Next Article in Journal
Economic Uncertainty and Firms’ Capital Structure: Evidence from China
Next Article in Special Issue
AutoReserve: A Web-Based Tool for Personal Auto Insurance Loss Reserving with Classical and Machine Learning Methods
Previous Article in Journal
Asymptotic Expected Utility of Dividend Payments in a Classical Collective Risk Process
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

A Comparison of Competing Asset Pricing Models: Empirical Evidence from Pakistan

1
Department of Maritime Studies, Faculty of Maritime and Industrial Studies, University of Piraeus, 185-33 Piraeus, Greece
2
Department of Insurance and Risk Management, Faculty of Economics, Management and Accountancy, University of Malta, 2080 Msida, Malta
3
Department of Management Sciences, Hitec University, Taxila 47080, Pakistan
4
Department of Management Sciences, Shaheed Zulfikar Ali Bhutto Institute of Science and Technology, Islamabad 44000, Pakistan
5
Department of Management Sciences, Islamia College University, Peshawar 25120, Pakistan
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Risks 2023, 11(4), 65; https://doi.org/10.3390/risks11040065
Submission received: 7 February 2023 / Revised: 10 March 2023 / Accepted: 17 March 2023 / Published: 24 March 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Computational Technologies for Financial Security and Risk Management)

Abstract

:
In recent years, the rapid and significant development of emerging markets has globally led to insight from potential investors and academicians seeking to assess these markets in terms of risk inheritance. Therefore, this study aims to explore the validity and applicability of the capital asset pricing model (henceforth CAPM) and multi-factor models, namely Fama–French models, in Pakistan’s stock market for the period of June 2010–June 2020. This study collects data on 173 non-financial firms listed on the Pakistan stock exchange, namely the KSE-100 index, and follows Fama-MacBeth’s regression methodology for empirical estimation. The empirical findings of this study conclude that small portfolios (small-size companies) earn considerably higher returns than big portfolios (large-size companies). Ultimately, the risk associated with portfolio returns is reported to be higher for small portfolios (small-size companies) than for big portfolios (large-size companies). According to the regression output, the CAPM was found to be valid for explaining the market risk premium above the risk-free rate. Similarly, the FF three-factor model was found to be valid for explaining time-series variation in excess portfolio returns. Later, we added human capital into FF three- and five-factor models. This study found that the human capital base six-factor model outperformed the other competing asset pricing models. The findings of this study indicate that small portfolios (small-size companies) earn more returns than big portfolios (large-size companies) to reward the investor for taking extra risks. Investors may benefit by timing their investments to maximize stock returns. Company investment in human capital adds reliable information, replicates the value of the company and, in the long term, helps investors make rational decisions.

1. Introduction

Investment decisions, such as whether to invest or not or how to efficiently allocate hard-earned money in different financial securities, are always one of the most prioritized decisions for investors around the globe. That is why asset pricing is a most important and controversial area in the financial economics literature.
Since Markowitz (1952)’s portfolio theory, academicians and practitioners have tried to develop a better asset pricing model. A better model would estimate the intrinsic values in a realistic way that is very close to prevailing market prices, thereby reducing anomalies compared to less efficient models (Zada et al. 2018). Thus, comparing alternative asset pricing models is crucial and necessary for choosing the best model among alternative competing models.
Sharpe (1964) provided the first asset pricing model, i.e., CAPM (the capital asset pricing model), for estimating the fundamental price of securities. It is a one-factor model with only a market factor. Later on, Ross (1976) proposed Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT), which resulted in the development of a multi-factor model. Since APT, many asset pricing anomalies were identified by many researchers in different regions of the world (e.g., the price-to-earnings ratio (P/E) of Basu (1977), size anomaly of Banz (1981), size anomaly of Reinganum (1981), earnings price anomaly of Basu (1983), value anomaly of Rosenberg et al. (1985), Fama and French (1987) stock volatility, leverage anomaly of Bhandari (1988), dividend anomaly of Fama and French (1988), momentum anomaly of Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), and book-to-market anomaly of Kothari and Shanken (1997) in search of models that would be better than CAPM.
Fama and French (1993) developed their influential three-factor model (FF3FM) by combining size and value anomalies with CAPM. The FF3FM is an extension of CAPM, and has been found to be a better model than CAPM and to overcome many of the existing asset pricing anomalies. Carhart (1997) proposed a four-factor model adding the momentum factor to FF3FM. Palacios-Huerta (2003) tested the efficiency of conditional CAPM with human capital. Similarly, Zhang (2006) tested human capital in the asset return, and Swathi (2013) stated that human capital has a causal relationship with cross-sectional returns.
Fama and French (2015) extended their FF3FM with two prominent factors, namely investment and profitability, in order to propose a five-factor model (FF5FM). Later on, Fama and French (2018) extended their own FF5FM to a six-factor model by including the momentum factor. The latest development in asset pricing was provided by Roy and Shijin (2018), who proposed a new six factor model (6FMRS) that included human capital as a new factor along with 5FMFF.
In an emerging country such as Pakistan, many researchers put their efforts into providing various studies on asset pricing models and their comparison; e.g., Wahab and Zada (2017) tested short- and long-term usage of CAPM in the cement industry, Hassan and Javed (2011) conducted a study to test 3FMFF, Zada et al. (2018) conducted a study on 5FMFF, and Zada et al. (2019) developed an efficient portfolio for investors to earn maximum profit by undertaking comparatively less risk than others. Younus and Butt (2022) tested the performance of 3FMFF, 5FMFF, and 6FMFF using time-series tests.
Many scholars across the world have recently focused on the development of human capital, including Roy and Shijin (2018), Maiti and Balakrishnan (2018), Tambosi et al. (2022), and Khan et al. (2022), to find a way to include human capital as a risk factor in asset pricing models. According to previous literature, limited studies have been conducted in the context of Pakistan that explore the dynamism of the asset pricing model. Such study is needed to test the efficiency of single-factor and multi-factor asset pricing models. Our study presents novel findings in two areas. First, this study tests the efficiency and validity of the single-factor and FF three-factor models. Second, this study extends the FF three-factor and five-factor models by adding human capital (proxied by payable salaries and wages) in order to propose human capital-augmented four- and six-factor models. Therefore, this study aims to test the validity and applicability of a single factor model (CAPM) and multi-factor asset pricing models that include the Fama–French three-factor model, human capital-based four-factor model, Fama–French five-factor model and human capital-based six-factor model, in the context of Pakistan. This study finds that CAPM significantly explained the market risk premium above the risk-free rate. Similarly, the FF three-factor model was found to be valid for explaining time-series variation in excess portfolio returns. However, the human capital-based four-factor model outperformed the FF three-factor model for explaining variation in asset returns. Later, we tested the FF five-factor model and employed the human capital-augmented six-factor model. Through this test, this study found that the human capital-based six-factor model outperformed the other competing asset pricing models, including CAPM, the FF three-factor model, the human capital four-factor model, and the FF five-factor model.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 1 contains the introduction to the study, Section 2 explains the review of related literature, Section 3 contains the methodology of the study, and Section 4 discusses the findings and gives conclusions and policy recommendations.

2. Literature Review

Markowitz (1952) empirically examined the relationship between individual security and portfolio, documenting that the risk associated with portfolio has a negligible effect on individual securities. Depending on the connotation and framework, individual security risk is actually the summation of risk incorporated in terms of opportunity cost, weight of the individual security, and variance and covariance of individual security returns. Later, Tobin (1958) explored the optimal utility function of the investor and asset return through a mean variance conceptual framework. Consequently, Sharpe (1964) developed the capital asset pricing model (henceforth CAPM), which is considered a breakthrough in the field of asset pricing. CAPM measures the sensitivity of stock to the market through the beta coefficient (β). The CAPM research by Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965) and Mossin (1966) attracted the attention of investors for explaining the risk–return relationship. Later, investors used this model for investment decisions. In the recent past, many researchers have criticized the efficiency and validity of CAPM for explaining the risk–return relationship (including Basu 1977, Ross 1976, Banz 1981, and Acaravci and Karaomer 2017). Subsequently, Fama (1970), relying on CAPM, proposed the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH). Based on its premise, if component model projections of stock returns are accurate, then security prices accurately reflect all information currently available. This is because it is possible for the stock market to be in equilibrium and for all information to be considered so that investors receive more compensation for taking calculated risks. Equity markets, however, are not always effective at reflecting all information that is available, and investors may be able to take advantage of arbitrage possibilities. This demonstrates CAPM’s drawback of not being able to quantify expected returns in relation to a single risk factor. Ross (1976) proposed Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT). This theory identified some unknown factors that affect stock returns. Later, some identified factors, namely GDP growth, inflation and dividend yield, were strongly questioned by many researchers. Furthermore, it was exceedingly challenging to determine or add the pertinent factors into the model (Susanti 2020). Rosenberg et al. (1985) documented that the assumptions of CAPM faced many critiques, as it only relies on market risk when measuring stock return. Further, it was suggested that stock return is not only dependent on market premium. Some other considered variables (i.e., size, leverage, price-to-earnings, and book-to-market ratio) can also affect stock return. Additionally, it concludes that a single beta (β) is insufficient to explain stock return. Similarly, Debondt and Thaler (1985) documented that there exists a positive relationship between book-to-market ratio and stock return. Later, Fama and French (1992) explored the combined effects of market beta, size, leverage, price-to-earnings (P-E) ratio, and book-to-market ratio for explaining cross-sectional variation in the expected returns of companies listed on the NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ. They found that market beta, size, and book-to-market ratio explain the cross-sectional variations in stock returns.
Similarly, Fama and French (1993) extended CAPM model with two prominent factors, namely size (small-minus-big, SMB) and value (high-minus-low) factors. Carhart (1997) extended the Fama–French three factors with a momentum (up-minus-down, UMD) factor. Across the world, many studies have been conducted that empirically test the FF3FM and C4FM. Such studies conclude that these models do not fully capture the variation in expected stock returns. As such, Fama and French (2015) extended their 3FM with two prominent factors, namely profitability (robust-minus-weak, RMW) and investment (conservative-minus-aggressive, CMA). Furthermore, Fama and French (2015) tested the 5FM in developed markets and concluded that 5FM better explains the variation than 3FM. Similarly, Fama and French (2018) extended their 5FM with a momentum (up-minus-down, UMD) factor, introducing the FF6 six-factor model. Later, Fama and French (2018) developed an alternative six-factor model (henceforth FF6cp). This model replaces the operating factor with cash profitability. Fama and French tested this alternative six-factor model in the US market and found that the model performs well under all performance metrics.
Martinsa and Eid (2015) tested the performance of FF3FM and FF5FM in the Brazilian stock market. They found that the FF5FM outperforms the FF3FM. Furthermore, the authors documented that MKT (market premium), SMB (size premium), and HML (value premium) explain most variation in excess returns compared to RMW and CMA. Chiah et al. (2016) tested FF3FM and FF5FM in the Australian market. The authors found that profitability and investment premium have positive and significant effects on stock returns. Moreover, the FF5FM outperforms the FF3FM for capturing the variation in asset returns. Contrarily, with the findings of Fama and French (2015), the authors documented that the value factor (HML) remains neutral in the presence of the CMA and RMW factors. Chowdhury (2017) tested the FF3FM in the Bangladesh stock market and found that low market capitalization companies outperform high market capitalization companies. Similarly, companies with high book-to-market ratios report low earnings. Furthermore, the author documented that FF3FM is less explanatory for explaining stock returns in the Bangladesh stock market. Jiao and Lilti (2017) tested the efficiency of FF3FM and FF5FM in the Chinese stock market. The authors documented that FF5FM showed different explanatory power within a set of variant portfolios. In addition to FF3FM, the two factors added in FF5FM (RMW (profitability) and CMA (investment premium)) do not capture more variation than the FF3FM in asset returns. Shaharuddin et al. (2018) tested the FF3FM in the pre- and post-periods of the 2008 financial crisis. They found that FF3FM is valid in both periods of the financial crisis for explaining variation in asset return. Kubota and Takehara (2018) documented that the FF5FM was less explanatory for explaining variation in asset returns. Furthermore, the authors reported that the conclusion drawn from this information is that some anomalies’ effects are still unknown. Huynh (2018) tested the performance of FF3FM and FF5FM through the GRS (Gibbons–Ross–Shanken) test. The author argued that the GRS test shows insufficient results for Fama–French models. Furthermore, this study concludes that the quest for developing optimum asset pricing models is still ongoing around the world. Similarly, Dutta (2019) found that FF5FM is inefficient for detecting long-term anomalies.
When the Fama–French three factor model (FF3FM) failed to accommodate a wide range of anomalies, Hou et al. (2017) added an additional factor (q-factor) in to the FF3FM. The q-factor model was found to successfully accommodate some anomalies. Later, Stambaugh and Yuan (2017) tested models to accommodate set anomalies in horse racing by considering the FF3FM, FF5FM, and q-factor model. They found the latter model superior to and better performing than the rest of the models. Fama and French (2018) proposed two models, FF6OP and FF6CP. Using the maximum squared Sharpe ratio, they found the alternative six-factor model the best performer of the models. Fletcher (2018) conducted a study in the UK equity market that tested the performance of FF5FM and FF6FM. It found that FF6FM is the foremost model for explaining variation in expected stock return. Racicot et al. (2019a) conducted a study in order to determine time-varying alpha (α) and beta (β) estimates using the recursive/rolling IV GMM technique. The authors documented that market risk premium was the most influential factor for explaining variation. Similarly, Racicot et al. (2019b) asserted that the FF model’s static approach might not be sufficient. The authors further concentrated on the Jensen performance measure’s time-varying characteristics and the market’s sensitivity to systematic risk, because these parameters are fundamentally universal in asset pricing models. Similarly, Chai et al. (2019) tested the FF5FM and FF6CP (alternative six-factor model) in US and Australian markets. This study found that the alternative six-factor model is suitable for both markets. Later, Hou et al. (2019) tested all models, including the q-factor model, mispricing model of Stambaugh and Yuan (2017), and FF five- and six-factor models of 2015, 2018, in the US market. They found the q-factor model more effective than other competing models in terms of the subsuming factor. Similarly, Barillas et al. (2020) conducted a study in the US market and tested eight models including the q-factor model of Hou et al. (2017), two-factor model of He et al. (2017), extended CAPM model of Frazzini and Pedersen (2014); mispricing model of Stambaugh and Yuan (2017), FF5FM 2015, Fama–French alternative and altered models 2015, and regular value factor model of Asness and Frazzini (2013). This study documented that the altered six-factor model was more effective than other models. Haqqani and Aleem (2020) tested the augmented liquidity six-factor model in the Pakistan equity market. The authors documented that the six-factor model performed efficiently in the PSX (Pakistan stock exchange). Furthermore, the liquidity factor has a significant and key role in the asset pricing model. Paliienko et al. (2020) evaluated the efficiency and performance of asset pricing models. The authors found that FF5FM better explained the variation in excess portfolio return compared to other asset pricing models. Sadhwani et al. (2019) evaluated the efficiency of FF3FM and FF5FM in the Pakistani stock market. They demonstrated that the FF5FM outperforms the FF3FM and better explains the variability in stock return. Foye and Valentincic (2020) documented that FF5FM more significantly captured variability in stock return than FF3FM in the Indonesian stock market. Mosoeu and Kodongo (2020) tested the efficiency of FF5FM in emerging equity markets. They found that the profitability is one of the most useful factors in emerging equity markets for explaining cross-section. Furthermore, according to the Gibbons–Ross–Shanken (GRS) test, the FF5FM performs poorly on geographically diversified and country-specific portfolios. Horvath and Wang (2020) examined the efficiency of the Fama–French model during COVID-19 in the U.S. stock market. The authors evaluated the performance of FF models. This study found that the R2 of the growth model for the dotcom bubble was statistically significant. Furthermore, this study reports a rapid decrease in R2 for portfolios during 2008 financial crisis. Zaremba et al. (2021) tested the efficiency of seven competing asset models (CAPM, FF3FM, C4FM, q-factor model, FF5FM, FF6OP and Barillas and Shanken model) in frontier markets. This study documented that the Carhart four factor model performs better than other competing models in frontier markets.
Ali et al. (2021) conducted a study testing the performance of CAPM, FF3FM, FF5FM and FF6FM (including the momentum factor) in the Pakistan equity market. This study concluded that FF5FM significantly explained more variation in excess portfolio returns than alternative asset pricing models. Li and Duan (2021) examined the effectiveness and performance of the FF3FM and FF5FM during the COVID-19 outbreak. Despite the authors’ observation that the significance level of all independent variables grew over the course of the pandemic, the FF5FM displayed a substantial increase and showed greater efficiency during the epidemic. Kostin et al. (2022) analyzed the performance of FF3FM during crises in the last two decades and the COVID-19 outbreak in emerging and developed markets. They found that the results of FF5FM do not outperform in developed markets. The authors suggest that adding more regression factors would improve the asset pricing models, which could yield more reliable returns. Similarly, Ali (2022) tested the augmented mispricing model of asset pricing in Pakistani stock market. This study examined the performance of the augmented UMO (undervalued-minus-overvalued) factor model, CAPM, C4FM, FF3FM, FF5FM and FF6FM using the factor spinning test, Barillas–Shanken maximum squared Sharpe ratio test, and Gibbons–Ross–Shanken (GRS) test. The author concludes that the UMO factor carries distinctive information from the rest of the factors, and the augmented UMO four-factor model including MKT (market premium), SMB (size premium), and RMW (profitability premium) outperforms other competing asset pricing models. Hua (2022) conducted study and compared the explanatory power of five models, namely the FF3FM, C4FM, Novy–Marx 4FM, FF5FM, and Hou–Xue–Zhang 4F-model, in the Chinese SME board. The author found that FF5FM was insufficient for explaining better variation in asset return for the SME board. Furthermore, this study concludes that C4FM and q-FM are better for capturing better variability in asset returns for the SME board. Akhtar et al. (2022) compared the FF3FM and Daniel and Titman characteristics model (D&T) in the Indian stock market. They found that FF3FM has more favorable characteristics for explaining variation in asset return than the Daniel and Titman (D&T) characteristics model. Similarly, Nugraha et al. (2022) conclude that FF5FM was efficient for explaining variation in excess portfolio returns.

Review of Human Capital in Asset Pricing Models

Mayers (1972) documented that human capital describes the variation in return predictability. Furthermore, he argues that 75% of consumption is based on the labor income growth rate. Similarly, Fama and Schwert (1977) found a weak relationship between human capital and marketable security returns. However, the most prominent models such as CAPM and Fama–French have ignored the inclusion of human capital in asset pricing models. Campbell (1996) introduced human capital, which was accounted for through wealth. Later, the author included human capital (proxied by LBR) in CAPM and found that the CAPM does not capture most of the variability in asset return. Jagannathan and Wang (1996) found that, in contrast with CAPM specifications, the labor income beta (β) substantially improved the performance of CAPM. According to Jagannathan and Wang (1998), human capital beta (β) is more likely to be positive over business cycle frequencies and negative over monthly frequencies. Similarly, Rosett (2001) used market- and accounting-based risk variables in their study, which documents that human capital has a statistically positive relationship with equity return. Qin (2002) added the non-traded human capital factor to the generalized CAPM and found that the human capital beta (β) captures the variation in asset returns. Similarly, in today’s knowledge based-economy, human capital must be considered an investment rather than an expense of a company; moreover, human capital has a greater influence on determining the value of company (Wright et al. 2001; Bontis 2003). According to Palacios-Huerta (2003), investing in human capital can have an impact on asset returns across industries. According to Pantzalis and Park (2009), organizations that invest in their human resources are compensated more, which boosts productivity and raises the market value of the company. Crook et al. (2011) finds that firm characteristics and the uniqueness of human assets are difficult to replicate and copy. A company that invests in its human resources might achieve a lasting competitive advantage over rival businesses. According to Edmans (2011), small-size businesses cannot rely on the market to forecast the accuracy of their human assets. Determining the link between human resources and corporate valuation is also crucial. According to Kim et al. (2011), an asset pricing model that includes human capital together with size and value premiums can forecast changes in stock returns. Human capital and asset returns are causally related. Similarly, human capital plays a significant role in asset pricing models (Shijin et al. 2012; Belo et al. 2017).
Kuehn et al. (2017) found that labor income is an important determinant for explaining cross-section variation in equity returns. Moreover, this study documented that firms with low labor loading outperform firms with high labor loading. Florensia and Susanti (2020) tested the HC6FM in the Indonesia stock market. The authors reveal that market, size, value, profitability, investment and labor income growth rate premiums have significant effects on excess stock returns. Maiti and Vukovic (2020) explored the role of human capital in firm valuation. They find that ignoring the human assets in firm valuation may lead to serious problems. Khan et al. (2022) extended FF5FM with augmented human capital in the context of Pakistan. The authors documented that the HC6FM model statistically captured variability in excess portfolio returns.

3. Research Methodology

This study collected monthly closing share price data for non-financial firms listed on the Pakistan stock exchange (PSX) over the period June 2010–June 2020. This sample period was selected as it was considered to be a normal period after the financial crisis of 2007–2008 and before the recent COVID-19 pandemic of 2020 (Ulbert et al. (2022). The sample contains all available data on stock prices, book value, market capitalization, profitability, investment, and payable salary and wages. This study excludes data from those firms that report a negative book-to-market ratio. Furthermore, for market returns we used the KSE-100 index as a proxy, and the three-month treasury bill rate was used as a proxy for the risk-free rate (Rf). We obtained the data from multiple sources. Company share price data were taken from business recorder websites. Data for market capitalization, firm book equity, profitability and investment were taken from the balance sheet analysis (BSA) report published by the state bank of Pakistan. The salary and wages payable data used as a proxy for human capital were obtained from listed companies’ annual reports. The monthly time series of the three-month treasury bill rates (Market treasury bill auction rate) and the daily trading volume of the KSE-100 index were taken from the websites of the Pakistan Stock Exchange and the State Bank of Pakistan, respectively. Similarly, T-bill (3%, 6%, 12%) rates in Pakistan are considered to be a financial tool that helps maintain liquidity in the economy. Therefore, the term liquidity has greater importance for business activity that improves economic growth (Ali et al. 2015).
To compute the factor premium, we sorted the sample into portfolios based on size, book-to-market (BM) ratio, investment, profitability, and labor income growth rate factors.

3.1. Variable Description

The variables, their description, and the related references are as follows:
VariableDescriptionReferences
SizeMarket capitalization is used as a proxy for size.Fama and French (1993)
HMLBook value of equity to market value of equity is used as a proxy for the value factor. Fama and French (1993)
RMWEarnings before interest and taxes (EBIT) divided by book value of equity is used as a proxy for the profitability factor. Fama and French (2015)
CMAAnnual change in total assets is used as a proxy for the investment factor.Fama and French (2015)
LBRAnnual salaries and wages payable mentioned in the fiscal year annual report, from end of year t-1 to end of year t, is used as a proxy for the labor income growth rate factor.Maiti and Balakrishnan (2018)

3.2. Portfolio Calculation and Formation

This study created 32 portfolios in which companies were divided into categories based on size, value, profitability, investment, and human capital. The term high represents companies with high market capitalization, high or low book-to-market value, robust or weak profitability, conservative or aggressive investment, and low or high labor income growth rate. The term small represents companies with small market capitalization, high or low book-to-market value, robust or weak profitability, conservative or aggressive investment, and low or high labor income growth rate. This study follows Fama and French (1992, 1993, 2015)’s estimation techniques for factor construction. Calculation of factor premiums is given in the Appendix A and the Portfolio Abbreviations and Descriptions in Appendix B.

3.3. Fama and MacBeth’s (1973) Regression

This study follows Fama and MacBeth’s (1973) methodology and regressed a set of thirty-two portfolios for the empirical estimation of excess portfolio return. In the recent past, Fama and MacBeth’s (1973) regression was widely followed by many researchers in empirical asset pricing studies. This study follows the factor construction criteria of Fama and French (1992, 1993, 2015) for portfolio stocks as a test to estimate risk premium associated with various factors (in our case, market, size, value, profitability, investment premium and human capital). Fama and MacBeth’s (1973) regressions investigate the linear relationship between exposure to (priced) risk variables and predicted returns. The core concept behind the regression approach is to forecast asset returns based on factor exposures or traits that mimic exposure to a risk factor in the cross-section over each period.
Econometrically, the regression can be expressed as
R 1 , t = α 1 + β 1 , F 1 F 1 , t + β 1 , F 2 , F 2 , t + + β 1 , F m F m , t + ϵ 1 , t
R 2 , t = α 2 + β 2 , F 1 F 1 , t + β 2 , F 2 F 2 , t + + B 2 , F m F m t + ϵ 2 , t
R n , t = α n + β n , F 1 F 1 , t + β n , F 2 F 2 , t + + B n , F m F m t + ϵ n , t

3.4. Econometric Model of the Study

The following Equations (1)–(5) show the econometric models of the study.
  • CAPM (capital asset pricing model)
R i t R f t = α + b i M K T t + e i t
  • FF3 (Fama–French three) factor model
R i t R f t = α + b i M K T t + s i S M B t + h i H M L t + e i t
  • Human capital four-factor model
R i t R f t = α + b i M K T t + s i S M B t + h i H M L t + l i L o M H i t + e i t
  • FF5 (Fama–French five) factor model
R i t R f t = α + b i M K T t + s i S M B t + h i H M L t + r i R M W t + c i C M A t + e i t
  • Augmented human capital six-factor model
R i t R f t = α + b i M K T t + s i S M B t + h i H M L t + r i R M W t + c i C M A t + l i L o M H i t + e i t
In these equations, R i t is the excess return of portfolio i for the month of t, and SMBt, HMLt, RMWt, CMAt and LoMHit are constructed factors, namely size, value, profitability, investment, and human capital, for portfolio i for the month of t.

4. Results and Discussion

Table 1 shows the descriptive summary containing mean, maximum, minimum, standard deviation, skewness, and kurtosis for the set of thirty-two portfolios sorted by size, value, profitability, investment, and labor income growth rate premium. Furthermore, the mean value shows the average return of each portfolio, while the standard deviation shows the associated risk of each portfolio.
It is indicated that portfolios sorted by size shows that the risk and return of the ten small portfolios (including small-size companies) are considerably higher than those of corresponding big-size portfolios (i.e., the risk and returns of SLLBCwCcLo, SLLBCwCcHoi, SLLBCwCALoi, SLLBCwCAHoi, SLLBCRCcLoi, SLLBCRCcHoi, SLLBCRCALoi, SHHBCwCALoi, SHHBCRCcLoi, and SHHBCRCcHoi report higher than BLLBCwCcLoi, BLLBCwCcHoi, BLLBCwCALoi, BLLBCwCAHoi, BLLBCRCcLoi, BLLBCRCcHoi, BHHBCwCcLoi, BHHBCRCcLoi, and BHHBCRCcHoi). This means that in Pakistan, on average small portfolios (small-size companies), earn considerably higher returns than big portfolios (large-size companies). The excess portfolio returns are represented by the mean values, while the maximum and minimum values represent the highest percentages of excess portfolio return movement from the mean value. The standard deviation shows the deviation from the mean value of the risk associated with each portfolio. Furthermore, portfolios sorted by size value show that five out of eight small high-value stock portfolios show higher mean values (excess portfolio return) along with standard deviation (risk) than those of the corresponding big low-value stock portfolios (i.e., excess return and risk of SHHBCwCcLoi, SHHBCwCcHoi, SHHBCwCALoi, SHHBCRCcHoi, and SHHBCRCALoi are reported to be higher than those of BLLBCwCcLoi, BLLBCwCcHoi, BLLBCwCALo, BLLBCRCcHoi, and BLLBCRCALoi). This means that, in Pakistan, small high-value stock portfolios earn considerably higher returns than big low-value stock portfolios. The average risk and return of three out of four small high-value robust stock portfolios are much greater than the prevalent values among big low-value weak stock portfolios, due to small high-value profitable stocks (excess return and risk of SHHBCRCcHoi, SHHBCRCALoi, and SHHBCRCAHoi are reported to be higher than those of SHHBCwCcHoi, SHHBCwCALoi, and SHHBCwCAHoi). This indicates that, in Pakistan, robust stocks (stocks with higher profitability) earn considerably higher returns than weak stocks (stocks with lower profitability). In addition, a portfolio comprised of small high-value robust conservative stocks exhibits a significantly higher rate of return and risk than a portfolio comprised of big low-value weak aggressive stocks (i.e., excess return and risk of SHHBCRCcHoi is reported to be higher than that of SHHBCRCAHoi). However, small, high-value, robust, conservative, low labor income growth rate stock portfolios show higher risk and returns than their corresponding large, low-value, weak, aggressive, high labor income growth rate stock portfolios (excess returns of SHHBCRCcLoi are reported to be higher than that of SHHBCRCAHoi). This indicates that when considering size, value, profitability, investment, and labor income growth rate, small-size portfolios are riskier than big-size portfolios, which results in higher returns. These results reported in Table 1, in the context of Pakistan, support the proposition of Richardson (1970) who argued that “Investors on average earn higher return by taking greater risk, thus, to enjoy broad acceptance throughout the investment community”.
Table 2 shows the descriptive statistics containing the mean, median, standard deviation, skewness, and kurtosis of factor premiums for each of the six factors. MKT (market- premium) reported a mean value of −0.018, while its maximum value was 0.129 and minimum value was −0.275. The negative mean value of MKT was found to be like the findings of Sadhwani et al. (2019) that MKT has a higher absolute mean value than other factors and is more volatile. SMB reported a mean value of 0.002 while its maximum value was 0.173 and minimum value was −0.066. RMW had a mean value of −0.008, a maximum value of 0.084 and a minimum value of −0.094. The negative mean value of RMW implies that weak stocks outperform robust stocks. The negative mean value of RMW found was like the findings of Zada et al. (2018). Small-value stocks and companies with low labor income growth outperform big-value stocks and stocks with high labor income growth, according to the positive mean values of SMB, HML, and LoMHi.
The study’s correlation matrix is shown in Table 3. It shows that SMB and MKT (market premium) have a positive correlation. HML (value premium) and CMA (investment premium) show negative correlations with MKT (market premium). LBR and MKT are found to be positively correlated; the VIF test was employed for the multicollinearity issue. The value of the VIF test was below 4. According to Hair et al. (2010), if a VIF value greater than 4 is found, then the multicollinearity problem exists among the explanatory variables. According to Table 3, there is no substantial multicollinearity among the variables that make up the factors.
Table 4 shows a comparison of the econometric models. This study constructed a set of thirty-two portfolios. Subsequently, we regressed the thirty-two portfolios for each model employed in this study. Furthermore, we compared all the competing asset pricing models (CAPM, F3FM, HC4FM, FF5FM, HC6FM) on the basis of the adjusted R2 of each model regressed against the thirty-two portfolios. CAPM and multifactor models for each portfolio are given in Table 5, Table 6, Table 7 and Table 8.
The adjusted R2 of CAPM ranges from 6.02–50.83%. This indicates that 6.02–50.83% is explained by the market premium above the risk-free rate. Similarly, the adjusted R2 of FF3FM for small portfolios (small-size companies) is 14.83% and for big portfolios (large-size companies) 54.30%. This indicates that 14.83–54.30% of variation is explained by the market, size and excess portfolio return value. The adjusted R2 of the human capital-based four-factor model for small portfolios (small-size companies) was 14.13% and for big size portfolios 59.31%. This indicates that 14.13–59.31% of variation is explained by the market, size, value and labor income growth premium in asset returns. The adjusted R2 of FF5FM for small portfolios (small-size companies) was 17.77% and for big portfolios (large-size companies) 57.96%. This indicates that 17.77–57.96% of variation is explained by the market, size, value, profitability and investment premium in excess portfolio returns. However, the adjusted R2 of the human capital-based six-factor model for small portfolios (small-size companies) was 21.75% and for big portfolios 61.13%. This indicates that 21.75–61.13% of variation is explained by the market, size, value, profitability, investment and labor income growth premium in excess portfolio returns.
Table 4 represents the explanatory summary of these five models, namely CAPM, FF3FM, HC4FM, FF5FM and HC6FM. These five asset pricing models are found to be statistically valid and appropriate for explaining variation in excess portfolio returns. Comparing these models on the basis of adjusted R2 indicated that the human capital-based six-factor model is more appropriate than and superior to other competing asset pricing models for explaining variability in excess portfolio returns in the context of Pakistan.

Results Interpretation for Human Capital Six-Factor Model

Table 9 (see Appendix B) shows the regression output for HC6FM. In the six-factor model, MKT (market premium), SMB (size premium), HML (value premium) RMW (profitability premium), CMA (investment premium), and LBR (labor income growth rate) are regressed on thirty-two portfolios. It is shown in Table 9 that all coefficients of MKT (market-premium) are positive and statistically significant for the market premium above the risk-free rate. However, the SMB (size premium) co-efficient for small portfolios (small-size companies) is positive and statistically significant for all sixteen small-size portfolios, and the association is found to be statistically significant at the 1% or 5% levels. By contrast, the coefficient of SMB for big-size portfolios is positive and statistically insignificant for all of the sixteen big-size portfolios. The significance of SMB for all of the sixteen small portfolios (small-size companies) and insignificance of SMB for the big portfolios shows that, in Pakistan, small portfolios (small-size companies) outperform big portfolios (large-size companies) on the basis of risk-adjusted returns. For HML (value premium factor), the co-efficient of seven out of sixteen high B/M stock portfolios is positive and statistically significant at the 5% level.
By comparison, the coefficient of six out of sixteen low B/M portfolios is found to be negative and statistically significant and insignificant at the 1 and 5% levels, respectively. The significant and positive relationship of HML to excess portfolio returns in value stock portfolios and significant and negative relationship of HML to excess portfolio returns in growth stock portfolios shows that, in Pakistan, portfolios of value stock (high B/M value stocks) outperform portfolios of growth stocks (low B/M value stocks) based on risk-adjusted returns. In the case of RMW (profitability premium), it is observed that the coefficients for small portfolios (small-size companies) with weak profitability are negative and statistically significant, while those for small portfolios (small-size companies) with robust profitability are positive and statistically significant or insignificant. In the case of RMW for big portfolios, the coefficients are found to be negative and statistically significant for big portfolios (large-size companies) with weak profitability, while the coefficients for big portfolios (large-size companies) with robust profitability are found to be positive and statistically significant or insignificant. The significance and positive relationship of RMW to portfolio returns for robust profitable stock portfolios, and significance and negative relationship of RMW to portfolio returns for weak stock portfolios, shows that portfolio stocks with robust profitability earn higher risk-adjusted returns compared to portfolio stocks with weak profitability. Similarly, investment premium (CMA) coefficients for small portfolios (small-size companies) with conservative investment are found to be positive and statistically significant for thirteen out of sixteen small portfolios. By comparison, for big portfolios (large-size companies) the coefficients are found to be negative and statistically significant for five out of sixteen stocks with aggressive investment. The significance and positive relationship of CMA to portfolio returns of conservative stock and significant and negative relation of CMA with portfolio returns of aggressive stock show that in Pakistan, conservative stocks outperform aggressive stocks on the basis of risk-adjusted returns. In the case of LBR (human capital), it is seen that for fourteen of the sixteen low labor income growth rate portfolios, the coefficients for low labor income growth rate stock are found to be positive and statistically significant, whereas for six out of sixteen portfolios with high labor income growth rates, the coefficients for large stocks are found to be positive or negative, and statistically significant. According to this interpretation, stock portfolios with low labor income growth outperform those with high labor income growth. Out of 32 portfolios, the estimated LBR or human capital component is determined to be statistically significant for 20 portfolios (small and big portfolios sorted from low to high labor income growth rate). This suggests that human capital is an important factor in determining the variation in excess portfolio returns. The adjusted R2 of the HC6FM (human capital six factor model) ranges from 21.75% to 61.13% and represents the variation in excess portfolio returns by market, size, value, profitability, investment, and labor income growth rate premium in the Pakistani stock market. The model is statistically significant overall, and F-statistics and its probability values are shown to be significant at the 5% level for all portfolios.

5. Discussion

The findings of this study are like the following studies and support the previous literature. Acaravci and Karaomer (2017) concluded that FF5FM was valid in the BIST (Borsa Istanbul stock exchange) for capturing variability in asset returns. According to Fama and French (1993), market risk has a significant role in explaining returns above the risk-free rate but does not account for variation in excess stock return. Additionally, they find that small portfolios (small-size companies) have a larger slope for the SMB factor, which measures the effect of size on stock returns, than large stocks. Similarly, Rosett (2001) used two risk variables (namely market and accounting base) and documented that human capital has a statistically positive relationship with equity returns. Wright et al. (2001) and Bontis (2003) documented that human capital must be considered an investment rather than an expense of the company. Furthermore, the authors argue that human capital has a greater influence on determining the value of a company. Shijin et al. (2012) conducted a study on the NIFTY−50 index and found a causal relationship between labor income and asset returns. Iqbal et al. (2013) found that portfolio managers and investors are encouraged to look for modified and multiple variables models instead of relying on CAPM (capital asset pricing model). According to Abbas et al. (2014), in terms of stock returns, small market capitalization companies outperform large market capitalization companies. Similarly, stocks with high BVR (book-to-market-ratio) report higher returns than stocks with low BVR (book-to-market-ratio).
Chowdhury (2017) tested the FF3FM in the Bangladesh stock market. The study found that FF3FM was less explanatory for explaining stock returns in Bangladesh. Zada et al. (2017) compared CAPM, the three-factor model, and the five-factor model, highlighting that FF5FM outperformed other competing asset pricing models. Rashid et al. (2018) found that MKT (market premium), SMB (size premium), and HML (value premium) are significant factors in the Pakistan equity market and concluded that small-size portfolios offer higher returns when compared to big-size portfolio returns. Fletcher (2018) investigated the UK stock market. The effectiveness of the FF5FM and six-factor model was tested in this study. The six-factor model was found to be the most effective in explaining variation in expected stock returns. Chai et al. (2019) tested the FF5FM and Fama–French alternative six-factor model (FF6CP). This study found that the alternative six-factor was superior to FF5FM for explaining the variability in asset returns. Ali et al. (2021) found that, in Pakistan, the profitability factor improves the description of stock returns. However, the authors found that for small portfolios (small-size companies) with negative RMW and CMA (indicating stock behavior of firms that are non-profitable and invest aggressively) and stock with positive RMW and CMA (indicating stock behavior of firms that are profitable and invest conservatively), FF5FM was less explanatory in Pakistan to capture these effects. Khan et al. (2022) tested HC6FM in Pakistan. The authors found that an augmented HC6FM statistically explained the variability in excess portfolio returns.

6. Conclusions

In recent years, the rapid and significant development of emerging markets has globally led to insight from potential investors and academicians seeking to assess these markets in terms of risk inheritance. Such rapid growth and development in emerging markets raises questions regarding unidentified factors that may be different from developed capital markets. Therefore, this study aims to choose the best model for accurately explaining variation in excess portfolio returns. This study collects data on 173 non-financial firms for the period 2010–2020 listed on the Pakistan stock exchange. In order to find an efficient asset pricing model, this study constructs a set of thirty-two portfolios sorted by size, value, profitability, investment, and human capital; these five factors are denoted SMB, HML, RMW, CMA, and LBR and examined along with market risk premium. Furthermore, this study follows Fama and MacBeth’s (1973) regression methodology and regresses the thirty-two portfolios. Descriptive summaries of the portfolios show that, in Pakistan, on average small portfolios (small-size companies) earn considerably higher returns than big portfolios (large-size companies). Ultimately, the risk associated with portfolio returns is higher for small portfolios than for big portfolios, which supports the proposition of Richardson (1970), who argues that “Investors on average earn higher return by taking greater risk, thus, to enjoy broad acceptance throughout the investment community”. According to empirical estimation, CAPM is found to be valid for explaining the variability of market risk premiums above the risk-free rate. FF3FM is also found to be valid for explaining variation in excess portfolio returns. In order to find the most suitable model, we added human capital to FF3FM. The estimated result shows that the human capital-based four-factor model outperforms FF3FM in better explaining the variability in asset returns. We then employed FF5FM and found it to be better for capturing variation on the basis of the adjusted R-square in excess portfolio return than CAPM, FF3FM and the human capital-based four-factor model. Then, we added human capital to FF5FM and proposed the augmented HC6FM. After estimation we found that the human capital-based six-factor model outperformed all the other competing asset pricing models (CAPM, FF3FM, HC4FM, FF5FM) on the basis of the adjusted R-square for explaining variation in excess portfolio return. According to the study findings, small portfolios (small-size companies) earn higher returns than big portfolios (large-size companies) and thus reward investors for taking extra risk. Similarly, excess portfolio returns of high book-to-market ratio stocks are higher than those of low book-to-market ratio stocks. This study encourages future researchers to include human capital in asset pricing models, and encourage investors to consider the human capital factor along with other factors in rational decisions. Furthermore, it is inferred that in the realm of asset pricing, human capital seems to be a vital factor. Therefore, investors are encouraged to take the firm’s investment in human capital into account in addition to other aspects such as size, value, profitability, and investment premium.

7. Limitations and Direction for Future Research

First, this study collected data from 2010–2020. Second, the sample size of the study was not enough to construct traditional portfolios (25 size–value, 25 size–value–profitability, and 25 size–value–profitability–investment portfolios) as specified by Fama and French (1992, 1993, 2015). Third, the scope of this study is limited to Pakistan, which represents one of the emerging Asian economies. Therefore, the result may not be applicable to comparison with developed countries. This study encourages future researchers to test the efficiency and applicability of these competing asset pricing models in developed countries. In addition, study can be conducted on extended sample periods. Moreover, future researchers should consider liquidity and value at risk factor as premiums along with other risk factors.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, N.K. and H.Z.; methodology, N.K. and E.T.; software, H.Z.; validation, N.K., H.Z., E.T. and S.A.; formal analysis, N.K.; investigation, A.I.; resources, N.K.; data curation, H.Z.; writing—original draft preparation, N.K.; writing—review and editing, E.T.; visualization, H.Z.; supervision, E.T.; project administration, E.T. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

Upon request from the corresponding author.

Acknowledgments

We thank the editor of the journal for the full fee waiver in the publication of this article.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

  • Factor Construction
Size Premium (SMB) = 1/16 *[(SLLBCwCCLoi-BHLBCwCcLoi) + (SLLBCwCCHii-BHLBCwCCHii) + (SLLBCwCALoi-BHLBCwCALoi) + (SLLBCwCAHii-BHLBCwCAHii) + (SLLBCRCCLoi)-(BHLBCRCCLoi) + (SLLBCRCCHii)-(BHLBCRCCHii) + (SLLBCRCALoi-BHLBCRCALoi) + (SLLBCRCALoi-BHLBCRCAHii) + (SLHBCWCCLoi-BHLBCWCCLoi) + (SLHBCWCCHii-BHHBCWCCHii) + (SLHBCwCALoi-BHHBCwCALoi) + (SLHBCwCAHii-BHHBCwCAHii) + (SLHBCRCcLoi-BHHBCRCcLoi) + (SLHBCRCcHii-BHHBCRCcHii) + (SLHBCRCALoi-BHHBCRCALoi) + (SLHBCRCAHii-BHHBCRCAHii)]
Value Premium (HML) = 1/16 *[(SLHBCWCCLoiSLLBCwCALoi) + (SLHBCWCCHii-SLLBCwCCHii) + (SLHBCwCALoi-SLLBCwCALoi) + (SLHBCwCAHii-SLLBCwCAHii) + (SLHBCRCCLoi-SLLBCRCCLoi) + (SLHBCRCCHii-SLLBCRCCHii) + (SLHBCRCALoi-SLLBCRCALoi) + (SLHBCRCAHii-SLLBCRCAHii) + (BLHBCwCCLoi-BLLBCwCcLoi) + (BHHBWCCCHi-BHLBCwCcHii) + (BHHBCwCALoi-BHLBCwCALoi) + (BHHBCwCAHii-BHLBCwCAHii) + (BHHBCRCcLoi-BHLBCRCcLoi) + (BHHBCRCcHii-BHLBCRCcHii) + (BHHBCRCALoi-BHLBCRCALoi) + (BHHBCRCAHii-BHLBCRCAHii)]
Profitability Premium (RMW) = 1/16 *[(SLLBCRCcLoi-SLLBCwCcLoi) + (SLLBCRCcHii-SLLBCwCcHii) + (SLLBCRCALoi-SLLBCwCALoi) + (SLLBCRCAHii-SLLBCwCAHii) + (SLHBCRCcLoi-SLHBCwCcLoi) + (SLHBCRCcHii-SLHBCwCcHii) + (SLHBCRCALoi-SLHBCwCALoi) + (SLHBCRCAHii-SLHBCwCAHii) + (BHLBCRCcLoi-BHLBCwCcLoi) + (BHLBCRCcHii-BHLBCwCcHii) + (BHLBCRCALoi-BHLBCwCALoi) + (BHLBCRCAHii-BHLBCwCAHii) + (BHHBCRCcLoi-BHHBCwCcLoi) + (BHHBCRCcHii-BHHBCwCcHii) + (BHHBCRCALoi-BHHBCwCALoi) + (BHHBCRCAHii-BHHBCwCAHii)]
Investment Premium (CMA) =1/16 *[(SLLBCwCcLoi-SLLBCwCALoi) + (SLLBCwCcHii-SLLBCwCAHii) + (SLLBCRCcLoi- SLLBCRCALoi) + (SLLBCRCcHii-SLLBCRCAHii) + (SLHBCwCcLoi-SLHBCwCALoi) + (SLHBCwCcHii-SLHBCwCAHii) + (SLHBCRCcLoi- SLHBCRCAHii) + (SLHBCRCcHii-SLHBCRCAHii) + (BHLBCwCcLoi-BHLBCwCALoi) + (BHLBCwCcHii-BHLBCwCAHii) + (BHLBCRCcLoi-BHLBCwCALoi) + (BHLBCRCcHii-BHLBCwCAHii) + (BHHBCwCcLoi-BHHBCwCALoi) + (BHHBCwCcHii-BHHBCwCAHii) + (BHHBCRCcLoi-BHHBCRCALoi) + (BHHBCRCcHii-BHHBCRCAHii)]
Labor Income Growth Premium (LoMHi) = 1/16 *[(SLLBCwCcLoi)-SLLBCwCcHii) + (SLLBCwCALoi)-SLLBCwCAHii) + (SLLBCRCcLoi-SLLBCRCcHii) + (SLLBCRCALoi-SLLBCRCAHii) + (SLHBCwCcLoi-SLHBCwCcHii) + (SLHBCwCALoi-SLHBCwCAHii) + (SLHBCRCcLoi-SLHBCRCcHii) + (SLHBCRCALoi-SHHBCRCAHii) + (BHLBCwCcLoi-BHLBCwCcHii) + (BHLBCwCALoi-BHLBCwCAHii) + (BHLBCRCcLoi-BHLBCRCcHii) + (BHLBCRCALoi-BHLBCRCAHii) + (BHHBCwCcLoi-BHHBCwCcHii) + (BHHBCwCALoi-BHHBCwCAHii) + (BHHBCRCcLoi-BHHBRCCcHii) + (BHHBCRCALoi-BHHBCRCAHii)]

Appendix B

Portofolio Abbreviations and Descriptions

PortfolioPortfolio Abbreviations/Descriptions
SLLBCwCcLoiCompany with small market capitalization, low BVR, weak profitability, conservative investment and paying low salaries.
SLLBCwCcHoiCompany with small market capitalization, low BVR, weak profitability, conservative investment and paying high salaries.
SLLBCwCALoiCompany with small market capitalization, low BVR, weak profitability, aggressive investment and paying low salaries.
SLLBCwCAHoiCompany with small market capitalization, low BVR, weak profitability, aggressive investment and paying high salaries.
SLLBCRCcLoiCompany with small market capitalization, low BVR, robust profitability, conservative investment and paying low salaries.
SLLBCRCcHoiCompany with small market capitalization, low BVR, robust profitability, conservative investment and paying high salaries.
SLLBCRCALoiCompany with small market capitalization, low BVR, robust profitability, aggressive investment and paying low salaries.
SLLBCRCAHoiCompany with small market capitalization, low BVR, robust profitability, aggressive investment and paying high salaries.
SHHBCwCcLoiCompany with big market capitalization, high BVR, weak profitability, conservative investment and paying low salaries.
SHHBCwCcHoiCompany with big market capitalization, high BVR, weak profitability, conservative investment and paying high salaries.
SHHBCwCALoiCompany with big market capitalization, high BVR, weak profitability, aggressive investment and paying low salaries.
SHHBCwCAHoiCompany with big market capitalization, high BVR, weak profitability, aggressive investment and paying high salaries.
SHHBCRCcLoiCompany with big market capitalization, high BVR, robust profitability, conservative investment and paying low salaries.
SHHBCRCcHoiCompany with big market capitalization, high BVR, robust profitability, conservative investment and paying high salaries.
SHHBCRCALoiCompany with big market capitalization, high BVR, robust profitability, aggressive investment and paying low salaries.
SHHBCRCAHoiCompany with big market capitalization, high BVR, robust profitability, aggressive investment and paying high salaries.
BLLBCwCcLoiBig company with small market capitalization, low BVR, weak profitability, conservative investment and paying low salaries.
BLLBCwCcHoiBig company with small market capitalization, low BVR, weak profitability, conservative investment and paying high salaries.
BLLBCwCALoiBig company with small market capitalization, low BVR, weak profitability, aggressive investment and paying low salaries.
BLLBCwCAHoiBig company with small market capitalization, low BVR, weak profitability, aggressive investment and paying high salaries.
BLLBCRCcLoiBig company with small market capitalization, low BVR, robust profitability, conservative investment and paying low salaries.
BLLBCRCcHoiBig company with small market capitalization, low BVR, robust profitability, conservative investment and paying high salaries.
BLLBCRCALoiBig company with small market capitalization, low BVR, robust profitability, aggressive investment and paying low salaries.
BLLBCRCAHoiBig company with small market capitalization, low BVR, robust profitability, aggressive investment and paying high salaries.
BHHBCwCcLoiBig company with big market capitalization, low BVR, weak profitability, conservative investment and paying low salaries.
BHHBCwCcHoiBig company with big market capitalization, high BVR, weak profitability, conservative investment and paying high salaries.
BHHBCwCALoiBig company with big market capitalization, high BVR, weak profitability, aggressive investment and paying low salaries.
BHHBCwCAHoiBig company with big market capitalization, high BVR, weak profitability, aggressive investment and paying high salaries.
BHHBCRCcLoiBig company with big market capitalization, high BVR, robust profitability, conservative investment and paying low salaries.
BHHBCRCcHoiBig company with big market capitalization, high BVR, robust profitability, conservative investment and paying high salaries.
BHHBCRCALoiBig company with big market capitalization, high BVR, robust profitability, aggressive investment and paying low salaries.
BHHBCRCAHoiBig company with big market capitalization, high BVR, robust profitability, aggressive investment and paying high salaries.

References

  1. Abbas, Nahzat, Jahanzeb Khan, Rabia Aziz, and Zain Sumrani. 2014. A study to check the applicability of Fama and French, Three-Factor Model on KSE 100-Index from 2004–2014. International Journal of Financial Research 6: 90–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Acaravci, Songul Kakilli, and Yunus Karaomer. 2017. Fama-French five-factor model: Evidence from Turkey. International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues 7: 130–37. [Google Scholar]
  3. Akhtar, Samreen Valeed, Ansari Ahmad, Saghir Ansari, and Alam Ahmad. 2022. Fama–French Three-Factor Versus Daniel-Titman Characteristics Model: A Comparative Study of Asset Pricing Models from India. Hindawi 2022: 6768434. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Ali, Fahad. 2022. Testing mispricing-augmented factor models in an emerging market: A quest for parsimony. Borsa Istanbul Review 22: 272–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Ali, Fahad, Usman Muhammad Khurram, and Yuexiang Jiang. 2021. The Five-Factor asset pricing model tests and profitability and investment premiums: Evidence from Pakistan. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 57: 2651–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Ali, Shahid, Muhamad Rafiq, and Saleem Gul. 2015. What determines the yields for treasury bills in Pakistan. FWU Journal of Social Sciences 9: 14–19. [Google Scholar]
  7. Asness, Clifford, and Andrea Frazzini. 2013. The Devil in HML’s Details. The Journal of Portfolio Management 39: 49–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Banz, Rolf W. 1981. The relationship between return and market value of common stock. Journal of Financial Economics 9: 3–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Barillas, Francisco, Raymond Kan, Cesare Robotti, and Jay Shanken. 2020. Model comparison with Sharpe ratios. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 55: 1840–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Basu, Sanjoy. 1977. Investment performance of common stocks in relation to their price-earnings ratios: A test of the efficient market hypothesis. The Journal of Finance 32: 663–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Basu, Sanjoy. 1983. The relationship between earnings’ yield, market value and return for NYSE common stocks: Further Evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 12: 129–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Belo, Frederico, Jun Li, Xiaoji Lin, and Xiaofei Zhao. 2017. Labor-force heterogeneity and asset prices: The importance of skilled labor. The Review of Financial Studies 30: 3669–709. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Bhandari, Laxmi Chand. 1988. Debt/equity ratio and expected common stock returns: Empirical evidence. The Journal of Finance 43: 507–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Bontis, Nick. 2003. Intellectual capital disclosure in Canadian corporations. Journal of Human Resource Cost Account 7: 9–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Campbell, John Y. 1996. Understanding risk and return. Journal of Political Economy 104: 298–345. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Carhart, Mark M. 1997. On persistance in mutual fund performance. The Journal of Finance LII: 57–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Chai, Daniel, Mardy Chiah, and Aangel Zhong. 2019. Choosing factors: Australian evidence. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 58: 101–223. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Chiah, Mardy, Daniel Chai, Angel Zhong, and Song Li. 2016. A better model? An empirical investigation of the Fama-French five-factor model in Australia. International Review of Finance 16: 595–638. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Chowdhury, Emon Kalyan. 2017. Functioning of Fama-French three factor model in emerging stock markets: An empirical study on Chittagong Stock Exchange, Bangladesh. Journal of Financial Risk Management 6: 352–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Crook, Russell, Sam Todd, James Combs, David Woehr, and David Ketchen. 2011. Does human asset matter? A meta-analysis of the relationship between human asset and firm performance. Journal of Applied Psychology 96: 443–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Debondt, Werner F., and Richard Thaler. 1985. Does the stock market overreact? The Journal of Finance 40: 793–805. Available online: http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28198507%2940%3A3%3C793%3ADTSMO%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Q (accessed on 19 February 2022). [CrossRef]
  22. Dutta, Anupam. 2019. Does the five factor asset pricing model have sufficient power? Global Business Review 20: 684–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Edmans, Alex. 2011. Does the stock market fully value intangibles? Employee satisfaction and equity prices. Journal of Financial Economics 101: 621–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Fama, Eugene F. 1970. Efficient Capital Markets: A review of theory and empirical work. The Journal of Finance 25: 383–417. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Fama, Eugene F., and James D. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of Political Economy 81: 607–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 1987. Commodity futures prices: Some evidence on forecast power, premiums, and the theory of storage. The Journal of Business 60: 55–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 1988. Permanent and temporary compnents of stock prices. Journal of Political Economy 96: 246–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. The Journal of Finance 47: 427–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 33: 3–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 2015. A five factor asset pricing model. Journal of Financial Economics 116: 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 2018. Choosing factors. Journal of Financial Economics 128: 234–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Fama, Eugene F., and William G. Schwert. 1977. Human capital and capital market equilibrium. Journal of Financial Economics 4: 95–125. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Fletcher, Jonathan. 2018. Bayesian tests of global factor models. Journal of Empirical Finance 48: 279–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  34. Florensia, Claudia, and Neneng Susanti. 2020. How does the six-factor model do in explaining the relationship between return and risk on the Indonesian stock exchange? Research in Business & Social Science 9: 93–107. [Google Scholar]
  35. Foye, James, and Aljosa Valentincic. 2020. Testing factor in Indonesia. Emerging Market Review 42: 100628. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Frazzini, Andrea, and Lasse Heje Pedersen. 2014. Betting against beta. Journal of Financial Economics 111: 1–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  37. Hair, Joseph F., William C. Black, Barry J. Babin, and Rolph E. Anderson. 2010. Multivariate Data Analysis, 7th ed. New York: Pearson. [Google Scholar]
  38. Haqqani, Kanwal, and Muhammad Aleem. 2020. Testing liquidity augmented Fama-French five-factor model in Pakistan stock exchange. Global Economics Review V: 255–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Hassan, Arshad, and Muhammad Tariq Javed. 2011. Size and Value premium in Pakistan equity market. African Journal of Business Management 5: 6747–55. [Google Scholar]
  40. He, Zhiguo, Kelly Bryan, and Manela Asaf. 2017. Intermediary asset pricing: New evidence from many asset classes. Journal of Financial Economics 126: 1–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  41. Horvath, Dominik, and Yung Wang. 2020. The examination of Fama-French model during COVID-19. Finance Research Letters 41: 101848. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Hou, Kewei, Chen Xue, and Lu Zhang. 2017. A Comparison of New Factor Models. Fisher College of Business Working Paper 2015-03-05. HKUST Finance Symposium 2016: Active Investing and Arbitrage Capital, Charles A. Dice Center Working Paper No. 2015-05. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2520929 (accessed on 6 February 2023). [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  43. Hou, Kewei, Haitao Mo, Chen Xue, and Lu Zhang. 2019. Which factors? Review of Finance 23: 1–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  44. Hua, Ziyue. 2022. A Comparative Analysis of the Fama-French Five-Factor Model. Frontiers in Business, Economics and Management 4: 34–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Huynh, Thanh. 2018. Explaining Anomalies in Australia with a Five-factor Asset Pricing Model. International Review of Finance 18: 123–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Iqbal, Athar, Akhtiar Ali, and Peter Xavier D’Abreo. 2013. Fama and French three factor model application in the Pakistan stock exchange. Journal of Business Studies 13: 1–11. [Google Scholar]
  47. Jagannathan, Ravi, and Zhenyu Wang. 1996. The conditional CAPM and the cross-section of Expected Returns. Journal of Finance 51: 3–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Jagannathan, Ravi, and Zhenyu Wang. 1998. An asymptotic theory for estimating beta-pricing model using cross-sectional regression. Journal of Finance 53: 1285–309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, and Sheridan Titman. 1993. Returns to buying winners and selling losers: Implications for stock market efficiency. The Journal of finance 48: 65–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Jiao, Wenting, and Jean Jacques Lilti. 2017. Whether profitability and investment factors have additional explanatory power comparing with Fama-French three-factor Model: Empirical evidence on Chinese A-share stock market. China Finance and Economic Review 5: 1–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  51. Khan, Naveed, Hassan Zada, and Imran Yousaf. 2022. Do premium exist in the stock market for labor income growth rate? A Six-factor Asset-Pricing Model: Evidence from Pakistan. Annals of Financial Economics 17: 2250017. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Kim, Dongcheol, Tong Suk Kim, and Byoung Kyu Min. 2011. Future labor income growth rate and the cross-section of equity returns. Journal and Banking and Finance 35: 67–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Kostin, B. Konstantin, Philippe Runge, and Michel Charifzdah. 2022. An analysis and comparison of multi-factor asset pricing model performance during pandemic situations in developed and emerging markets. Mathematics 10: 142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Kothari, S. P., and Jay Shanken. 1997. Book-to-market, dividend yield, and expected market returns: A time-series analysis. Journal of Financial Economics 44: 169–203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Kubota, Keiichi, and Hitoshi Takehara. 2018. Does the Fama and French five-factor model work well in Japan? International Review of Finance 17: 137–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Kuehn, Lars Alexander, Mikhail Simutin, and Jessie Wang. 2017. A labor asset pricing model. The Journal of Finance 75: 2131–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  57. Li, Kanlong, and Yanjun Duan. 2021. Research on application of Fama and French three-factor and five factor models in American industry. International Conference on Advances in Optics and Computational Sciences. Journal of Physics: Conference Series 1865: 042105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Lintner, John. 1965. Security prices, risk, and maximal gains from diversification. The Journal of Finance 20: 587–15. [Google Scholar]
  59. Maiti, Moinak, and A. Balakrishnan. 2018. Is human capital the six factor. Journal of Economic Studies 45: 710–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Maiti, Moinak, and Darko Vukovic. 2020. Role of human capital assets in measuring firm performance and its implication for firm valuation. Journal of Economic Structures 9: 1–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Markowitz, Harry. 1952. Portfolio selection. The Journal of Finance 7: 77–91. [Google Scholar]
  62. Martinsa, Clarice Carneiro, and William Eid Jr. 2015. Pricing assets with Fama-French five-factor model: A Brazilian Market Novelty. XV Encontro Brasileiro de Finanças 23: 25. [Google Scholar]
  63. Mayers, David. 1972. Nonmarketable assets and capital market equilibrium under uncertainty. In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets. New York: Praeger Publishers, pp. 223–48. [Google Scholar]
  64. Mosoeu, Selebogo, and Odongo Kodongo. 2020. The Fama-French Five-Factor Model and emerging market equity return. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 85: 56–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Mossin, Jan. 1966. Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market. Econometrica 34: 768–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Nugraha, Farhan, Nurmatias Nurmatias, and Wahyudi Wahyudi. 2022. Analisis Fama French 5 Factors Model Dalam Mempengaruhi Excess Return Saham Pada Lq45. Ikraith-Ekonomika 5: 89–102. [Google Scholar]
  67. Palacios-Huerta, Ignacio. 2003. The robustness of the conditional CAPM with human capital. Journal of Financial Econometrics 1: 272–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  68. Paliienko, Oleksandr, Svitlana Naumenkova, and Svitlana Mishchenko. 2020. An empirical investigation of the Fama-French five-factor model. Investment Management and Financial Innovations 17: 143–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  69. Pantzalis, Christos, and Jung Chul Park. 2009. Equity market valuation of human asset and stock returns. Journal of Bank Finance 33: 1610–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Qin, Jie. 2002. Human-capital-adjusted capital asset pricing model. The Japanese Economic Review 53: 182–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Racicot, Francois E., William F. Rentz, Alfred Kahl, and Olivier Mesly. 2019a. Examining the dynamics of illiquidity risks within the phases of the business cycle. Borsa Istanbul Review 19: 117–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Racicot, Francois E., William F. Rentz, David Tessier, and Raymond Theoret. 2019b. The conditional Fama-French model and endogenous illiquidity: A robust instrumental variables test. PLoS ONE 14: e0221599. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Rashid, Haroon Syed, Mohsin Sadaqat, Khalil Jebran, and Ali Zulfiqar Memon. 2018. Size premium, value premium and market timing: Evidence from an emerging economy. Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Science 23: 266–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Reinganum, Marc. 1981. A Misspecification of Capital Asset Pricing: Empirical Anomalies Based on Earnings Yields and Market Values. Journal of Financial Economics 9: 19–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Richardson, K. Lemont. 1970. Do high risks lead to high returns? Financial Analysts Journal 26: 88–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Rosenberg, Bar, Kenneth Reid, and Ronald Lanstein. 1985. Persuasive evidence of market efficiency. The Journal of Portfolio Management Spring 11: 9–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Rosett, Joshua G. 2001. Equity risk and the labor stock: The case of union contracts. Journal of Accounting Research 39: 337–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Ross, Stephen A. 1976. The Arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. Journal of Economic Theory 13: 341–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Roy, Rahul, and Santhakumar Shijin. 2018. A six factor assets pricing model. Borsa Istanbul Review 18: 205–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Sadhwani, Ranjeeta, Rehman Mujeeb Bhayo, and Ahmed Niaz Bhutto. 2019. A test of five factor model in Pakistan. Pacific Business Review International 11: 42–52. [Google Scholar]
  81. Shaharuddin, Shahrin Saaid, Yeap Wee Lau, and Rubi Ahmad. 2018. Is the Fama and French three-factor model relevant? Evidence from Islamic unit trust funds. Journal of Asian Finance, Economics and Business 5: 21–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Sharpe, William F. 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. The Journal of Finance 19: 425–42. [Google Scholar]
  83. Shijin, Santhakumar, Arun Kumar Gopalaswamy, and Debashis Acharya. 2012. Dynamic risk-return relation with human capital: A study on Indian markets. International Journal of Emerging Markets 7: 146–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Stambaugh, Robert F., and Yu Yuan. 2017. Mispricing factors. The Review of Financial Studies 30: 1270–315. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  85. Susanti, Neneng. 2020. Pengaruh Faktor—Faktor Terpilih Model Penetapan Harga Aset dan Kinerja Perusahaan TerhadapPengembalian Saham Serta Dampaknya pada Nilai Perusahaan di Bursa Efek Indonesia. Bandung: Universitas Pasundan. [Google Scholar]
  86. Swathi, B. 2013. Discrete time asset pricing model with presence of human capital: A study on Indian markets. Financial Markets and Services Emerging Trends 7: 1–78. [Google Scholar]
  87. Tambosi, Filho Elmo, Almir Martins Vieria, and Fabio Gallo Garcia. 2022. Testing conditional CAPM with the inclusion of human capital. Academy of Accounting and Financial Studies Journal 26: 1–8. [Google Scholar]
  88. Tobin, James. 1958. Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk. The Review of Economic Studies 25: 65–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  89. Ulbert, Jozsef, Andras Takas, and Vivien Csapi. 2022. Golden ratio-based capital structre as a tool for boosting firm’s financial performance and market acceptance. Heliyon 8: e09671. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Wahab, Yasir, and Hassan Zada. 2017. Testing Short Term and Long Term Applicability of CAPM: A Case of Pakistani Cement Industry. Research Journal of Finance and Accounting 8: 6–19. [Google Scholar]
  91. Wright, Patrick M., Benjamin B. Dunford, and Scott A. Snell. 2001. Human resources and the resource based view of the firm. Journal of Management 27: 701–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Younus, Mehak, and Hilal Anwar Butt. 2022. Performance of factor models in explaining return patterns: Evidence from Pakistan. Investment Analysts Journal 51: 143–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Zada, Hassan, Arshad Hassan, Muhammad Zeb Khan, and Mustafa Afeef. 2019. An approporiate investment portfolio for stock market investors: Evidence from Pakistan. Sarhad Journal of Management Sciences 5: 343–56. [Google Scholar]
  94. Zada, Hassan, Mobben. Ur Rehman, and Muddasar Ghani Khwaja. 2018. Application of Fama and French five factor model of asset pricing: Evidence from Pakistan Stock Market. International Journal of Economics, Management and Accounting 26: 1–23. [Google Scholar]
  95. Zada, Hassan, Mustafa Afeef, and Arshad Hassan. 2017. Does Fama & French’s five-factor model perform better than the capital asset pricing model and Fama & French’s three-factor model? Evidence from an emerging equity market. Journal of Administrative & Business Studies 2: 1–17. [Google Scholar]
  96. Zaremba, Adam, Alina Maydybura, Anna Czapkiewicz, and Marina Arnaut. 2021. Explaining equity anomalies in frontier markets: A horserace of factor pricing models. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 57: 3604–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  97. Zhang, Qiang. 2006. Human capital weak identification and asset pricing. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38: 873–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Table 1. Descriptive summary of the thirty-two portfolios.
Table 1. Descriptive summary of the thirty-two portfolios.
Excess Portfolio ReturnsMeanMedianMaxMinStd. Dev.SkewnessKurtosis
SLLBCwCcLoi0.0520.0071.303−0.2460.183−0.4185.805
SLLBCwCcHoi0.0280.0130.363−0.1500.1000.9030.943
SLLBCwCALoi0.0210.0090.486−0.2010.1020.9453.291
SLLBCwCAHoi0.0230.0110.352−0.2130.1070.7880.935
SLLBCRCcLoi0.0230.0080.539−0.2290.1051.2814.326
SLLBCRCcHoi0.028−0.0051.060−0.1830.151−0.7435.769
SLLBCRCALoi0.017−0.0020.492−0.2610.1150.8461.660
SLLBCRCAHoi0.0210.0040.405−0.1910.0980.9191.513
SHHBCwCcLoi0.0240.0130.442−0.1730.1091.0492.046
SHHBCwCcHoi0.0230.0061.060−0.2340.147−0.2393.578
SHHBCwCALoi0.0240.0080.526−0.2060.1131.2573.137
SHHBCwCAHoi0.008−0.0070.368−0.1470.0931.0361.418
SHHBCRCcLoi0.0260.0040.414−0.2050.1010.8451.448
SHHBCRCcHoi0.0370.0151.060−0.2180.1503.54519.445
SHHBCRCALoi0.0250.0030.453−0.2320.1150.8431.230
SHHBCRCAHoi0.0150.0050.389−0.2440.1010.5971.915
BLLBCwCcLoi0.0150.0100.423−0.1730.1020.9042.067
BLLBCwCcHoi0.0150.0010.275−0.1780.0830.4670.634
BLLBCwCALoi0.0180.0050.359−0.1940.0921.1282.399
BLLBCwCAHoi0.0210.0160.413−0.2050.0860.9563.454
BLLBCRCcLoi0.0220.0220.255−0.1350.0850.508−0.020
BLLBCRCcHoi0.0210.0060.389−0.2220.0940.8272.020
BLLBCRCALoi0.0160.0140.413−0.2030.0910.9863.048
BLLBCRCAHoi0.0210.0120.341−0.2920.1000.4541.047
BHHBCwCcLoi0.0170.0010.468−0.1420.0941.3343.725
BHHBCwCcHoi0.0350.0120.601−0.1700.1101.7645.724
BHHBCwCALoi0.0260.0230.446−0.2260.1121.0312.637
BHHBCwCAHoi0.0260.0190.330−0.1430.0860.7850.897
BHHBCRCcLoi0.0170.0100.398−0.1550.0860.7982.357
BHHBCRCcHoi0.0220.0110.443−0.1090.0891.6434.706
BHHBCRCALoi0.0290.0140.413−0.2360.1041.0481.888
BHHBCRCAHoi0.0270.0160.471−0.2310.1110.9612.388
Note: Max = Maximum, Min = Minimum, Std. Dev. = Standard Deviation. Description of each portfolio is given in Appendix A.
Table 2. Descriptive summary of the six factors.
Table 2. Descriptive summary of the six factors.
MKTSMBHMLRMWCMALBR
Mean−0.0180.0020.008−0.0080.0040.038
Median−0.011−0.0160.001−0.0040.0020.003
Max0.1290.1730.0640.0840.1950.081
Std. Dev.0.0590.0370.0230.0280.0380.033
Min−0.275−0.066−0.083−0.094−0.122−0.170
S.E0.0050.0030.0020.0020.0030.003
Skewness−0.6181.454−0.208−0.0650.773−1.195
Kurtosis2.3154.0601.1511.2855.8005.598
Note: Max = Maximum, Min = Minimum, S.E = Standard Error, Std. Dev. = Standard Deviation.
Table 3. Correlation matrix of the six factors.
Table 3. Correlation matrix of the six factors.
MKTSMBHMLRMWCMALBRVIF
MKT1 1.017
SMB0.0481 1.153
HML−0.0460.1361 1.096
RMW0.090−0.0250.0901 1.082
CMA−0.1810.305−0.0470.1121 1.195
LBR0.101−0.168−0.230−0.258−0.22611.202
Table 4. Model comparison on the basis of Adj-R2.
Table 4. Model comparison on the basis of Adj-R2.
Portfolio Return CAPMFF3FMH4FMFF5FMH6FM
SLLBCwCcLoi6.70%30.82%36.94%42.35%47.95%
SLLBCwCcHoi20.54%33.14%32.64%39.15%38.62%
SLLBCwCALoi50.83%54.30%59.31%57.96%60.75%
SLLBCwCAHoi27.73%36.68%36.52%43.87%43.45%
SLLBCRCcLoi22.79%27.26%33.82%33.11%45.25%
SLLBCRCcHoi6.02%33.84%42.01%49.08%52.83%
SLLBCRCALoi35.01%42.11%51.76%45.01%53.52%
SLLBCRCAHoi25.43%30.30%33.55%32.26%36.07%
SHHBCwCcLoi24.45%35.50%45.35%40.49%48.93%
SHHBCwCcHoi12.08%44.27%52.10%56.20%61.13%
SHHBCwCALoi23.06%33.40%40.32%42.11%45.13%
SHHBCwCAHoi28.87%41.82%41.31%45.54%45.33%
SHHBCRCcLoi20.27%27.27%30.75%29.41%36.06%
SHHBCRCcHoi10.76%38.66%44.57%55.60%57.08%
SHHBCRCALoi28.72%34.00%41.00%35.23%40.68%
SHHBCRCAHoi31.30%44.12%44.52%49.12%48.92%
BLLBCwCcLoi27.04%29.53%34.22%36.45%39.71%
BLLBCwCcHoi38.98%38.51%37.98%41.07%40.57%
BLLBCwCALoi16.61%15.18%21.50%17.77%21.75%
BLLBCwCAHoi34.25%33.16%32.62%35.99%35.62%
BLLBCRCcLoi30.67%33.58%33.82%36.57%38.07%
BLLBCRCcHoi34.18%33.34%32.94%35.60%35.05%
BLLBCRCALoi37.91%37.27%36.72%38.57%38.23%
BLLBCRCAHoi47.47%46.59%46.40%52.91%52.59%
BHHBCwCcLoi19.23%18.81%23.95%31.23%38.12%
BHHBCwCcHoi15.78%14.83%14.13%24.49%24.11%
BHHBCwCALoi34.55%34.63%40.47%36.93%40.72%
BHHBCwCAHoi22.95%22.17%23.69%26.68%29.65%
BHHBCRCcLoi40.51%39.88%40.17%39.48%39.87%
BHHBCRCcHoi21.27%20.24%21.21%24.55%26.83%
BHHBCRCALoi27.78%30.59%34.45%31.20%37.50%
BHHBCRCAHoi33.99%34.38%34.02%33.65%36.53%
Note: Description of each portfolio is given in Appendix A.
Table 5. Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM).
Table 5. Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM).
InterceptMKTAdj-R2F-Stat
SLLBCwCcLoi0.0370.850.0669.541 **
(2.189) **(3.089) ***
SLLBCwCcHoi0.0120.7830.20531.763 ***
(1.421)(5.635) ***
SLLBCwCALoi0.0131.2350.508124.037 ***
(1.991) *(11.137) ***
SLLBCwCAHoi0.010.9750.277346.662 ***
(1.201)(6.831) ***
SLLBCRCcLoi0.0090.8720.227936.133 ***
(1.031)(6.011) ****
SLLBCRCcHoi0.010.6660.06018.619 **
(0.724)(2.935) **
SLLBCRCALoi0.0081.1720.35165.098 ***
(0.981)(8.068) ***
SLLBCRCAHoi0.0050.8390.25441.582 ***
(0.729)(6.448) ***
SHHBCwCcLoi0.0110.9250.24439.515 ***
(1.223)(6.286) ***
SHHBCwCcHoi0.0090.8930.12717.348 ***
(0.699)(4.165) ***
SHHBCwCALoi0.0170.9440.23536.657 ***
(1.115)(6.054) ***
SHHBCwCAHoi−0.0660.8540.28849.303 ***
(−0.826)(7.021) ***
SHHBCRCcLoi0.0040.7990.20231.256 ***
(0.523)(5.597) ***
SHHBCRCcHoi0.0220.8590.10715.347 **
(1.666)(3.917)
SHHBCRCALoi0.01441.0580.28748.937 ***
(1.545)(6.995) ***
SHHBCRCAHoi−0.0020.9640.31355.221 ***
(−0.318)(7.431) ***
BLLBCwCcLoi0.0010.9130.27145.095 ***
(0.159)(6.715) ***
BLLBCwCcHoi−0.0030.8980.38977.033 ***
(−0.591)(8.776) ***
BLLBCwCALoi−0.0030.6490.16524.701 ***
(−0.048)(4.972) ***
BLLBCwCAHoi0.0060.8490.34262.997 ***
(0.918)(7.937) ***
BLLBCRCcLoi0.0060.8140.30653.641 ***
(0.983)(7.324) ***
BLLBCRCcHoi0.0080.9430.34162.787 ***
(1.154)(7.923) ***
BLLBCRCALoi0.0030.9590.37973.669 ***
(0.484)(8.583) ***
BLLBCRCAHoi0.0121.1720.476108.528 ***
(1.771)(10.417) ***
BHHBCwCcLoi0.0010.7220.19229.326 ***
(0.013)(5.415) ***
BHHBCwCcHoi0.0180.7640.15723.295 ***
(1.896)(4.826) ***
BHHBCwCALoi0.0161.1270.34563.826 ***
(1.919) *(7.989) ***
BHHBCwCAHoi0.0080.7130.22936.437 ***
(1.211)(6.036) ***
BHHBCRCcLoi0.0030.9320.40582.037 ***
(0.557)(9.057) ***
BHHBCRCcHoi0.0040.7020.21233.149 ***
(0.637)(5.757) ***
BHHBCRCALoi0.0150.9370.27746.768 ***
(1.877) *(6.838) ***
BHHBCRCAHoi0.0171.1050.33962.266 ***
(2.014) ***(7.899) ***
Note: T-values are shown in parentheses, while 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels are represented by the symbols *, **, ***, respectively. Description of each portfolio is given in Appendix A.
Table 6. Fama–French Three-Factor Model.
Table 6. Fama–French Three-Factor Model.
InterceptMKTSMBHMLAdj-R2F-Stat
SLLBCwCcLoi0.0390.7422.287−2.1120.30818.673 **
(2.103) **(3.123) ***(6.001) ***(−3.476) ***
SLLBCwCcHoi0.0160.7380.831−1.0820.33120.666 ***
(1.271)(5.775) ***(4.068) ***(−3.309) ***
SLLBCwCALoi0.0121.2130.443−0.6580.54348.135 ***
(1.889) *(11.283) ***(2.588)**(−2.401)**
SLLBCwCAHoi0.0080.9350.844−0.7940.36623.984 ***
(0.995)(6.979) ***(3.939) ***(−2.306) **
SLLBCRCcLoi0.0070.8530.684−0.0710.27215.862 **
(0.816)(6.019) ***(3.031) ***(−0.198)
SLLBCRCcHoi0.0030.6052.1490.2270.33821.291 ***
(0.265)(3.168) ***(7.036) ***(0.465)
SLLBCRCALoi0.0061.1330.774−0.8740.42129.854 ***
(0.792)(8.239) ***(3.522) ***(−2.486) **
SLLBCRCAHoi0.0040.8120.625−0.3930.30318.246 **
(0.518)(6.444)***(3.106)**(−1.222)
SHHBCwCcLoi0.0070.9080.9770.2850.35522.832 ***
(0.929)(6.604) ***(4.482) ***(0.819)
SHHBCwCcHoi0.0020.8581.9781.3970.44232.514 ***
(0.198)(5.013) ***(7.227) ***(3.191) ***
SHHBCwCALoi0.0070.9320.7970.8920.33420.894 ***
(0.859)(6.435) ***(3.441) ***(2.408) **
SHHBCwCAHoi−0.0080.8460.7480.7310.41829.507 ***
(−1.316)(7.656) ***(4.238) ***(2.588) **
SHHBCRCcLoi0.0020.7730.797−0.0780.27215.876 **
(0.247)(5.651) ***(3.644) **(−0.223)
SHHBCRCcHoi0.0150.8271.8691.3470.38625.996 ***
(1.411)(4.534) ***(6.411) ***(2.889) **
SHHBCRCALoi0.0121.0470.6650.5250.33921.433 ***
(1.334)(7.177) ***(2.853) **(1.409)
SHHBCRCAHoi−0.0050.9510.8650.6380.44132.316 ***
(−0.779)(8.091) ***(4.612) ***(2.125) **
BLLBCwCcLoi0.0070.8990.296−0.7670.29517.622 **
(0.092)(6.643) ***(1.382)(−2.236) **
BLLBCwCcHoi−0.0030.8990.102−0.2460.38525.839 ***
(−0.626)(8.647) ***(0.625)(−0.913)
BLLBCwCALoi−0.0040.6490.0120.0240.1518.098 **
(−0.054)(4.915)**(0.066)(0.073)
BLLBCwCAHoi0.0050.8470.041−0.0430.33120.683 **
(0.891)(7.835) ***(0.237)(−0.158)
BLLBCRCcLoi0.0060.7940.228−0.6950.33521.053 ***
(0.942)(7.283) ***(1.309)(−2.494) **
BLLBCRCcHoi0.0080.9390.019−0.2210.33320.839 ***
(1.149)(7.815) ***(0.099)(−0.721)
BLLBCRCALoi0.0030.955−0.022−0.2440.37224.562 **
(0.508)(8.483) ***(−0.126)(−0.848)
BLLBCRCAHoi0.0121.1680.023−0.0710.46535.607 ***
(1.745)(10.287) ***(0.127)(−0.245)
BHHBCwCcLoi−0.0010.7280.0250.3930.18810.192 **
(−0.019)(5.435) ***(0.117)(1.149)
BHHBCwCcHoi0.0180.771−0.0320.3380.1487.907 **
(1.873)*(4.831) ***(−0.127)(0.828)
BHHBCwCALoi0.0151.1310.1770.4950.34622.009 **
(1.827)*(7.988) ***(0.754)(1.132)
BHHBCwCAHoi0.0080.7150.0850.2170.22112.296 **
(1.147)(6.006) ***(0.455)(0.714)
BHHBCRCcLoi0.0030.937−0.037−0.2130.39827.312 ***
(0.589)(8.964) ***(−0.225)(−0.803)
BHHBCRCcHoi0.0050.708−0.1190.1480.20211.065 **
(0.668)(5.754) ***(−0.563)(0.471)
BHHBCRCALoi0.0140.9450.1970.7860.30518.479 **
(1.786)*(7.019) ***(0.919)(2.284) **
BHHBCRCAHoi0.0161.0980.3360.1610.34321.779 ***
(1.879)*(7.841) ***(1.502)(0.458)
Note: T-values are shown in parentheses, while 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels are represented by the symbols *, **, ***, respectively. Description of each portfolio is given in Appendix A.
Table 7. Human Capital Four-Factor Model.
Table 7. Human Capital Four-Factor Model.
InterceptMKTSMBHMLLBRAdj-R2F-Stat
SLLBCwCcLoi0.0280.6632.476−1.6791.4560.36918.427 **
(1.994) *(2.894) ***(6.734) ***(−2.837) **(3.508) ***
SLLBCwCcHoi0.0090.7330.843−1.0560.0870.32615.414 **
(1.243)(5.685) ***(4.063)***(−3.147)***(0.369)
SLLBCwCALoi0.0111.1690.538−0.4420.7250.59344.366 ***
(1.778) * (11.494) ***(3.291) ***(−1.673)(3.909) ***
SLLBCwCAHoi0.0070.9230.871−0.7280.2070.36518.117 **
(0.943)(6.847) ***(4.016) ***(−2.077) **(0.841)
SLLBCRCcLoi0.0050.8010.7980.1880.8730.33816.209 **
(0.641)(5.914) ***(3.665) ***(0.533)(3.535) ***
SLLBCRCcHoi0.0050.6821.971−0.179−1.3650.42822.552 ***
(0.526)(3.793) ***(6.817) ***(−0.382)(−4.163) ***
SLLBCRCALoi0.0041.0690.922−0.5371.1320.51732.915 ***
(0.578)(8.473) ***(4.543) ***(−1.637)(4.919) ***
SLLBCRCAHoi0.0050.8450.549−0.566−0.5820.33516.018 **
(0.688)(6.829) ***(2.758) **(−1.766) *(−2.589) **
SHHBCwCcLoi0.0050.8421.1170.6061.0760.45325.683 ***
(0.734)(6.657)***(5.508)***(1.846)*(4.679)***
SHHBCwCcHoi0.0040.9311.8091.011−1.2990.52133.359 ***
(0.474)(5.837)***(7.049)***(2.434)**(−4.467)***
SHHBCwCALoi0.0050.8780.9211.1760.9550.40321.096 ***
(0.683)(6.371) ***(4.156) ***(3.281) ***(3.801) ***
SHHBCwCAHoi−0.0090.8450.7570.7350.0130.41321.941 ***
(−1.312)(7.576) ***(4.183) ***(2.534) **(0.067)
SHHBCRCcLoi0.0080.7370.8810.1120.6390.30714.211 **
(0.099)(5.491) ***(4.081) ***(0.321)(2.612) **
SHHBCRCcHoi0.0180.8921.7181.001−1.1620.44524.919 ***
(1.694)(5.123) ***(6.129) ***(2.212) **(−3.656) ***
SHHBCRCALoi0.0110.9920.7910.8150.9710.40921.669 ***
(1.184)(7.157) ***(3.549) ***(2.259) **(3.841) ***
SHHBCRCAHoi−0.0060.9330.9030.7240.2930.44524.869 ***
(−0.859)(7.938) ***(4.777) ***(2.368) **(1.353)
BLLBCwCcLoi−0.0060.8520.396−0.5510.7230.34216.476 **
(−0.082)(6.527) ***(1.865) *(−1.629)(3.044) **
BLLBCwCcHoi−0.0030.8910.104−0.2360.0140.37919.214 **
(−0.621)(8.556) ***(0.622)(−0.873)(0.074)
BLLBCwCALoi−0.0010.6070.1150.2470.7490.2159.152 **
(−0.244)(4.752) ***(0.538)(0.745)(3.216) ***
BLLBCwCAHoi0.0050.8440.047−0.0280.0510.32615.401 **
(0.871)(7.733) ***(0.272)(−0.101)(0.257)
BLLBCRCcLoi0.0050.7890.259−0.6240.2380.33816.203 **
(0.872)(7.135) ***(1.473)(−2.195) **(1.192)
BLLBCRCcHoi0.008;0.9460.003−0.257−0.1210.32915.611 **
(1.175)(7.806) ***(0.016)(−0.816)(−0.553)
BLLBCRCALoi0.0030.956−0.023−0.247−0.0090.36718.264 **
(0.507)(8.406) ***(−0.138)(−0.835)(−0.044)
BLLBCRCAHoi0.0121.1770.002−0.118−0.1590.46426.752 ***
(1.784) *(10.293) ***(0.012)(−0.399)(−0.766)
BHHBCwCcLoi−0.0010.6880.1170.6040.7070.23910.369 ***
(−0.194)(5.281) ***(0.559)(1.781) *(2.972) ***
BHHBCwCcHoi0.0180.775−0.0410.318−0.0680.1415.895 **
(1.875) *(4.816) ***(−0.159)(0.;758)(−0.231)
BHHBCwCALoi0.0141.0810.2840.6680.8710.40421.226 ***
(1.706) *(7.966) ***(1.303)(1.894) *(3.525) ***
BHHBCwCAHoi0.0090.7370.0340.104−0.3930.23610.235 **
(1.263)(6.216) ***(0.187)(0.325)(−1.829) *
BHHBCRCcLoi0.0030.916−0.006−0.1420.2370.40120.976 ***
(0.508)(8.806) ***(−0.038)(−0.526)(1.251)
BHHBCRCcHoi0.0040.689−0.0650.2520.3490.2129.006 **
(0.586)(5.599) ***(−0.333)(0.789)(1.556)
BHHBCRCALoi0.0130.9070.2850.9860.6710.34416.632 **
(1.671)(6.897) ***(1.349)(2.882) **(2.798) **
BHHBCRCAHoi0.0151.0890.3570.2080.1580.34216.341 **
(1.834) *(7.715) ***(1.573)(0.568)(0.615)
Note: T-values are shown in parentheses, while 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels are represented by the symbols *, **, ***, respectively. Description of each portfolio is given in Appendix A.
Table 8. Fama–French Five-Factor Model.
Table 8. Fama–French Five-Factor Model.
InterceptMKTSMBHMLRMWCMAAdj-R2F-Stat
SLLBCwCcLoi0.031.0021.773−1.662−1.8621.3110.42318.486 ***
(2.243) **(4.474) ***(4.799) ***(−2.958) ***(−4.036) ***(3.598) ***
SLLBCwCcHoi0.0090.8350.658−0.904−0.8610.4250.39116.314 ***
(1.299)(6.629) ***(3.169) ***(−2.861) **(−3.329) ***(2.077) **
SLLBCwCALoi0.0121.1960.537−0.639−0.576−0.3120.57933.807 ***
(2.005) **(11.262) ***(3.029) ***(−2.405) **(−2.635) **(−1.809) *
SLLBCwCAHoi0.0080.9210.955−0.752−0.879−0.4140.43819.608 **
(1.096)(7.075) ***(4.448) ***(−2.301) **(−3.245) ***(−1.957) *
SLLBCRCcLoi0.0060.9330.4520.0110.2910.7110.33112.782 **
(0.787)(6.651) ***(1.963) *(0.032)(1.012)(3.128) ***
SLLBCRCcHoi0.0020.7841.6460.4120.5931.5420.49823.944 **
(0.205)(4.509) ***(5.766) ***(0.952)(1.664)(5.486) ***
SLLBCRCALoi0.0071.0460.992−0.9870.049−0.6370.45820.479 **
(0.864)(7.565) ***(4.349) ***(−2.843) **(0.172)(−2.833) **
SLLBCRCAHoi0.0040.7390.782−0.5110.373−0.4240.32212.332 **
(0.561)(5.759) ***(3.693) ***(−1.586)(1.412)(−2.034) **
SHHBCwCcLoi0.0070.9890.8280.456−0.9050.3480.40417.195 **
(0.942)(7.314) ***(3.714) **(1.344)(−3.252) ***(1.586)
SHHBCwCcHoi0.0011.0491.4841.6390.0141.4550.56231.541 ***
(0.119)(6.695) ***(5.744) ***(4.169) ***(0.043)(5.712) ***
SHHBCwCALoi0.0080.9160.9260.935−0.998−0.4790.42118.309 **
(0.963)(6.568) ***(4.026) ***(2.672) **(−3.475) ***(−2.114) **
SHHBCwCAHoi−0.0080.7860.9190.666−0.176−0.5180.45520.901 ***
(−1.306)(7.122) ***(5.047) ***(2.405) **(−0.774)(−2.888) **
SHHBCRCcLoi0.0010.8160.661−0.0430.3050.4360.29410.914 **
(0.214)(5.861) ***(2.888) **(−0.123)(1.048)(1.901) *
SHHBCRCcHoi0.0150.9371.4741.4081.2541.2890.55630.804 ***
(1.562)(5.853) ***(5.578) ***(3.504) ***(3.802 ***)(4.949) ***
SHHBCRCALoi0.0121.0090.7890.495−0.294−0.3960.35213.946 **
(1.377)(6.769) ***(3.209) ***(1.323)(−0.957)(−1.635)
SHHBCRCAHoi−0.0050.8591.0970.5220.012−0.6890.49123.974 ***
(−0.756)(7.434) ***(5.752) ***(1.799) *(0.052)(−3.621) ***
BLLBCwCcLoi0.0050.9870.132−0.581−0.9810.3840.36414.652 **
(0.068)(7.511) ***(0.612)(−1.762) *(−3.622) ***(1.799) *
BLLBCwCcHoi−0.0040.952−0.013−0.131−0.4860.2930.41717.587 **
(−0.662)(9.145) ***(−0.079)(−0.502)(−2.266) **(1.737) *
BLLBCwCALoi−0.0030.6510.0570.063−0.566−0.1880.1776.144 **
(−0.037)(4.848) ***(0.261)(0.187)(−2.047) **(−0.864)
BLLBCwCAHoi0.0060.8340.112−0.031−0.448−0.2540.35914.383 **
(0.938)(7.638) ***(0.623)(−0.113)(−1.992) *(−1.432)
BLLBCRCcLoi0.0060.8530.075−0.6240.0660.4710.36514.722 **
(0.916)(7.754) ***(0.388)(−2.263) **(0.294)(2.634) **
BLLBCRCcHoi0.0080.967−0.085−0.2080.3640.3420.35614.156 **
(1.135)(7.939) ***(−0.422)(−0.682)(1.452)(1.728) *
BLLBCRCALoi0.0030.949−0.046−0.2840.4480.1150.38515.942 **
(0.502)(8.252) ***(−0.246)(−0.971)(1.893) *(0.617)
BLLBCRCAHoi0.0121.167−0.046−0.1230.8080.2840.52927.738 ***
(1.825) *(10.607) ***(−0.255)(−0.447)(3.566) ***(1.591)
BHHBCwCcLoi−0.0070.884−0.3090.628−0.6530.9190.31211.807 ***
(−0.099)(6.919) ***(−1.471)(1.967) **(−2.489) ***(4.441) ***
BHHBCwCcHoi0.0180.915−0.3050.591−1.1030.6940.2448.718
(1.942)95.892)(−1.192)(1.517)(−3.449)(2.756)
BHHBCwCALoi0.0161.1070.2720.413−0.509−0.3560.36914.934 **
(1.889) *(7.723) ***(1.152)(1.1494)(−1.724) *(−1.503)
BHHBCwCAHoi0.0080.798−0.0560.356−0.6760.3350.2669.659 **
(1.154)(6.622) ***(−0.257)(1.197) *(−2.726) **(1.728) *
BHHBCRCcLoi0.0030.959−0.099−0.165−0.1540.1680.39416.524 ***
(0.562)(8.923) ***(−0.563)(−0.615)(−0.695)(0.965)
BHHBCRCcHoi0.0040.794−0.3160.267−0.1630.5890.2458.742 **
(0.634)(6.421) ***(−1.551)(0.862)(−0.642)(2.939) ***
BHHBCRCALoi0.0140.9240.2090.7290.4870.0140.31211.794 **
(1.799) *(6.677) ***(0.917)(2.098) **(1.709) *(0.063)
BHHBCRCAHoi0.0161.0810.3910.144−0.096−0.1710.33613.069 **
(1.881) *(7.429) ***(1.632)(0.396)(−0.322)(−0.725)
Note: T-values are shown in parentheses, while 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels are represented by the symbols *, **, ***, respectively. Description of each portfolio is given in Appendix A.
Table 9. Human-Capital Six-Factor Model.
Table 9. Human-Capital Six-Factor Model.
InterceptMKT SMBHMLRMWCMALBRAdj-R2 F-Stat
SLLBCwCcLoi0.0260.9191.809−1.267−1.6461.6151.5440.47719.268 **
(2.121) ***(4.346) ***(5.397) ***(−2.283) **(−3.241) ***(4.324) ***(3.639) ***
SLLBCwCcHoi0.0090.8360.656−0.911−0.8670.422−0.0220.38613.478 **
(1.296)(6.584) ***(3.128) ***(−2.806) **(−3.231) ***(2.025) **(−0.096)
SLLBCwCALoi0.0111.1670.583−0.473−0.417−0.2310.5780.60731.697 ***
(1.876) *(11.322) ***(3.428) ***(−1.798) *(−1.916) *(−1.361)(3.019) ***
SLLBCwCAHoi0.0080.9260.947−0.779−0.896−0.428−0.0940.43416.242 **
(1.115)(7.053) ***(4.368) ***(−2.322) **(−3.238) ***(−1.987) *(−0.386)
SLLBCRCcLoi0.0040.8690.5630.3590.6240.8831.2120.45217.392 **
(0.536)(6.839) ***(2.685) **(1.107)(2.325) **(4.239) ***(5.125) ***
SLLBCRCcHoi0.0040.8321.5560.1290.3221.402−0.9850.52823.214 ***
(0.413)(4.961) ***(5.633) ***(0.302)(0.911)(5.108) ***(−3.171) ***
SLLBCRCALoi0.0040.9911.094−0.6680.354−0.4791.1110.53523.833 ***
(0.635)(7.753) ***(5.186) ***(−2.047) **(1.313)(−2.287) **(4.675) ***
SLLBCRCAHoi0.0050.7720.722−0.6970.194−0.517−0.6490.36612.189 **
(0.756)(6.164) ***(3.494) ***(−2.183) **(0.735)(−2.517) **(−2.792) **
SHHBCwCcLoi0.0050.9360.9230.755−0.6190.4971.0490.48919.999 **
(0.727)(7.442) ***(4.445) ***(2.349) **(−2.329) **(2.408) **(4.4522) ***
SHHBCwCcHoi0.0031.1031.3851.328−0.2831.301−1.0820.61132.191 ***
(0.389)(7.444) ***(5.661) ***(3.506) ***(−0.905)(5.351) ***(−3.931) ***
SHHBCwCALoi0.0060.8810.9881.131−0.811−0.3820.6840.45117.315 **
(0.813)(6.464) ***(4.392) ***(3.249) ***(−2.811) **(−1.707) *(2.705) **
SHHBCwCAHoi−0.0080.7940.9040.621−0.218−0.541−0.1540.45317.443 **
(−1.253)(7.147) ***(4.934) ***(2.191) **(−0.931)(−2.966) **(−0.748)
SHHBCRCcLoi−0.0050.7710.7420.2110.5440.5560.8870.36612.187 **
(−0.006)(5.794) ***(3.379) ***(0.623)(1.936) *(2.551) **(3.587) ***
SHHBCRCcHoi0.0160.9711.4141.2211.0751.196−0.6520.57127.375 ***
(1.729) *(6.135) ***(5.415) ***(3.021) ***(3.216) ***(4.611) ***(−2.219) **
SHHBCRCALoi0.0110.9630.8720.755−0.046−0.2680.9020.40614.599 **
(1.217)(6.715) ***(3.683) ***(2.063) **(−0.151)(−1.141)(3.385) ***
SHHBCRCAHoi−0.0050.8511.1120.5680.056−0.6580.1640.48919.991 **
(−0.795)(7.317) ***(5.786) ***(1.911) *(0.229)(−3.446) ***(0.741)
BLLBCwCcLoi−0.0070.9550.191−0.397−0.8050.4750.6390.39714.063 **
(−0.103)(7.427) ***(0.902)(−1.209)(−2.961) **(2.254) **(2.676) **
BLLBCwCcHoi−0.0040.954−0.017−0.142−0.4960.287−0.0380.40514.539 **
(−0.645)(9.085) ***(−0.098)(−0.531)(−2.237) **(1.668) *(−0.197)
BLLBCwCALoi−0.0010.6180.1160.246−0.399−0.0980.6370.2176.5135 **
(−0.206)(4.704) ***(0.534)(0.732)(−1.406)(−0.454)(2.606) **
BLLBCwCAHoi0.0060.8440.101−0.065−0.481−0.271−0.1190.35611.974 **
(0.972)(7.637) ***(0.558)(−0.233)(−2.068) **(−1.504)(−0.584)
BLLBCRCcLoi0.0050.8330.106−0.5110.1750.5270.3930.38613.191 **
(0.799)(7.631) ***(0.591)(−1.834) *(0.758)(2.943) **(1.938) *
BLLBCRCcHoi0.0080.965−0.081−0.1960.3760.3480.0410.35411.702 **
(1.116)(7.845) ***(−0.402)(−0.626)(1.447)(1.728)(0.181)
BLLBCRCALoi0.0030.943−0.034−0.2420.4850.1340.1320.38213.276 **
(0.457)(8.136) ***(−0.181)(−0.818)(1.981) *(0.706)(0.615)
BLLBCRCAHoi0.0111.162−0.037−0.0940.8360.2990.0990.52622.998 ***
(1.784) *(10.479) ***(−0.203)(−0.335)(3.565) ***(1.643)(0.482)
BHHBCwCcLoi−0.0020.838−0.2320.868−0.4231.0380.8340.38113.217 **
(−0.343)(6.906) **(−1.162)(2.802) **(−1.651)(5.217) ***(3.701) **
BHHBCwCcHoi0.0180.924−0.3230.536−1.1560.667−0.1910.2417.301 **
(1.976) *(5.913) ***(−1.251)(1.342)(−3.498) ***(2.601) **(−0.659)
BHHBCwCALoi0.0141.0710.3410.628−0.303−0.2440.7470.40714.624 **
(1.758) *(7.661) ***(1.478)(1.761) *(−1.029)(−1.065)(2.889) **
BHHBCwCAHoi0.0090.817−0.0980.205−0.8150.266−0.5260.2969.359 **
(1.331)(6.957) ***(−0.509)(0.684)(−3.284) ***(1.352)(−2.412) **
BHHBCRCcLoi0.0030.946−0.075−0.091−0.0810.2060.2630.39814.148 **
(0.477)(8.789) ***(−0.427)(−0.327)(−0.358)(1.168)(1.317)
BHHBCRCcHoi0.0030.769−0.2720.407−0.0320.6580.4850.2688.272 **
(0.504)(6.299) ***(−1.348)(1.303)(−0.117)(3.281) ***(2.135) **
BHHBCRCALoi0.0130.8880.2880.9790.7260.1380.8730.37512.967 **
(1.646)(6.643) ***(1.326)(2.891) **(2.594) **(0.635)(3.533) ***
BHHBCRCAHoi0.0171.0740.4010.175−0.066−0.1550.1090.36510.837 **
(1.845) *(7.339) ***(1.659)(0.469)(−0.214)(−0.648)(0.404)
Note: T-values are shown in parentheses, while 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels are represented by the symbols *, **, ***, respectively. Description of each portfolio is given in Appendix A.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Thalassinos, E.; Khan, N.; Ahmed, S.; Zada, H.; Ihsan, A. A Comparison of Competing Asset Pricing Models: Empirical Evidence from Pakistan. Risks 2023, 11, 65. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks11040065

AMA Style

Thalassinos E, Khan N, Ahmed S, Zada H, Ihsan A. A Comparison of Competing Asset Pricing Models: Empirical Evidence from Pakistan. Risks. 2023; 11(4):65. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks11040065

Chicago/Turabian Style

Thalassinos, Eleftherios, Naveed Khan, Shakeel Ahmed, Hassan Zada, and Anjum Ihsan. 2023. "A Comparison of Competing Asset Pricing Models: Empirical Evidence from Pakistan" Risks 11, no. 4: 65. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks11040065

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop