κ ) 1 t 0 t u 1 ( η ) d η + 1 t 0 t σ 1 u 1 ( η ) d W 1 ( η ) + 1 t 0 t U Π 1 ( u ) u 1 ( η ) N ( d η , d u ) ,
using the strong law of large numbers for local martingales, we get
0 δ N 1 τ 1 ( μ 1 + κ ) 1 t 0 t u 1 ( η ) d η ,
then,
1 t 0 t u 1 ( η ) d η δ N 1 τ 1 ( μ 1 + κ ) a . s .

5. Stochastic Persistence

In order to prove the stochastic persistence of both the free jobs and the capital labor, we define the following constant
N 1 = i = 1 i = 2 σ i 2 2 + 2 N 1 ( μ 1 + κ + μ 2 ) ,
N 2 = i = 3 i = 4 σ i 2 2 + 2 N 2 ( μ 3 + θ + μ 4 ) ,
with
N 1 = min U Π 1 ( u ) ln ( 1 + Π 1 ( u ) ) , U Π 2 ( u ) ln ( 1 + Π 2 ( u ) )
and
N 2 = min U Π 3 ( u ) ln ( 1 + Π 3 ( u ) ) , U Π 4 ( u ) ln ( 1 + Π 4 ( u ) ) .
Theorem 5. 
If min { N 1 , N 2 } > 0 and v 2 u 1 α κ c , then, all the free jobs and labor force persistence in the mean. In addition, we have
1 t 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η N 1 τ 1 a . s . 1 t 0 t u 1 ( η ) d η δ N 1 τ 1 ( μ 1 + κ ) a . s . 1 t 0 t v 2 ( η ) d η N 2 τ 2 a . s . 1 t 0 t v 1 ( η ) d η μ 4 N 2 θ τ 2 a . s .
Proof. 
We consider the following function:
G 1 ( u 1 , u 2 ) = ln ( u 1 u 2 ) ,
ItÔ’s formula implies that
d G 1 = L G 1 d t + i = 1 i = 2 σ i d W i + U q i ( u ) u i ln ( 1 + q i ( u ) ) N ( d t , d u ) ,
with
L G 1 = δ u 2 u 1 ( μ 1 + κ ) + κ u 1 u 2 μ 2 τ 1 u 2 c v 2 1 + α u 2 + i = 1 i = 2 σ i 2 2 + U q i ( u ) ln ( 1 + q i ( u ) ) ν ( d u ) .
Since v 2 u 1 α κ c , then,
L G 1 τ 1 u 2 ( μ 1 + κ + μ 2 ) + i = 1 i = 2 σ i 2 2 + 2 N 1
where N 1 = min U Π 1 ( u ) ln ( 1 + Π 1 ( u ) ) , U Π 2 ( u ) ln ( 1 + Π 2 ( u ) ) , then
L G 1 τ 1 u 2 + N 1
with
N 1 = i = 1 i = 2 σ i 2 2 + 2 N 1 ( μ 1 + κ + μ 2 ) .
Then,
ln ( u 1 ( t ) u 2 ( t ) ) ln ( u 1 ( 0 ) u 2 ( 0 ) ) τ 1 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η + N 1 t + i = 1 i = 2 0 t σ i d W i ( η ) + U q i ( u ) u i ln ( 1 + q i ( u ) ) N ( d η , d u ) .
Thus fact implies that
ln ( u 1 ( t ) u 2 ( t ) ) t ln ( u 1 ( 0 ) u 2 ( 0 ) ) t τ 1 1 t 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η + N 1 + i = 1 i = 2 1 t 0 t σ i d W i ( η ) + U q i ( u ) u i ln ( 1 + q i ( u ) ) N ( d η , d u )
Using the strong law of large numbers for local martingales, we get
0 τ 1 1 t 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η + N 1 ,
therefore,
1 t 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η N 1 τ 1 a . s .
Using the first equation of system (1), we get
u 1 ( t ) u 1 ( 0 ) = δ 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η ( μ 1 + κ ) 0 t u 1 ( η ) d η + 0 t σ 1 u 1 ( η ) d W 1 ( η ) + 0 t U Π 1 ( u ) u 1 ( η ) N ( d η , d u ) ,
then,
u 1 ( t ) u 1 ( 0 ) t = δ 1 t 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η ( μ 1 + κ ) 1 t 0 t u 1 ( η ) d η + 1 t 0 t σ 1 u 1 ( η ) d W 1 ( η ) + 1 t 0 t U Π 1 ( u ) u 1 ( η ) N ( d η , d u ) ,
we know that 1 t 0 t u 2 ( η ) d η N 1 τ 1 , so
u 1 ( t ) u 1 ( 0 ) t δ K 1 τ 1 ( μ 1 + κ ) 1 t 0 t u 1 ( η ) d η + 1 t 0 t σ 1 u 1 ( η ) d W 1 ( η ) + 1 t 0 t U Π 1 ( u ) u 1 ( η ) N ( d η , d u ) ,
The strong law of large numbers for local martingales implies that
0 δ N 1 τ 1 ( μ 1 + κ ) 1 t 0 t u 1 ( η ) d η ,
then,
1 t 0 t u 1 ( η ) d η δ N 1 τ 1 ( μ 1 + κ ) a . s .
We use the following function:
G 2 ( v 1 , v 2 ) = ln ( v 1 v 2 ) ,
ItÔ’s formula implies that
d G 2 = L G 2 d t + i = 3 i = 4 σ i d W i + U q i ( u ) y i 2 ln ( 1 + q i ( u ) ) N ( d t , d u ) ,
with
L G 2 = 1 v 1 c u 2 v 2 1 + α u 2 ( μ 3 + θ ) + θ v 1 v 2 μ 4 τ 2 v 2 + i = 3 i = 4 σ i 2 2 + U q i ( u ) ln ( 1 + q i ( u ) ) ν ( d u ) .
Therefore,
L G 2 τ 2 v 2 ( μ 3 + θ + μ 4 ) + i = 3 i = 4 σ i 2 2 + 2 N 2 ,
where N 2 = min U Π 3 ( u ) ln ( 1 + Π 3 ( u ) ) , U Π 4 ( u ) ln ( 1 + Π 4 ( u ) ) , then
L G 2 τ 2 v 2 + N 2
with
N 2 = i = 3 i = 4 σ i 2 2 + 2 N 2 ( μ 3 + θ + μ 4 ) .
Therefore,
ln ( v 1 ( t ) v 2 ( t ) ) ln ( v 1 ( 0 ) v 2 ( 0 ) ) τ 2 0 t v 2 ( η ) d η + N 2 t + i = 3 i = 4 0 t σ i d W i ( η ) + U q i ( u ) y i 2 ln ( 1 + q i ( u ) ) N ( d η , d u ) .
Thus fact implies that
ln ( v 1 ( t ) v 2 ( t ) ) t ln ( v 1 ( 0 ) v 2 ( 0 ) ) t τ 2 1 t 0 t v 2 ( η ) d η + N 2 + i = 3 i = 4 1 t 0 t σ i d W i ( η ) + U q i ( u ) y i 2 ln ( 1 + q i ( u ) ) N ( d η , d u )
Using the strong law of large numbers for local martingales, we have
0 τ 2 1 t 0 t v 2 ( η ) d η + N 2 ,
then,
1 t 0 t v 2 ( η ) d η N 2 τ 2 a . s .
The last equation of system (1) implies that
v 2 ( t ) v 2 ( 0 ) θ 0 t v 1 ( η ) d η μ 4 0 t v 2 ( η ) d η + 0 t σ 4 v 2 ( η ) d W 4 ( η ) + 0 t U Π 4 ( u ) v 2 ( η ) N ( d η , d u ) ,
then,
v 2 ( t ) v 2 ( 0 ) t θ 1 t 0 t v 1 ( η ) d η μ 4 1 t 0 t v 2 ( η ) d η + 1 t 0 t σ 4 v 2 ( η ) d W 4 ( η ) + 1 t 0 t U Π 4 ( u ) v 2 ( η ) N ( d η , d u ) ,
so,
μ 4 1 t 0 t v 2 ( η ) d η + v 2 ( t ) v 2 ( 0 ) t θ 1 t 0 t v 1 ( η ) d η + 1 t 0 t σ 4 v 2 ( η ) d W 4 ( η ) + 1 t 0 t U Π 4 ( u ) v 2 ( η ) N ( d η , d u ) .
Since 1 t 0 t v 2 ( η ) d η N 2 τ 2 , then
μ 4 N 2 τ 2 + v 2 ( t ) v 2 ( 0 ) t θ 1 t 0 t v 1 ( η ) d η + 1 t 0 t σ 4 v 2 ( η ) d W 4 ( η ) + 1 t 0 t U Π 4 ( u ) v 2 ( η ) N ( d η , d u ) ,
Using the strong law of large numbers for local martingales, we have
μ 4 N 2 τ 2 θ 1 t 0 t v 1 ( η ) d η ,
then,
1 t 0 t v 1 ( η ) d η μ 4 K 2 θ τ 2 a . s .

6. Numerical Simulations

Now, our main objective is to give numerical simulations of the model in (1); furthermore, we consider the equation
d Y ( t ) = h t , Y ( t ) d t + σ t , Y ( t ) d W t + U Π ( t , u ) f t , Y ( t ) N ˇ ( d t , d u ) .
Then, the solution of (10) is
Y ( t ) = Y ( 0 ) + 0 t h s , Y ( s ) d s + 0 t σ s , Y ( s ) d W s Part I + f t , Y ( t ) 0 t U Π ( s , u ) N ˇ ( d s , d u ) Part II .
For approximation of part I in (10), we will use the Runge–Kutta method
Y k + 1 = Y k + 1 6 K 1 + 2 K 2 + 2 K 3 + K 4
where
K 1 = h ( t k , Y k ) ) Δ t + σ ( t k , Y k ) ( W k + 1 W k ) , K 2 = h ( t k + Δ t 2 t , Y k + K 1 2 ) ) Δ t + σ ( t k + Δ t 2 , Y k + K 1 2 ) ( W k + 1 W k ) , K 3 = h ( t k + Δ t 2 , Y k + K 2 2 ) ) Δ t + σ ( t k + Δ t 2 , Y k + K 2 2 ) ( W k + 1 W k ) , K 4 = h ( t k + Δ t , Y k + K 3 ) ) Δ t + σ ( t k + Δ t , Y k + K 3 ) ( W k + 1 W k ) .
For part I I , we will have two cases.
Consider any infinitesimal interval [ T i , T i + 1 ) ( t i , t i + 1 ) .
If there is no jump on this interval:
f t , Y ( t ) T i T i + 1 U Π ( s , u ) N ˇ ( d s , d u ) = 0 .
If there is only one jump point t i [ T i , T i + 1 ) , so
f t , Y ( t ) T i T i + 1 U Π ( u ) N ˇ ( d s , d u ) = f t i , Y ( t i ) Π t i , ζ ( t i ) ,
then,
f t , Y ( t ) 0 t U Π ( s , u ) N ˇ ( d s , d u ) = i = 0 i = n f t i , Y ( t i ) Π t i , ζ ( t i ) .
Consequently, the Runge–Kutta method of problem (10) will be
Y k + 1 = Y k + 1 6 K 1 + 2 K 2 + 2 K 3 + K 4
where
K 1 = h ( t k , Y k ) ) Δ t + σ ( t k , Y k ) ( W k + 1 W k ) + f ( t k , Y ( t k ) ) Π ( t k , ζ ( t k ) ) , K 2 = h ( t k + Δ t 2 t , Y k + K 1 2 ) ) Δ t + σ ( t k + Δ t 2 , Y k + K 1 2 ) ( W k + 1 W k ) + f ( t k + Δ t 2 , Y ( t k ) + K 1 2 ) Π ( t k + Δ t 2 , ζ ( t k + Δ t 2 ) ) , K 3 = h ( t k + Δ t 2 , Y k + K 2 2 ) ) Δ t + σ ( t k + Δ t 2 , Y k + K 2 2 ) ( W k + 1 W k ) + f ( t k + Δ t 2 , Y ( t k ) + K 2 2 ) Π ( t k + Δ t 2 , ζ ( t k + Δ t 2 ) ) , K 4 = h ( t k + Δ t , Y k + K 3 ) ) Δ t + σ ( t k + Δ t , Y k + K 3 ) ( W k + 1 W k ) + f ( t k + Δ t , Y ( t k ) + K 3 ) Π ( t k + Δ t , ζ ( t k + Δ t ) ) .
We use the previous method to solve the system in (1) and the parameters values in Table 1.
In Figure 1, we show the dynamics of u 1 , u 2 , v 1 , and v 2 , and we observe that both free jobs and the total labor force in the deterministic and the stochastic curves tend to zero; furthermore, we have the extinction of free jobs and the total labor force.
Figure 2 represents the behavior of u 1 , u 2 , v 1 , and v 2 . We remark that the labor force is extinct and the free jobs stay non negative; this means that the population of the labor force will be extinct and the free jobs will persist.
In Figure 3, we illustrate the interaction between u 1 , u 2 , v 1 , and v 2 . We show that both free jobs and and the labor force stay strictly positive in the two cases of stochastic and deterministic, then we have the persistence of both the free jobs and the labor force.

7. Conclusions and Discussion

In this paper, we have studied the interaction between free jobs and the labor force by decomposing each class into two subclasses. For the free jobs, we have considered the proposed new free jobs by the recruiting company and the confirmed free jobs. For the labor force, in order to account for labor force seasonality or internship periods, we divide the labor force into the precariat population and the mature labor force. Moreover, we have studied the well-posedness of the solution, by proving the existence, uniqueness, and the stochastic ultimate boundedness. In addition, we examined the behavior of our model in three cases. The first of them concerns the extinction of both free jobs and the labor force; the second concerns the extinction of the labor force and the persistence of free jobs; and the last concerns the persistence of both free jobs and the labor force. Finally, our study is supported by a numerical simulations in order to validate our theoretical findings. In a possible follow-up to our investigation in this article, we can extend problem (1) to different fractional derivatives, which rely on several fractional derivative operators, such as the Liouville–Caputo, Riemann–Liouville, and other fractional derivative operators [24,25]. In addition, we can extend our system to an impulsive problem such as that studied in [26].

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Conflicts of Interest

This work does not have any conflict of interest.

References

  1. Tcherneva, R.P. When a rising tide sinks most boats: Trends in US income inequality. Real World Econ. Rev. 2015, 71, 64–74. [Google Scholar]
  2. Piketty, T.; Saez, E.; Zucman, G. Distributional National Accounts: Methods and Estimates for the United States. Q. J. Econ. 2018, 133, 553–609. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Piketty, T. Capital in the Twenty-First Century; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  4. David, A.; Katz, L.F.; Kearney, M.S. The Polarization of the US Labor Market; NBER Working Paper; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  5. Kaplan, N.S.; Rau, J. It’s the Market: The Broad-Based Rise in the Return to Top Talent. J. Econ. Perspect. 2013, 27, 35–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Acemoglu, D.; Pascual, R. Robots and Jobs: Evidence from US Labor Market; NBER Working Paper; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  7. David, A.; Salomons, A. Is Automation Labor-Displacing? Productivity Growth, Employment, and the Labor Share; Brookings Papers on Economic Activity; Brookings Institution: Washington, DC, USA, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  8. Bloom, N. Corporations in the Age of Inequality; Harvard Business Review; 2017. Available online: https://hbr.org/cover-story/2017/03/corporations-in-the-age-of-inequality (accessed on 1 August 2017).
  9. Dorn, D.; Katz, L.F.; Patterson, C.; Van Reenen, J. Concentrating on the Fall of the Labor Share. Am. Econ. Rev. 2017, 107, 180–185. [Google Scholar]
  10. Baker, D. The Upward Redistribution of Income: Are Rents the Story? CEPR Working Paper; Center for Economic and Policy Research: Washington, DC, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  11. Howell, D.R.; Arne, L.K. Declining Job Quality in the United States: Explanations and Evidence; Washington Center for Equitable Growth: Washington, DC, USA, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  12. Stiglitz, J.E. The Price of Inequality; W.W. Norton: New York, NY, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  13. Weil, D. The Fissured Workplace; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  14. Naidu, S. A Political Economy Take on W/Y. In After Piketty; Boushey, H., DeLong, J.B., Steinbaum, M., Eds.; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2017; pp. 99–125. [Google Scholar]
  15. Standing, G. Work after Globalization: Building Occupational Citizenship; Edwin Elgar: Northhampton, MA, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  16. Wolff, N.E.; Zacharias, A. Class structure and economic inequality. Camb. J. Econ. 2013, 37, 1381–1406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Standing, G. The Precariat; Bloomsbury: New York, NY, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  18. Standing, G. The Precariat and Class Struggle. RCCS Annu. Rev. 2015, 7, 3–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  19. Greenstein, J. The Precariat class structure and income inequality among US workers: 1980–2018. Rev. Radic. Political Econ. 2020, 52, 447–469. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. International Labor Organization (ILO). Work Employment and Social Outlook: The Changing Nature of Jobs; International Labor Organization: Geneva, Switzerland, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  21. Breman, J.; van der Linden, M. Informalizing the Economy: The Return of the Social Question at a Global Level. Dev. Chang. 2014, 45, 920–940. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Riad, D.; Hattaf, K.; Yousfi, N. Dynamics of capital-labour model with Hattaf-Yousfi functional response. Br. J. Math. Comput. Sci. 2016, 18, 1–7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Zine, H.; Danane, J.; Torres, D.F. A Stochastic Capital-Labour Model with Logistic Growth Function. arXiv 2022, arXiv:2202.05348. [Google Scholar]
  24. Danane, J.; Allali, K.; Hammouch, Z. Mathematical analysis of a fractional differential model of HBV infection with antibody immune response. Chaos Solitons Fractals 2020, 136, 109787. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Danane, J.; Hammouch, Z.; Allali, K.; Rashid, S.; Singh, J. A fractional-order model of coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19) with governmental action and individual reaction. Math. Methods Appl. Sci. 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  26. Zhang, T.-W.; Zhou, J.-W.; Liao, Y.-Z. Exponentially stable periodic oscillation and Mittag-Leffler stabilization for fractional-order impulsive control neural networks with piecewise Caputo derivatives. IEEE Trans. Cybernet. 2021, 52, 9670–9683. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
Figure 1. The behavior of free jobs and the labor force.
Figure 1. The behavior of free jobs and the labor force.
Mca 27 00093 g001
Figure 2. The behavior of free jobs and the labor force.
Figure 2. The behavior of free jobs and the labor force.
Mca 27 00093 g002aMca 27 00093 g002b
Figure 3. The behavior of free jobs and the labor force.
Figure 3. The behavior of free jobs and the labor force.
Mca 27 00093 g003
Table 1. The values of the used parameters.
Table 1. The values of the used parameters.
ParametersFigure 1Figure 2Figure 3
δ 0.7 0.1785 0.305
τ 1 0.92 0.37 0.47
c 0.75 0.17 0.63
κ 0.32 0.19 0.4
θ 0.53 0.048 0.048
α 0.84 0.037 0.037
μ 1 0.91 0.0342 0.034
μ 2 0.532 0.0401 0.0401
μ 3 0.483 0.0481 0.058
μ 4 0.489 0.0432 0.0432
σ 1 10 5 10 4 10 4
σ 2 3 × 10 5 3 × 10 5 3 × 10 5
σ 3 3 × 10 5 3 × 10 5 3 × 10 5
σ 4 3 × 10 5 3 × 10 5 3 × 10 5
Π 1 ( u ) 0.051 0.051 0.052
Π 2 ( u ) 0.007 0.007 0.007
Π 3 ( u ) 0.009 0.006 0.007
Π 4 ( u ) 0.009 0.008 0.007
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Danane, J. Stochastic Capital–Labor Lévy Jump Model with the Precariat Labor Force. Math. Comput. Appl. 2022, 27, 93. https://doi.org/10.3390/mca27060093

AMA Style

Danane J. Stochastic Capital–Labor Lévy Jump Model with the Precariat Labor Force. Mathematical and Computational Applications. 2022; 27(6):93. https://doi.org/10.3390/mca27060093

Chicago/Turabian Style

Danane, Jaouad. 2022. "Stochastic Capital–Labor Lévy Jump Model with the Precariat Labor Force" Mathematical and Computational Applications 27, no. 6: 93. https://doi.org/10.3390/mca27060093

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop