Next Article in Journal
On Solving the Problem of Finding Kinetic Parameters of Catalytic Isomerization of the Pentane-Hexane Fraction Using a Parallel Global Search Algorithm
Previous Article in Journal
A Flexible Robust Possibilistic Programming Approach toward Wood Pellets Supply Chain Network Design
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Designing of Optimal Reinsurance Indemnity

by
Viktorija Skvarciany
* and
Indrė Lapinskaitė
Institute of Dynamic Management, Vilnius Gediminas Technical University, 10223 Vilnius, Lithuania
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Mathematics 2022, 10(19), 3662; https://doi.org/10.3390/math10193662
Submission received: 26 May 2022 / Revised: 26 September 2022 / Accepted: 4 October 2022 / Published: 6 October 2022
(This article belongs to the Section Financial Mathematics)

Abstract

:
This paper contributes to relevant research in the area of optimal reinsurance indemnity and deals with the risk measures that are used in reinsurance. The research aims at finding optimal reinsurance contracts under different risk levels. The paper has demonstrated that the method of calculating the indemnity of the reinsurance contract discussed in the aforementioned article—the reduction of the square of excess of loss—can be generalised and is valid in all instances where p ∈ (0; 1) ∪ (1; +∞). The results could be useful for the insurance companies calculating indemnities for different cases, as they could state the degrees that fit their needs most.
MSC:
97M30

1. Introduction

There are many different reasons why insurance companies fail. According to Carter [1], some reasons are similar to those in other industries, such as inefficiencies or inappropriate pricing, but the most common failure among insurance companies is an indefinite increase in major expenditures. Therefore, the main role of reinsurance is to protect against potential contingent losses through risk diversification. Stashchuk et al. [2] emphasised that reinsurance not only ensures the stability of the insurers’ development and their safe raising of funds but is also one of the most important measures to ensure effective protection against various natural, man-made or other risks, as well as a fair performance of their obligations as insurers. The need for reinsurance is also directly linked to the regulatory authority’s requirement for insurance companies to control their risk by setting strict risk management policies.
Different optimisation criteria and conditions are calculated by various risk measurement tools. Bernard and Tian used value at risk (VaR) and the conditional tail expectation (CTE) to address the optimal reinsurance task [3]. Other authors have analysed VaR and conditional value at risk (CVaR) in their articles [4,5]. For instance, Zhang et al. [6] used VaR and tail value at risk (TVaR). In addition, Hu et al. [7] used CTE in their study.
The current paper is based on the article “Optimal Reinsurance Arrangements Under Tail Risk Measures” [3] which examines the optimal risk management strategy for an insurance company in light of regulatory constraints. The reduction of the square of large losses used in the article referred to is changed in this article to the p-th degree of losses, and by reducing the p-th degree of excess of loss (The reinsurance contract with an excess of loss provision indicates that the reinsurer is responsible for losses over a certain limit m [8].), the optimal indemnity (Indemnity is compensation to a party for a loss or damage that has already occurred) level of the reinsurance contract is found.
Despite the various risk measures used in reinsurance, this article focuses on and examines one of the methods of calculating reinsurance contract indemnity—the conditional tail—using the VaR margin condition and seeks to find the optimal level of indemnity that would reduce the insurance company’s losses.
The paper consists of three parts. First, the introduction describes the role of reinsurance, the different optimisation criteria and conditions used by the risk measurement tools, and the explanation of the basis on which this research was conducted. The second chapter is dedicated to the calculation of the indemnity of a reinsurance contract and seeks to find the optimal level of indemnity. The propositions and proofs are presented in this chapter. Finally, by comparing and discussing the results in relation to the relevant literature, the final chapter concludes the research.

2. Method

This article examines the methods of calculating the indemnity of a reinsurance contract and seeks the optimal indemnity that would reduce the losses of the insurance company. The study considers a risk measure that is based on the expected p-th degree excessive loss, and this risk is related to the variance tail measure [3]. Tail risk measures are useful as they summarise the extent of potential losses in the worst possible outcomes [9]. Tail risk measures refer to measures that are focused on the behaviour of the tails, such as value at risk. Thus, this work addresses the following problem: to find the optimal level of indemnity I(X), which is solved by:
min I ( X ) { E [ ( W 0 W ν ) p ] 𝟙 W 0 W > ν }   s .   t .   { 0 I ( X ) X ,                   E [ I ( X ) ] = Δ ~ ,                      
where:
Δ —variation,
Δ ~ = Δ 1 + ρ , ρ > 0 ,
W 0 —initial assets of the insurance company (equity, premiums collected from insurance contracts sold),
W —the final assets of the insurance company, if reinsurance has been purchased,
W = W 0 P X + I ( X ) ,
Ν—VaR quantity, i.e., the probability that the loss will exceed ν must be less than the confidence level α ,
X —the total amount of indemnity payable at the end of the period (loss),
I ( X ) —reinsurance contract indemnity,
α —confidence level,
ρ—safety supplement,
P—premium for a reinsurance contract with indemnity I(X).
This task aims to minimise the p-th degree of excessive losses.
Note: In the article of Bernard and Tian [3], the aim of this task was to minimise the square of excessive losses.
Proposition 1.
Assume that X has a continuous, strictly increasing distribution function, X [ 0 ; + ) and PS, S { P : 0 P < E [ ( X ν + P ) + + C ( ( X ν + P ) + ) ] } , where C is the cost function (The cost function is a formula used to predict the cost that will be experienced at a certain activity level.). Let d P   and l P be deductibles (Deductible is the amount of money that the customer is responsible for paying toward an insured loss.), for which the corresponding premiums are P. In that case (1), the solution of the task is indemnity ( X d P * ) + in instances where p ( 1 ; + ) and ( X l P * ) + , and when p ( 0 ;   1 ) , for which P* is the solution to the problem of such minimisation:
min 0 P Δ ~ E [ ( W 0 W P ν ) p 𝟙 W 0 W P > ν ]
with W P being assets after relevant indemnity ( X d P ) + or ( X l P * ) + purchase.
Two auxiliary lemmas (Lemmas 1 and 2) are needed to find the solution.
Lemma 1.
Let p ( 0 ; + ) . Suppose Y * satisfies the following conditions:
 (i) 
0 Y * X ,
 (ii) 
E [ Y * ] = Δ ~ ,
 (iii) 
There exists such a  λ > 0 , such that for each  ω Ω , Y * ( ω ) there is the following optimisation problem solution:
  min Y [ 0 ,   X ( ω ) ] { ( P + X ( ω ) Y ν ) p 𝟙 Y < P + X ( ω ) ν + λ Y } .
Then Y * is the solution to the problem (2).
Proof of Lemma 1.
Let I be the possible indemnity for a reinsurance contract that satisfies the limitations of the optimisation problem.
Let Y * be the optimal indemnity for a reinsurance contract that satisfies all three conditions of the lemma.
Applying condition (iii), the result is that in all cases where ω Ω ,
( P + X ( ω ) Y * ( ω ) ν ) p   𝟙 Y * ( ω ) < P + X ( ω ) ν + λ Y * ( ω )   ( P + X ( ω ) I ( ω ) ν ) p   𝟙 I ( ω ) < P + X ( ω ) ν + λ I ( ω ) .
Thus, we derive that
( P + X ( ω ) Y * ( ω ) ν ) p   𝟙 Y * ( ω ) < P + X ( ω ) ν ( P + X ( ω ) I ( ω ) ν ) p   𝟙 I ( ω ) < P + X ( ω ) ν λ ( I ( ω ) Y * ( ω ) ) .
Next, we calculate the expected values of both sides of the inequality, and based on condition (ii), we obtain
E [ ( P + X Y * ν ) p   𝟙 Y * < P + X ν ] E [ ( P + X I ν ) p   𝟙 I < P + X ν ] λ ( E [ I ( X ) ] Δ ~ ) = 0
This means that
E [ ( P + X Y * ( ω ) ν ) p   𝟙 Y * < P + X ν ]   E [ ( P + X I ν ) p   𝟙 I < P + X ν ] .
The lemma is thus proved. □
Note: In the Bernard and Tian article [3], this lemma was proved, where p = 1 and 2 , but it is correct in all instances where p > 0 .
Lemma 2.
If P ν ,   then each member of the family { Y λ } λ > 0 satisfies conditions (i) and (iii) of Lemma 2.
Here:
Y λ ( ω ) = { 0 ,                                                                                                 i f   X ( ω ) < ν P + ( λ p ) 1 p 1 , X ( ω ) + P ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ,             i f   ν P + ( λ p ) 1 p 1 X ( ω ) ,
when p ( 1 ; + ) and
Y λ ( ω ) = { 0 , if X ( ω ) < ν P , X ( ω ) + P ν , if ν P X ( ω ) ν P + ( 1 λ ) 1 1 p , 0 , if X ( ω ) > ν P + ( 1 λ ) 1 1 p ,
when p ( 0 ;   1 ) .
Proof of Lemma 2.
Let us distinguish two instances:
 I. 
When p ( 1 ; + ) ;
 II. 
When p ( 0 ; 1 ) .
 I. 
When p ( 1 ; + ) .
1. We will demonstrate the inequalities of condition (i) of Lemma 1:
(a)
If X < ν P + ( λ p ) 1 p 1 , then Y λ = 0 , o X 0 .
(b)
If X ν P + ( λ p ) 1 p 1 , then 0 Y λ = X + P ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 X .
From this, we deduce that 0 Y λ X in both instances.
2. We will demonstrate property (iii) of Lemma 1.
Firstly, if 0 X < ν P , then P + X ν < 0 , and the function that needs to be minimised at interval [ 0 ; X ] equals λ Y (see (2)). The latter is increasing in the interval [ 0 ; X ] , since λ > 0 ; therefore, the minimum is reached when Y * = 0 .
On the other hand, if X ν P and P ν , then 0 P + X ν X .
There are two instances:
(a)
If Y [ 0 ; P + X ν ) , then the function to be minimised is
Φ 1 ( Y ) = ( P + X ν Y ) p + λ Y .
We seek the minimum of the latter function:
Φ 1 ( Y ) = p ( P + X ν Y ) p 1 + λ .
We find critical points in the interval [ 0 ;   P + X ν ) :
Φ 1 ( Y ) = 0 , p ( P + X ν Y ) p 1 = λ , ( P + X ν Y ) p 1 = λ p , P + X ν Y = ( λ p ) 1 p 1 .
This point does not necessarily belong to the interval [ 0 ;   P + X ν ) , but Φ 1 ( Y ) increases when Y ( P + X ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ; + ) and decreases when Y ( ;   P + X ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ) .
At the critical point, the value of the function is Φ 1 ( Y ) , and at the left end of interval [ 0 ; P + X ν ) :
Φ 1 ( P + X ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ) = ( P + X ν P X + ν + ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ) p + λ ( P + X ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ) = λ ( P + X ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ) + ( λ p ) 1 p 1 .
Φ 1 ( 0 ) = ( P + X ν ) p
Since 0 P + X ν X , then
( Φ 1 ) m i n = Φ 1 ( Y m i n ) ,   here
Y m i n = max ( 0 ,   X + P ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ) .
(b)
If Y [ P + X ν ,   X ] , then the function to be minimised is Φ 2 ( Y ) = λ Y .
Its minimum is at the point Y = P + X ν , since the function Φ 2 ( Y ) is increasing; hence, its minimum is at the left edge of the interval:
( Φ 2 ) m i n = λ ( P + X ν ) .
Now, ( Φ 1 ) m i n needs to be compared with ( Φ 2 ) m i n . We shall analyse two instances:
 1. 
When 0 < X + P ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 , then
Φ 1 ( Y ) = ( λ p ) p p 1 + λ ( P + X ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ) = ( λ p ) p p 1 + λ ( P + X ν ) λ ( λ p ) 1 p 1 = Φ 2 ( P + X ν ) ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ( λ λ p ) = ( Φ 2 ) m i n λ ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ( 1 1 p ) < ( Φ 2 ) m i n .
 2. 
When 0 X + P ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 , then
( Φ 1 ) m i n = ( P + X ν ) p ,
( Φ 2 ) m i n = λ ( P + X ν ) ,
P + X ν   ( λ p ) 1 p 1 .
Inequality of power ( Φ 1 ) m i n ( Φ 2 ) m i n , when, and only when, 0 P + X ν   λ 1 p 1 , whereas in our case P + X ν   ( λ p ) 1 p 1 < λ 1 p 1 , since p > 1 , which means that Y m i n = Y λ (see (3)), which satisfies condition (iii) of Lemma 1.
 II. 
When p ( 0 ; 1 )
The first part of the proof is analogical to parts (a) and (b) of the proof for Part I of Lemma 2, when p ( 1 ;   ) , but in this instance, we obtain these values:
( Φ 1 ) m a x = Φ 1 ( Y m a x ) ,   here
Y m a x = max ( 0 ,   X + P ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ) .
At the critical point, a maximum is achieved, whereas the task is to minimise the purpose function, which therefore requires a minimum point which can be only at the extremes of interval [ 0 ; P + X ν ) :
Φ 1 ( 0 ) = ( P + X ν ) p ,
Φ 1 ( P + X ν ) = lim Y P + X ν Φ 1 ( Y ) = λ ( P + X ν ) .
Therefore,
( Φ 1 ) m i n = ( P + X ν ) p ,   when
( P + X ν ) p < λ ( P + X ν ) ,
X > ν P + ( 1 λ ) 1 1 p   and
( Φ 1 ) m i n = λ ( P + X ν ) ,   when
( P + X ν ) p   λ ( P + X ν ) ,
X ν P + ( 1 λ ) 1 1 p ,   and
( Φ 2 ) m i n = λ ( P + X ν ) .
From this, it follows that
Y m i n = {   0 ,                 when     X > ν P + ( 1 λ ) 1 1 p , P + X ν ,           when   ν P X ν P + ( 1 λ ) 1 1 p , 0 ,                   when   X < ν P ,                                        
which means that Y m i n = Y λ (see (4)), and that satisfies condition (iii) of Lemma 1. □
Note. Y must not be a negative value; therefore, 0 is chosen when X < ν P .
Proof of Proposition
1. Two auxiliary theorems are needed to prove the proposition.
Lebesgue’s dominated convergence theorem. If f n   ( n = 1, 2, …) are measurable functions, g is a non-negative integral function, | f n ( ω ) | g ( ω ) ( n = 1, 2, …) and f n f , then
lim n I f n ( ω ) d ω I f ( ω ) d ω
Bolzano–Cauchy theorem. If the continuous function f in the segment [ a ; b ] acquires the uneven values f ( a ) = A and f ( b ) = B at the extremities of the segment, then every value C that satisfies condition A < C < B is matched by some point c of the segment [ a ; b ] , such that f ( c ) = C .
From Lemmas 1 and 2, it follows that we must prove the existence of λ > 0, such that Y λ , which is defined in Lemma 2, satisfies condition (ii) of Lemma 1. First, the mean of Y λ must be calculated. There are two instances:
  • ε λ E ( Y λ ) = E ( ( X + P ν ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ) 𝟙 X ν P + ( λ p ) 1 p 1 ) (see (3)),
  • δ λ E ( Y λ ) = E ( ( X + P ν ) 𝟙 ν P X ν P + ( 1 λ ) 1 1 p ) (see (4)).
We see that
lim λ 0 + ε λ = E ( ( X + P ν ) + )   and lim λ + ε λ = 0
That is to say, P ( 0 ;   E ( X + P ν ) + ) .
We will prove that ε λ is a continuing function, i.e., lim λ λ 0 ε λ = ε λ 0 , here λ 0 > 0 .
From the assumption that the distribution of X is continuous, it flows that the distribution of Y λ is also continuous.
Based on Lebesgue’s theorem of dominated convergence, we can assert that | Y λ | | Y 0 | , where Y 0 is an integrable non-negative function. From this, it follows that
lim λ λ 0 ε λ = lim λ λ 0 E ( Y λ ) = E Y 0 = ε λ 0 .
Since ε λ is a continuous function, and 0 < P < E ( X + P ν ) + , based on the Bolzano–Cauchy theorem, it can be asserted that it fully completes the interval and that therefore there is a solution λ * + * satisfying the equation ε λ = E [ I ( X ) ] = Δ ~ .
We see that
lim λ 0 + δ λ = E ( ( X + P ν ) + )   and lim λ + δ λ = 0
From here on, the proof is analogical to that demonstrated in the first instance; i.e., there is a solution λ * + * satisfying the equation ε λ = E [ I ( X ) ] = Δ ~ .
The proposition is proved. □

3. Discussion and Conclusions

Considering the results of the research in the research area of optimal reinsurance indemnity, the variety of approaches should be emphasised. The first research started in the 1960s when Borch [10] elucidated that reinsurance is optimal when the reinsurance premium is set according to the expected value premium principle, which is supported by Arrow [11]. Kaluszka [12] has derived optimal reinsurance under premium principles considering the variance of the retained loss as the function to be minimised. Later on, Kaluszka [13] calculated the reinsurance premium based on the expectation and variance of the total risk, and continued his research by applying many different convex premium principles, including TVaR [14]. The combination of VaR and CTE as risk measures was used by Cai and Tan [15]. Balbas et al. [16] analysed whether the classical reinsurance contracts could be optimal and proved that the optimal reinsurance problem could be solved by providing the optimal conditions for general risk measures. Chi [4] and Chi and Tan [5] asserted that the optimal layer reinsurance is always optimal under VaR and CVaR criteria. VaR and TVaR as criteria were applied by Zhang et al. [17] and Zhang et al. [6] concerning winning mutual benefits for both sides, insurer and reinsurer. CTE, as a condition in combination with Wang’s premium principle, was analysed by Hu et al. [7]. To outline, it could be noticed that risk measures such as VaR, CTE and TVaR are used and analysed frequently under miscellaneous conditions. The current article contributes to the variety of approaches by adapting and expanding the research performed by Bernard and Tian [3], who found the optimal indemnity I(X) by minimising the square of excess loss.
To conclude, this article’s goal—to find the optimal indemnity I(X), which minimises the p-th degree of excess loss—was achieved. One of the methods of calculating the reinsurance contract indemnity was considered: the conditional tail expectation using the VaR condition is different from the one used in Bernard and Tian’s (2009) article on reducing the square of excessive losses. It can be argued that the optimal indemnity has been found, and the losses of the insurance company would be reduced. The results could be useful for insurance companies calculating indemnities for different cases, as they could state the degrees that fit their needs most.
However, solving the mentioned problems, the dynamism of the pension ecosystem and the uncertainty of economic growth cannot be ignored. In future research, such an analysis should consider other potential risk measures, premium principles and changing regulatory constraints.

Author Contributions

Conceptualisation, V.S. and I.L.; methodology, V.S. and I.L.; software, V.S.; validation, V.S. and I.L.; formal analysis, V.S. and I.L.; investigation, V.S. and I.L.; resources, V.S. and I.L.; data curation, V.S. and I.L.; writing—original draft preparation, V.S. and I.L.; writing—review and editing, V.S. and I.L.; supervision, V.S.; project administration, V.S. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Carter, R.L. Reinsurance; Springer Science & Business Media: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  2. Stashchuk, O.; Borysyuk, O.; Datsyuk-Tomchuk, M. The Problems of the Domestic Reinsurance Development in Conditions of Financial Instability. Financ. Credit. Act. Probl. Theory Pract. 2021, 3, 154–161. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Bernard, C.; Tian, W. Optimal Reinsurance Arrangements Under Tail Risk Measures. J. Risk Insur. 2009, 76, 709–725. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Chi, Y. Optimal reinsurance under variance related premium principles. Insur. Math. Econ. 2012, 51, 310–321. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Chi, Y.; Tan, K.S. Optimal reinsurance with general premium principles. Insur. Math. Econ. 2013, 52, 180–189. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Zhang, N.; Qian, L.; Jin, Z.; Wang, W. Optimal stop-loss reinsurance with joint utility constraints. J. Ind. Manag. Optim. 2021, 17, 841–868. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Hu, S.; Hu, X.; Hu, J. The Optimal Reinsurance Strategy under Conditional Tail Expectation (CTE) and Wang’s Premium Principle. Math. Probl. Eng. 2021, 2021, 1–6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Li, P.; Zhou, M.; Yao, D. Optimal time for the excess of loss reinsurance with fixed costs. Int. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2022, 79, 466–475. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Fairbrother, J.; Turner, A.; Wallace, S.W. Problem-driven scenario generation: An analytical approach for stochastic programs with tail risk measure. Math. Program. 2022, 191, 141–182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Borch, K. An attempt to determine the optimum amount of stop-loss reinsurance. In Proceedings of the Transactions of the 16th International Congress of Actuaries, Brussels, Belgium, December 1960; pp. 597–610. [Google Scholar]
  11. Arrow, K.J. Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. Am. Econ. Rev. 1963, 53, 941–973. [Google Scholar]
  12. Kaluszka, M. Optimal reinsurance under mean-variance premium principles. Insur. Math. Econ. 2001, 28, 61–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Kaluszka, M. An extension of Arrow’s result on optimality of a stop loss contract. Insur. Math. Econ. 2004, 35, 527–536. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Kaluszka, M. Optimal reinsurance under convex principles of premium calculation. Insur. Math. Econ. 2005, 36, 375–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Cai, J.; Tan, K.S. Optimal Retention for a Stop-loss Reinsurance under the VaR and CTE Risk Measures. ASTIN Bull. 2007, 37, 93–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Balbás, A.; Balbás, B.; Heras, A. Optimal reinsurance with general risk measures. Insur. Math. Econ. 2009, 44, 374–384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Zhang, N.; Jin, Z.; Qian, L.; Wang, R. Optimal quota-share reinsurance based on the mutual benefit of insurer and reinsurer. J. Comput. Appl. Math. 2018, 342, 337–351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Skvarciany, V.; Lapinskaitė, I. Designing of Optimal Reinsurance Indemnity. Mathematics 2022, 10, 3662. https://doi.org/10.3390/math10193662

AMA Style

Skvarciany V, Lapinskaitė I. Designing of Optimal Reinsurance Indemnity. Mathematics. 2022; 10(19):3662. https://doi.org/10.3390/math10193662

Chicago/Turabian Style

Skvarciany, Viktorija, and Indrė Lapinskaitė. 2022. "Designing of Optimal Reinsurance Indemnity" Mathematics 10, no. 19: 3662. https://doi.org/10.3390/math10193662

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop