Next Article in Journal
A Model of Urban and Socio-Technical Participation: Between Deliberative Democracy and Strong Governance—The Case of the City of Messina
Next Article in Special Issue
The Changes of Desertification and Its Driving Factors in the Gonghe Basin of North China over the Past 10 Years
Previous Article in Journal
Smart Land Governance: Towards a Conceptual Framework
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Impact of Land Transfer on Vulnerability as Expected Poverty in the Perspective of Farm Household Heterogeneity: An Empirical Study Based on 4608 Farm Households in China
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Does Environmental Decentralization Affect the Supply of Urban Construction Land? Evidence from China

1
School of Economics, Sichuan University, Chengdu 610065, China
2
Department of Land Resource and Real Estate Management, School of Public Administration, Sichuan University, Chengdu 610065, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Land 2023, 12(3), 601; https://doi.org/10.3390/land12030601
Submission received: 10 February 2023 / Revised: 26 February 2023 / Accepted: 1 March 2023 / Published: 3 March 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Rethinking the Man-Land Relations in China)

Abstract

:
Against the background of Chinese decentralization, the preferences and choices of local governments significantly affect the scale and structure of urban construction land supply. Due to the shortage of financial funds and the political performance pursuit of local governments, environmental decentralization gives local governments greater autonomy in environmental management, and increases the possibility for local governments relying on land transfer income to make up for the financial gap and provide public goods and services. This paper analyses the impact of environmental decentralization on the construction land supply scale of local government based on the panel data of 30 provinces in China from 2003 to 2015. The results indicate that: (1) environmental decentralization has a positive effect on the increase in urban construction land supply scale; (2) environmental decentralization affects urban construction land supply by strengthening land financial dependence and distorting land resources misallocation; (3) there are regional disparities in the effect of environmental decentralization on urban construction land supply. The impact is greater in regions with high financial pressure, high economic growth pressure, and low environmental protection pressure. In summary, some policy suggestions are put forward to reasonably supply urban construction land against the background of Chinese decentralization.

1. Introduction

Land resources are extremely important for ensuring food security, facilitating economic development, and protecting the ecological environment [1,2]. Urbanization has accelerated the conversion of agricultural land around cities to non-agricultural construction uses, which is a common problem faced by the whole world [3,4]. This phenomenon is particularly acute in developing countries, such as India and China [5]. Over the years, the important role of land in China’s rapid economic development cannot be ignored. A great deal of construction land has been provided by the Chinese government to support urbanization and industrialization [6]. According to data from the “China urban construction statistical yearbook”, the area of urban construction land in China increased from 6720 km2 to 52,761.3 km2, with an average annual growth of 6.06%, from 1981 to 2016. In contrast, this rate of urban population growth over the same period was only 2.98%. However, economic growth that heavily relies on land not only causes many social problems such as land finance, illegal land use, inefficiency of industrial land, and soaring housing prices [7], but also leads to environmental problems, such as declining biodiversity and environmental pollution [8]. Governments are working to curb urban sprawl through environmental regulation [9,10,11,12,13].
In response to environmental problems, including those caused by urban sprawl and land resources misallocation, the Chinese government has adopted a decentralized management model (environmental federalism) [14]. In other words, central and local governments share environmental management powers. Local governments are responsible for specific matters of environmental management, including pollution prevention, ecological protection, and environmental access management. The central government is responsible for supervising and coordinating local governments. According to Environmental Protection Law of the People’s Republic of China, all factors affecting human survival and development are the objects of environmental management, including natural elements (atmosphere, water, land, etc.), as well as artificial transformation elements (nature reserves, urban and rural areas, etc.) [15]. In terms of land use management, the improvement of central environmental protection supervision has prompted local governments to rationally plan the scale and structure of construction land supply, and the supply of highly polluting industrial land has been restricted. Statistics show that the supply area of construction land gradually declined after reaching a peak of 374,804.03 hm2 in 2013; the proportion of the land transferred by agreement plummeted from 50.08% in 2007 to 16.06% in 2008 (the agreed transfer can reflect the supply of industrial land) [16]. This suggests that changes in local government autonomy alter the allocation of resources. This phenomenon also exists in other locations worldwide, such as Montpellier (France), Rome (Italy), and Jakarta (Indonesia), where the expansion of construction use is also affected by decentralization [17,18].
Construction land expansion is a complex issue. In addition to environmental regulations, there are many factors that affect the expansion of urban construction land, including land use planning, land systems, public policy, etc. [19,20]. The factors influencing the supply of construction land under China’s unique institutional background are particularly complex. First, the Chinese government is the sole subject of land acquisition and transfer. The government can obtain most of the land appreciation profits by acquiring land at a low price and selling it at a high price [21]. Therefore, they intervene in the scale and structure of urban construction land supply according to their own interests [22,23,24]. Second, fiscal decentralization and political centralization increase incentives for local government officials to sell land for fiscal revenue and political performance [25,26,27,28,29], resulting in an excessive supply of urban construction land [30]. In addition, some factors, such as economic development level, population size, and industrial structure, can also affect the government’s land supply [31,32,33].
With the advancement of urbanization around the world, curbing the disorderly expansion of cities and determining the reasonable scale of urban construction land supply are common concerns for all countries [34,35]. The government plays an important role in controlling the scale and structure of construction land supply. The scale of construction land supply is the result of the government’s resource allocation after comprehensive consideration of various factors, such as environmental protection and economic development. Decentralization affects the allocation of resources by changing the government’s autonomy in the choice of economic, political, environmental, and other goals. How to design the administrative management system to achieve better allocation of resources by the government has attracted much attention. Our research provides Chinese experience for this. Some of the literature has analyzed the logic of massive land supply by local governments under the background of fiscal decentralization and political centralization. However, the impact of the environmental protection assessment requirements of the central government and the evolution of the environmental management system on construction land supply by local governments has not been paid attention to. Therefore, this paper incorporates environmental decentralization into the framework of Chinese decentralization and analyzes the influence of environmental decentralization on local government land supply. The main issues addressed in this paper include: (1) Does environmental decentralization affect local government urban construction land supply? (2) How does environmental decentralization affect the supply of urban construction land by local government? (3) Is there regional difference in the influence of environmental decentralization on urban construction land supply? Compared with the existing research of scholars, this paper proposes innovations in the following aspects: (1) environmental decentralization is incorporated into the Chinese decentralization framework, which expands the Chinese decentralization system. (2) Based on the Chinese decentralization framework, the urban construction land supply behaviors of local governments are analyzed. The impact of environmental decentralization on urban construction land supply is emphatically analyzed, which provides a new concept for studying the influencing factors of local government land supply. (3) Combined with the incentive mechanism of urban construction land supply under Chinese decentralization, the impact of environmental decentralization on land supply in regions with different financial pressure, economic growth pressure, and environmental protection pressure is considered, which provides policy directions for coordinating economic development and environmental protection.

2. Institutional Background and Theoretical Hypothesis

2.1. Institutional Background

China has a unique institutional background of fiscal decentralization and political centralization, which is different from the fiscal decentralization and federal political system of Western countries [36]. In terms of finance, China implements a tax-sharing system, and the fiscal budgets of governments at all levels are relatively independent. This means that local governments have certain economic decision-making power and can govern according to their own preferences [37]. In terms of politics and bureaucracy, China is in power with one party and implements vertical management with upward responsibility, which forms a multi-departmental M-shaped hierarchy [38,39]. The superior (or central) government has the right to appraise the performance of local government officials and decide on their promotion [40].
Corresponding to the delegated powers, China implements a decentralized environmental management system [41]. That is, environmental decentralization. Environmental decentralization originates from environmental federalism, which studies the environmental management functions of all levels of government [42]. In the “pyramid” system, where the central government is located above and the local governments are located below, local governments are authorized to participate in environmental management affairs [43]. It is generally believed that environmental centralization can effectively control cross-regional pollution, and that environmental decentralization is more flexible and targeted [44,45,46,47]. Since the reform and opening up in 1978, the evolution of environmental decentralization in China can be divided into three stages [48]. The first stage was from 1978 to 1993. During this stage, financial and administrative powers were highly decentralized, and the degree of environmental decentralization was high. The central government lacked supervision over local environmental affairs. The second stage was from 1994 to 2007. During this stage, with the increase in central government’s fiscal revenue, the environmental management powers of central government improved, and the degree of environmental decentralization decreased. The third stage is from 2008 to the present. With the adjustment of the government environmental protection institutions and the increased emphasis on environmental protection, the central government decentralized environmental administrative power and enhanced environmental supervision power and environmental governance incentives. Several instances in the literature have confirmed the beneficial effects of environmental decentralization in China, including promoting green development and pollution control [49,50]. However, some scholars believe that the institutional background of fiscal decentralization and political centralization in China makes the incentives and constraints of local government environmental protection mismatched. When decentralizing environmental rights, local governments will relax environmental control, which forms a race to the bottom and aggravates environmental pollution [51,52].
The fiscal decentralization, political centralization, and environmental decentralization implemented in China can be summarized as Chinese decentralization.

2.2. Theoretical Hypothesis

The institutional arrangement of Chinese decentralization affects the construction land supply by local government in three aspects: fiscal decentralization, political centralization, and environmental decentralization. In terms of fiscal decentralization, the 1994 tax-sharing reform led to a misalignment of the executive and fiscal powers of the government [53]. Fiscal revenues flow upwards to the central government, and the responsible affairs remain in the local government, resulting in a huge fiscal gap [54,55]. Decentralization has led local governments to provide land for construction to ease fiscal pressures and cover fiscal deficits. This is manifested in the expansion of fiscal revenue through “land rent” and “land tax” [56]. The “land rent” refers to the one-time income obtained by transferring land. Selling commercial and residential land at a high price can obtain more “land rent” [57,58]. The “land tax” refers to attracting investment by selling industrial land at low prices, and developing industries to obtain continuous tax revenue [59]. When it comes to political centralization, Chinese officials are usually accountable to the top. Local government officials are promoted through excellent performance appraisals [60]. Economic growth is the core of performance measurement, so there is fierce competition around GDP growth [61,62,63]. In order to win the GDP championship, local governments often sell industrial land at reserve prices or free of charge to attract investment and promote economic growth, which increases the supply of construction land [28,29]. The importance of environmental indicators in performance appraisals has increased in recent years, which limits the expansion of construction land [36]. Environmental decentralization affects the supply of construction land by relaxing or tightening environmental constraints after weighing the importance of economic growth and environmental protection. After incorporating environmental decentralization into the Chinese decentralization framework, the incentives and constraints of local government construction land supply are shown in Figure 1.
Under the specific institutional background of Chinese decentralization, environmental decentralization gives local governments greater autonomy in choosing economic development goals and environmental protection goals [64]. Local governments’ economic incentives and political incentives do not match the environmental protection constraints, which causes local governments to prioritize economic growth over environmental welfare. Local governments ignore environmental issues and supply a great deal of construction land to generate revenue and boost the economy.
Hence, the first hypothesis is obtained: environmental decentralization will increase the urban construction land supply by local government.
When environmental management power is decentralized, the local government will compare the importance of economic incentives, political incentives, and environmental constraints. Against the background of the shortage of local government’s fiscal revenue and the pursuit of political performance, environmental decentralization increases the motivation of local governments to pursue “land rent”, “land tax”, and “attracting investment from land”, so that local governments reduce environmental protection requirements. This leads to the intensification of the local government’s land financial dependence and land resources misallocation. Thus, the scale of construction land supply is increased.
Hence, the second hypothesis is obtained: environmental decentralization increases the urban construction land supply scale of local governments by increasing land financial dependence and land resources misallocation.
Environmental decentralization affects construction land supply by changing the economic incentives, political incentives, and environmental constraints of local governments. Therefore, in regions with different financial pressures, economic growth pressures, and environmental protection pressures, the incentives and constraints of land supply are also distinct. In regions with high financial pressure, local governments have stronger economic incentives. When environmental power is decentralized, there is a stronger incentive to provide a great deal of land at the expense of the environment [65]. In regions with high economic growth pressure, local governments have a stronger motivation to attract investment by land [66,67]. Environmental decentralization will increase the supply of industrial land, which expands the scale of construction land supply. In regions with high environmental protection pressures, local governments have stricter constraints on the preservation of the environment. When environmental power is devolved, local governments will optimize local environmental management and limit the scale of land supply [68].
Hence, the third hypothesis is obtained: there are regional disparities in the effects of environmental decentralization on urban construction land supply. In the regions with high financial pressure, high economic growth pressure, and low environmental protection pressure, the impact of environmental decentralization on construction land supply is more significant.

3. Research Design

3.1. Model Settings

In the context of Chinese decentralization, environmental, fiscal decentralization, and political centralization jointly affect the urban construction land supply by local governments. Thus, the following fixed-effect model is established [50].
L S i t = β 0 + β 1 E D i t + β 2 F D i t + β 3 F A I i t + β 4 I P C i t + β i X i t + θ i + μ t + ε i t
where L S i t is the explained variable, representing construction land supply; E D i t is the explanatory variable, representing environmental decentralization; F D i t is fiscal decentralization; F A I i t and I P C i t are fixed asset investment and environmental protection investment, respectively, representing political centralization; X i t are other control variables, including per capita GDP, population, urbanization rate of land, the proportion of secondary and tertiary industries, financial pressure; i and t represent the provinces and periods under consideration, respectively; β 0 is the constant term; β 1 β i are coefficients; θ i and μ t represent the province and time effects, respectively; ε i t is the random error term. In order to make the data smoother and reduce heteroscedasticity, the non-proportional data are dealt with as logarithms.

3.2. Variable Selection

(1) Explained variable. The construction land supply scale is used to describe the construction land supply behavior of local government. The data sources of urban construction land supply in the existing literature mainly include the “China Land and Resources Statistical Yearbook” [33], the land survey results sharing application service platform, and the network of “landchina” [69,70]. Among them, the time span of the data in the “China Land and Resources Statistical Yearbook” is relatively long. Therefore, this paper uses the construction land transfer area in the “China Land and Resources Statistical Yearbook” to express the scale of land supply.
(2) Explanatory variable. Environmental decentralization reflects the functional division of central and local governments in environmental management affairs. The higher the degree of environmental decentralization, the greater the authority of local governments in environmental affairs. Referring to the existing literature, the relative personnel number of environmental protection agencies at all levels is used to calculate environmental decentralization [71,72]. The calculation formula for environmental decentralization is as follows.
E D i t = [ L E P P i t / P O P i t N E P P t / P O P t ] × [ 1 ( G D P i t G D P t ) ]
where E D i t is environmental decentralization; L E P P i t , P O P i t , G D P i t are the personnel number of environmental protection agencies, population, and gross domestic product of province i in year t ; L E P P t , P O P t , G D P t are the number of personnel in environmental protection agencies, population, and gross domestic product of whole country in year t ; ( 1 G D P i t / G D P t ) is the economic scaling factor for reducing endogenous interference [73].
(3) Control variables. Under the framework of Chinese decentralization, the impact of fiscal decentralization and political centralization on land supply cannot be ignored. Therefore, three special control variables were selected, including fiscal decentralization, fixed asset investment per unit of GDP, and industrial pollution control completed investment. Fiscal decentralization typically includes revenue decentralization and expenditure decentralization [74]. Fiscal revenue incentives can increase local government construction land supply. Thus, this paper uses fiscal revenue decentralization. Fixed assets investment is used to represent the promotion incentives of political centralization [75], and industrial pollution control completed investment is used to represent the environmental constraints of political centralization [76]. For the control of other social and economic factors, referring to the research of Wang (2015), Zhou (2019), and Li (2021) [32,33,50], six control variables are selected from the five aspects: economic development, population size, urban expansion, industrial structure, and financial pressure. Specific indicators include the per capita GDP and its square, population, land urbanization rate, the proportion of secondary and tertiary industries, and financial pressure.
The contents of the variables are shown in Table 1.

3.3. Data Sources

Since the personnel number of environmental protection agencies at provincial level has only been updated to 2015, the panel data of 30 provinces (Hong Kong, Macao, Taiwan, and Tibet are not included) from 2003 to 2015 are used for analysis. The data on urban construction land supply area and land transfer income are from the “China Land and Resources Statistical Yearbook (2004–2016)”. The data on the number of employees in environmental protection agencies are from the “China Environmental Yearbook (2004–2016)”. Other data are from the provincial annual database on the website of the “National Bureau of Statistics of China”. The descriptive statistics of the variables are shown in Table 2.
The spatiotemporal evolution of urban construction land supply and environmental decentralization is plotted in Figure 2.
Figure 2(a1,a2) shows that there is more construction land supply in the east than in the west, and the land supply in the Yangtze River Delta and Pearl River Delta is the largest. From 2003 to 2015, land supply in some provinces in the central and western regions of China increased. Figure 2(b1,b2) shows that the provinces closer to the capital (Beijing) have a higher degree of environmental decentralization. From 2003 to 2015, environmental decentralization in the central region decreased, while it marginally increased in the western region.

4. Empirical Results

4.1. Basic Estimation Results

For fear of unrealistic regression results, it is necessary to check that the data is stable before regression. Since this paper uses short panel data, the LLC unit root test is used. The test results indicate that the data used for regression are all stationary. The basic estimation results are shown in Table 3. FE1 is the estimation result of adding no control variables, and FE2 and FE3 are the estimation results of gradually adding special control variables and other control variables.
The regression results in Table 3 show that after adding all control variables, the coefficient of environmental decentralization is significant, at the level of 5%, which indicates that environmental decentralization increases the scale of construction land supply. The effect of fiscal decentralization is positive, at a 1% significance level, suggesting that the greater financial autonomy of local governments, the stronger the motivation to provide a great deal of construction land. The coefficient of fixed asset investment per unit of GDP is positive, at a 1% significance level, suggesting that the scale of construction land supply is expanding due to the competition of local governments to attract investment. The effect of industrial pollution control investment is negative, at a 5% significance level, indicating that environmental protection constraints limit the expansion of construction land supply. The coefficient of square per GDP is markedly negative, at the level of 1%, indicating that there is an inverted U-shaped Kuznets curve relationship between economic development and construction land supply. The scale of construction land supply first increases and then decreases with economic growth. The proportion of secondary and tertiary industries is significantly negative, at the level of 1%, indicating that industrial structure upgrading can reduce construction land supply. The effect of local government financial pressure on land supply is markedly positive, at the level of 5%, indicating that the greater financial pressure, the more construction land supply. Population size and land urbanization have a positive influence on construction land supply, but they are not significant enough.

4.2. Robustness Test

To make the regression results more robust and reliable, the explained and explanatory variables are replaced, and the estimation method is changed. The robustness test results are shown in Table 4. In Table 4, FE4 is the regression result of replacing the explained variable with land transfer income (LTI). FE5 is the regression result of replacing the explanatory variable by environmental decentralization with a lag of one period. In addition, the model may suffer from heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation, and the feasible generalized least squares (FGLS) method is used to mitigate these problems [37,77]. The third column in Table 4 are the regression results with FGLS. The main work of environmental management includes administration, supervision, and monitoring. Therefore, subdivided environmental decentralization can be used for robustness testing. FE6, FE7, and FE8 are the estimated results of environmental administrative decentralization, environmental supervision decentralization, and environmental monitoring decentralization, respectively.
Table 4 indicates that environmental decentralization has a remarkable positive influence on land transfer income. The impacts of fiscal decentralization and competition for attracting investment on land transfer income are also significantly positive. The impact of environmental decentralization lagging one period on land supply is significant, at a level of 1%, indicating that the current land supply is affected by environmental decentralization in the previous period. The regression results with FGLS are not much different from the basic estimation. From the perspective of subdivided environmental decentralization, the influences of environmental administrative and monitoring decentralization are not significant, while the impact of environmental supervision decentralization is significant, at a level of 5%. The reason for this may be that administrative and monitoring decentralization increases the flexibility and positiveness of environmental management and helps to improve environmental performance. Supervision decentralization weakens the importance of environmental constraints and reduces environmental performance. Robustness test results are consistent with basic estimation results. It can be considered that the impact of environmental decentralization on urban construction land supply is stable.

4.3. Endogenetic Test

There are many factors that affect urban construction land supply. Although some variables affecting land supply are controlled in this paper, there may still be some factors that are not considered by the model. In addition, the bidirectional causality relationship between explanatory variables and explained variables may also produce endogeneity. In this paper, the first-order and second-order lags of environmental decentralization are used as instrumental variables, and two-stage least square (2SLS) regression is used to eliminate endogenous effects [78]. The generalized method of moments (GMM) can deal with endogenous issues [79]. In this paper, the system generalized method of moments (sys-GMM) is used to further avoid the endogenous and weak instrumental variables [50]. The endogeneity test results are shown in Table 5.
Table 5 shows that the impact of environmental decentralization on urban construction land supply is significantly positive, at a 10% level, whether estimated using the 2SLS model or the sys-GMM model. After accounting for endogeneity, the impact of environmental decentralization on urban construction land supply is still significantly positive.

5. Further Analysis

5.1. Intermediary Mechanism

Theoretical analysis has shown that land finance dependence and land resources misallocation increase the scale of local government construction land supply. Land financial dependence can be measured by indicators such as the proportion of land transfer income to GDP [80], the proportion of land transfer income to local government fiscal revenue [81,82], and per capita land transfer income [83]. In this paper, the proportion of land transfer revenue in the general public budget revenue of the local government is used to represent the land financial dependence of local government. Land resources misallocation in this paper refers to the unreasonable allocation between different uses of construction land. This is because the government supplies a great deal of industrial land at low prices, resulting in a high proportion of industrial land. Scholars believe that agreement transfers go hand in hand with the supply of industrial land at low prices. Thus, the proportion of land transferred by agreement to the total land transfer area can be used to measure the degree of land resource misallocation [16]. The estimated results of the intermediary effect are shown in Table 6.
Table 6 shows that the impact of environmental decentralization on land financial dependence and land resource misallocation is significantly positive, at a level of 1%, which indicates that environmental decentralization exacerbates land financial dependence and land resource misallocation. Comparing the columns (3)–(5) in Table 6, it can be found that the impact of environmental decentralization on land supply is significantly reduced after controlling land financial dependence and land resource misallocation. It shows that the two intermediary variables have a remarkable influence on urban construction land supply [84].

5.2. Heterogeneity Analysis

After environmental decentralization, urban construction land supply by local governments should be balanced and chosen among fiscal revenue, economic growth, and environmental protection. Local governments with high pressure on fiscal revenue and economic growth may loosen environmental control and transfer a great deal of construction land for obtaining more land transfer income and better political performance. Local governments with high environmental protection pressures are more inclined to protect the environment and will not supply a great deal of construction land. In order to contrast the different influences in the regions with different financial pressure, economic growth pressure, and environmental protection pressure, this paper uses the median of pressure to divide the provinces into two types of regions. Referring to Li (2015), the calculation of financial pressure is attained by the proportion of the disparity between fiscal expenditure and fiscal revenue to GDP [50]. The provinces are divided into high and low financial pressure regions based on the median of the average financial pressure in each province from 2003 to 2015. Providing more land can boost economic growth [85]. The regions with high economic growth pressure have a stronger willingness to supply more construction land. Referring to Yang (2016), regional economic growth pressure is represented by the divergence between the local GDP growth rate of the current year and the last year [86]. Similarly, the regional division standard is the median of the average economic growth pressure. Chemical oxygen demand (COD) and SO2 are often used to indicate pollution levels [87,88]. COD is mainly produced by industrial enterprises, and is often used as an important indicator to measure environmental pollution. Therefore, COD emissions per unit of GDP are used to measure environmental protection pressure. The regional division of environmental pressure is in accordance with financial pressure and economic growth pressure. The estimated results for regions with distinct financial pressures, economic growth pressure, and environmental protection pressures are shown in Table 7.
From the perspective of financial pressure, the effect of environmental decentralization on urban construction land supply is significantly positive, at a level of 10%, in the regions with high financial pressure, but it is not significant in the regions with low financial pressure. Moreover, the regression coefficient of environmental decentralization in regions with high financial pressure is larger (0.609 > 0.396). The results show that environmental decentralization prompts local governments with high financial pressure to increase construction land supply to ease financial pressure.
From the perspective of economic growth pressure, the effect of environmental decentralization on urban construction land supply is markedly positive, at a level of 10%, in regions with high economic growth pressure. The influence is negative in regions with low economic growth pressure, and it is not significant. The regression coefficient of environmental decentralization in regions with high economic growth pressure is larger (0.845 > −0.007). It shows that the motivation of local governments, which relies on construction land supply to boost economy, distorts the impact of environmental decentralization.
From the perspective of environmental protection pressure, the impact of environmental decentralization on urban construction land supply is significant, at a level of 5%, in the regions with low environmental protection pressure, and it is not significant in the regions with high environmental protection pressure. Moreover, the regression coefficient of environmental decentralization in the regions with low environmental protection pressure is larger (0.760 > 0.245), which indicates that environmental decentralization has a greater influence on construction land supply in regions with low environmental protection pressure. The cause for such a phenomenon is that the environmental constraints in regions with low environmental protection pressure are relatively weak. When the degree of environmental decentralization increases, local governments tend to supply more construction land to improve economic and political performance.

6. Policy Suggestions

The research of this paper provides some policy ideas for local governments to reasonably supply urban construction land against the background of Chinese decentralization.
(1) The environmental management power and responsibilities of the central and local governments should be reasonably divided, and the incentive and restraint mechanisms for construction land supply should be adjusted. The original intention of environmental decentralization is to realize the localization of environmental management and improve the efficiency of environmental management. However, in practice, local governments are encouraged by fiscal revenue and political performance to loosen environmental control and increase construction land supply in the background of environmental decentralization. By decentralizing the environmental administrative power and centralizing the environmental supervision power, local government’s target choice and land supply behavior can be efficaciously restrained. In addition, strengthening the central environmental protection constraints can increase the environmental preferences of local governments and encourage them to reasonably supply construction land. Some measures should be used, such as strictly implementing the environmental protection supervision system and improving the importance of environmental protection indicators in performance appraisal.
(2) Differentiated environmental decentralization should be implemented to form differentiated construction land supply incentives. The strong economic and political incentives brought by urban construction land to local governments make environmental decentralization ineffective in regions with high financial pressure, high economic growth pressure, and low environmental protection pressure. The central government ought to strengthen environmental centralization in these three types of regions. While empowering local governments with environmental administrative power, the central government’s regulatory powers ought to be enhanced to restrict local governments’ land supply behavior that damages the environment. In regions with low financial pressure, low economic growth pressure, and high environmental protection pressure, the central government should increase the degree of environmental decentralization to improve environmental management efficiency.
(3) The land financial dependence of local governments ought to be weakened. Looking for new sources of income and changing financing methods can alleviate the financial pressure of local governments and weaken their land financial dependence. Specific measures can be implemented from two aspects: open source and throttling. Firstly, the fiscal and taxation systems ought to be innovated to increase the tax revenue of local governments, such as levying property tax and inheritance tax, and so on [89]. Secondly, BOT (build-operate-transfer) and other financing modes could be adopted in infrastructure construction to alleviate the financial pressure of the government [90]. Moreover, the land lease can be changed to annual lease, and the land transfer income can be changed from one-time income to continuous income. While ensuring the government’s stable income, the urban construction land supply for obtaining short-term economic profits can be controlled.
In addition, urban planning is an important means to control the expansion of construction land scale. The government’s environmental policy objectives should be fully considered when formulating land use plans [91]. In the use of land, it is necessary to strengthen the guiding and standardizing roles of planning, and realize the scientific and rational allocation of land for different purposes, such as urban construction land and agricultural land.

7. Discussion and Conclusions

7.1. Discussion

In recent years, China’s environmental problems have gradually come to light. Under the environmental decentralization system, the environmental management power of the central government has gradually been strengthened [92]. This shows that the central government is trying to find a balance of environmental decentralization to coordinate the economic growth goals and the environmental protection goals of local government. We integrated environmental decentralization into the Chinese decentralization framework. Then, under the framework of Chinese decentralization, the incentives and constraints of environmental decentralization, fiscal decentralization, and political centralization on the supply of construction land by local governments were studied.
Our research enriches the Chinese decentralization framework. Previous studies have only emphasized the incentives of fiscal decentralization and political centralization on local government land supply [64,85,93]. Tang (2019) focused on the impact of environmental politically binding indicators on local governments’ land violations [36]. However, there has been no in-depth analysis of the impact of environmental management systems on local government land supply. More importantly, the expansion of urban construction land against the background of resource constraints and environmental protection has been more strictly regulated [94]. Clarifying the incentives and constraints of government land supply is conducive to achieving the rational allocation of urban land.
Our research results suggest that environmental decentralization reduces the performance of land environmental management in China. This differs from Laskowski (2005) and Blundell (2021), in that environmental decentralization improves performance by improving environmental policy adaptability [44,45]. As Ulph (1998) argued, information asymmetry between local and central governments in the context of Chinese decentralization distorts the performance of environmental decentralization [46]. Among the three environmental management affairs of administration, supervision, and monitoring, supervision decentralization has the most obvious promotion of the expansion of construction land. Our research also shows that the impact of environmental decentralization on construction land supply regionally varies. Where economic, political, and environmental protection constraints differ, the performance of environmental decentralization is also different. Fredriksson’s study of 110 countries also concluded that there were regional differences in environmental decentralization performance [95].
Although our study is based on the specific situation in China, it is also meaningful to analyze government actions in the supply of urban construction land in other countries. The impact of local government incentives and constraints on urban construction land supply also exists in Western countries. Götze (2021) found that municipalities in Germany and the Netherlands also provide a loose supply of urban land due to financial incentives [96]. Perrin (2018) and Kurnia (2021) studied the impact of decentralization on the expansion of urban construction land in France, Italy, and Indonesia [17,18].

7.2. Conclusions

The economical and intensive use of land resources is an important measure to push ecological civilization construction. Practice in western countries has proved that decentralization can reduce information asymmetry and principal-agent risks, and improve policy efficiency. However, decentralization may also allow local governments to loosen environmental regulations to attract investment, which could boost economic development. Under the Chinese decentralization framework, fiscal decentralization and political centralization provide incentives for local governments to supply a great deal of urban construction land to make up for fiscal gaps and support economic growth. Environmental decentralization increases the possibility of local governments to loosen environmental regulation, which promotes the expansion of construction land supply. The efficiency of environmental decentralization is further reduced. Based on the theoretical analysis of the effect of environmental decentralization on construction land supply, the interprovincial panel data from 2003 to 2015 were used for analysis. The main conclusions are as follows:
(1) Environmental decentralization promotes the expansion of urban construction land supply scale. Environmental decentralization intensifies the positive incentives of economic and political incentives to the supply of construction land, and weakens environmental constraints. Due to the important role of construction land in local economic development, local governments usually choose to relax environmental control and supply a great deal of construction land.
(2) Environmental decentralization promotes the expansion of urban construction land supply by strengthening land financial dependence and distorting land resources misallocation. Environmental decentralization increases the possibility of “land rent”, “land tax”, and “attract investment by land”, while weakening environmental constraints. This raises land financial dependence and the misallocation of land resources, which accelerates the swell of construction land supply scale.
(3) Environmental decentralization has diverse incentives and constraints in regions with distinct financial pressure, economic growth pressure, and environmental protection pressure, and has different impacts on construction land supply. In regions with high financial and economic growth pressure, local governments, driven by economic and political incentives, choose to relax environmental constraints and supply a great deal of construction land. In regions with low environmental protection pressure, local governments have lower environmental constraints. The impact of environmental decentralization on urban construction land supply is greater than that in regions with high environmental protection pressure.

7.3. Limitations and Future Research

There are some deficiencies in this study. First, this paper only pays attention to the effect of environmental decentralization on the urban construction land supply scale of local government. However, the construction land supply structure of different uses and industries is also affected by the preferences and behaviors of local government, which is a content worthy of study. Second, due to data limitations, this paper only focuses on the impact of decentralization and centralization between the central government and provincial governments on urban construction land supply. However, Chinese governments at or above the county level are empowered to supply land. The impact of decentralization and centralization between the upper and lower governments below the provincial level on land supply is also worth studying. Third, this paper only studies the impact of environmental decentralization on construction land supply in the context of China’s specific system. However, there may be differences in the performance of environmental decentralization in different institutional contexts. In the future, comparative analysis with other countries could also be carried out.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, L.H., P.T. and X.W.; methodology, P.T. and X.W.; software, X.W.; validation, P.T. and X.W.; formal analysis, P.T. and X.W.; investigation, X.W.; resources, P.T. and L.H.; data curation, X.W.; writing—original draft preparation, P.T. and X.W.; writing—review and editing, P.T., L.H. and X.W.; visualization, X.W.; supervision, P.T. and L.H.; project administration, P.T. and X.W.; funding acquisition, P.T. and L.H. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the National Social Science Fund (19BJY110) and the Project of Sichuan University (2021CXC03).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Publicly available datasets were analyzed in this study. These data can be found at: https://data.stats.gov.cn/, and https://data.cnki.net/Yearbook/Navi?type=type&code=A, accessed on 14 June 2022.

Acknowledgments

The authors are particularly grateful to the anonymous reviewers for their comments and suggestions which contributed to the further improvement of this paper.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Liu, J.; Jin, X.B.; Xu, W.Y.; Gu, Z.M.; Yang, X.H.; Ren, J.; Fan, Y.T.; Zhou, Y.K. A New Framework of Land Use Efficiency for the Coordination among Food, Economy and Ecology in Regional Development. Sci. Total Environ. 2020, 710, 135670. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  2. Fleming, A.; Anthony, P.O.; Cara, S.; Sue, O.; Daniel, M.; Matthew, T.H. Improving Acceptance of Natural Capital Accounting in Land Use Decision Making: Barriers and Opportunities. Ecol. Econ. 2022, 200, 107510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Imbrenda, V.; Giovanni, Q.; Rosanna, S.; Gianluca, E.; Luca, S.; Marcela, P.; Rosa, C.; Maria, L. Land Degradation and Metropolitan Expansion in a Peri-urban Environment. Geomat. Nat. Hazards Risk 2021, 12, 1797–1818. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Dolley, J.; Fiona, M.; Bradley, B.; Jeremy, R.; James, A.R.; Baris, E.; Novi, Q. Analysing Trade-offs and Synergies between SDGs for Urban Development, Food Security and Poverty Alleviation in Rapidly Changing Peri-urban Areas: A Tool to Support Inclusive Urban Planning. Sustain. Sci. 2020, 15, 1601–1619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Simon, D. Urban Environments: Issues on the Peri-urban Fringe. Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour. 2008, 33, 167–185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Ding, C.R.; Zhao, X.S. Land Market, Land Development and Urban Spatial Structure in Beijing. Land Use Policy 2014, 40, 83–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Feng, L.; Yang, Y.L.; Yao, L. Decentralization and Incentives: Research on the Central-Local Relations within the Land Supply System. China Land Sci. 2013, 27, 4–10+23. [Google Scholar]
  8. Hassan, M.M.; Nazem, M.N.I. Examination of Land Use/land Cover Changes, Urban Growth Dynamics, and Environmental Sustainability in Chittagong City, Bangladesh. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 2016, 18, 697–716. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Huang, K.X.D. Growth and Cycles in China’s Unbalanced Development: Resource Misallocation, Debt Overhang, Economic Inequality, and the Importance of Structural Reforms. Front. Econ. China 2019, 14, 53–71. [Google Scholar]
  10. De Mello, K.; Taniwaki, R.H.; Paula, F.R.D.; Valente, R.V.; Randhir, T.O.; Macedo, D.R.; Leal, C.G.; Rodrigues, C.B.; Hughes, R.M. Multiscale Land Use Impacts on Water Quality: Assessment, Planning, and Future Perspectives in Brazil. J. Environ. Manag. 2020, 270, 110879. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Vito, I.; Rosa, C.; Leonardo, B.; Valerio, D.S.; Luca, S. Urban sprawl: Theory and practice. Adv. Chem. Pollut. Environ. Manag. Prot. 2022, 8, 23–46. [Google Scholar]
  12. Amponsah, O.; Blija, D.K.; Ayambire, R.A.; Takyi, S.A.; Mensah, H.; Braimah, I. Global Urban Sprawl Containment Strategies and Their Implications for Rapidly Urbanising Cities in Ghana. Land Use Policy 2022, 114, 105979. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Pourtaherian, P.; Jaeger, J.A.G. How Effective Are Greenbelts at Mitigating Urban Sprawl? A Comparative Study of 60 European Cities. Landsc. Urban Plan. 2022, 227, 104532. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Millimet, D.L. Environmental Federalism: A Survey of the Empirical Literature. Case West. Reserve Law Rev. 2014, 64, 1669. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. The National People’s Congress of the People’s Republic of China Home Page. Available online: http://www.npc.gov.cn/zgrdw/englishnpc/Special/CombatingClimateChange/2009-08/28/content_1516267.htm (accessed on 23 February 2023).
  16. Du, W.J.; Li, M.J. The Impact of Land Resource Mismatch and Land Marketization on Pollution Emissions of Industrial Enterprises in China. J. Environ. Manag. 2021, 299, 113565. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  17. Perrin, C.; Nougarèdes, B.; Sini, L.; Branduini, P.; Salvati, L. Governance Changes in Peri-urban Farmland Protection following Decentralisation: A Comparison between Montpellier (France) and Rome (Italy). Land Use Policy 2018, 70, 535–546. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  18. Kurnia, A.A.; Rustiadi, E.; Fauzi, A.; Pravitasari, A.E.; Saizen, I.; Ženka, J. Understanding Industrial Land Development on Rural-Urban Land Transformation of Jakarta Megacity’s Outer Suburb. Land 2022, 11, 670. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Lawton, A.; Morrison, N. The Loss of Peri-urban Agricultural Land and the State-local Tensions in Managing Its Demise: The Case of Greater Western Sydney, Australia. Land Use Policy 2022, 120, 106265. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Spyra, M.; Kleemann, J.; Calò, N.C.; Schürmann, A.; Fürst, C. Protection of Peri-urban Open Spaces at the Level of Regional Policy-making: Examples from Six European Regions. Land Use Policy 2021, 107, 105480. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Landesa Home Page. Available online: http://www.landesa.org/china-survey-6/ (accessed on 23 February 2023).
  22. Zhang, J.; Fan, J.; Mo, J. Government Intervention, Land Market, and Urban Development: Evidence from Chinese Cities. Econ. Inq. 2017, 55, 115–136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Jiang, N.P.; Xu, H. Research on the effect of local government to urban land supply in China. Econ. Theory Bus. Manag. 2015, 01, 55–66. [Google Scholar]
  24. Ran, R. Perverse Incentive Structure and Policy Implementation Gap in China’s Local Environmental Politics. J. Environ. Policy Plan. 2013, 15, 17–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Lichtenberg, E.; Ding, C. Local Officials as Land Developers: Urban Spatial Expansion in China. J. Urban Econ. 2009, 66, 57–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Head, K.; Ries, J. Inter-City Competition for Foreign Investment: Static and Dynamic Effects of China’s Incentive Areas. J. Urban Econ. 1996, 40, 38–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Cai, M.N.; Murtazashivili, J.B.; Murtazashvili, I.; Wang, H. Sugarcoating the Bitter Pill: Compensation, Land Governance, and Opposition to Land Expropriation in China. J. Peasant. Stud. 2020, 47, 1371–1392. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Tao, R.; Su, F.B.; Liu, M.X.; Cao, G.Z. Land Leasing and Local Public Finance in China’s Regional Development: Evidence from Prefecture-level Cities. Urban Stud. 2010, 47, 2217–2236. [Google Scholar]
  29. Wang, R.; Hou, J. Land Finance, Land Attracting Investment and Housing Price Fluctuations in China. Int. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2021, 72, 690–699. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Liu, S.Y.; Wang, Z.F.; Zhang, W.F.; Xiong, X.F. The Exhaustion of China’s “Land-Driven Development” Mode: An Analysis Based on Threshold Regression. J. Manag. World 2020, 36, 80–92+119+246. [Google Scholar]
  31. Jiang, M.; Xin, L.J.; Li, X.B.; Tan, M.H. Spatiotemporal Variation of China’s State-Owned Construction Land Supply from 2003 to 2014. Sustainability 2016, 8, 1137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  32. Zhou, C.S.; Jin, W.F.; Zhang, G.J.; Li, M.; Wang, S.J. Spatio-temporal characteristics and influencing factors of state owned construction land supply in China. Acta Geogr. Sin. 2019, 74, 16–31. [Google Scholar]
  33. Wang, X.B.; Shao, Y.F.; Zhang, Q.H. Influential factors and regional difference of local government land transfer: Based on 1999–2011 provincial panel data. J. Wuhan Univ. Technol. (Soc. Sci. Ed.) 2015, 28, 627–634. [Google Scholar]
  34. Bidandi, F.; Williams, J.J. Understanding Urban Land, Politics, and Planning: A Critical Appraisal of Kampala’s Urban Sprawl. Cities 2020, 106, 102858. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Banzhaf, H.S.; Lavery, N. Can the Land Tax Help Curb Urban Sprawl? Evidence from Growth Patterns in Pennsylvania. J. Urban Econ. 2010, 67, 169–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Tang, P.; Feng, Y.; Li, M.; Zhang, Y.Y. Can the Performance Evaluation Change from Central Government Suppress Illegal Land Use in Local Governments? A New Interpretation of Chinese Decentralisation. Land Use Policy 2021, 108, 105578. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Xie, J. Why Natural Resources Become A Curse: “Grabbing Hand” under Market Distortion—An Empirical Test from the Perspective of Officials ′Promotion Incentive Caused by “Chinese Decentralization”. Commer. Res. 2019, 11, 23–31. [Google Scholar]
  38. Lin, N. Capitalism in China: A Centrally Managed Capitalism (CMC) and Its Future. Manag. Organ. Rev. 2011, 7, 63–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Maskin, E.; Qian, Y.Y.; Xu, C.G. Incentives, Information, and Organizational Form. Rev. Econ. Stud. 2000, 67, 359–378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  40. Zhang, X.B. Fiscal Decentralization and Political Centralization in China: Implications for Growth and Inequality. J. Comp. Econ. 2006, 34, 713–726. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  41. Lo, K. How Authoritarian Is the Environmental Governance of China? Environ. Sci. Policy 2015, 54, 152–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Loomis, J.J.; Oliveira, C.M.R.D.; Dziedzic, M. Environmental Federalism in EIA Policy: A Comparative Case Study of Paraná, Brazil and California, US. Environ. Sci. Policy 2021, 122, 75–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Feng, S.L.; Sui, B.; Liu, H.M.; Li, G.X. Environmental Decentralization and Innovation in China. Econ. Model. 2020, 93, 660–674. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Laskowski, S.; Morgenstern, R.D.; Blackman, A. Environmental Decentralization in the United States: Seeking the Proper Balance between National and State Authority. IDEAS Work. Pap. Ser. RePEc 2005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Blundell, W.; Evans, M.F.; Stafford, S.L. Regulating Hazardous Wastes under U.S. Environmental Federalism: The Role of State Resources. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2021, 108, 102464. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Ulph, A. Political Institutions and the Design of Environmental Policy in a Federal System with Asymmetric Information. Eur. Econ. Rev. 1998, 42, 583–592. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  47. Gray, W.B.; Shadbegian, R.J. ‘Optimal’ Pollution Abatement—Whose Benefits Matter, and How Much? J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2004, 47, 510–534. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Qi, Y.; Lu, H.Y.; Xu, Y.K. Research on the Reformation of China’s Environmental Decentralization System: Institutional Change, Numerical Estimates and Effects Assessment. China Ind. Econ. 2014, 1, 31–43. [Google Scholar]
  49. Wu, H.T.; Li, Y.W.; Hao, Y.; Ren, S.Y.; Zhang, P.F. Environmental Decentralization, Local Government Competition, and Regional Green Development: Evidence from China. Sci. Total Environ. 2020, 708, 135085. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Li, G.X.; Guo, F.Y.; Di, D.Y. Regional Coial factors aironmental Decentralization, and Target Selection of Local Governments. Sci. Total Environ. 2021, 755, 142536. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Ran, Q.Y.; Zhang, J.N.; Hao, Y. Does Environmental Decentralization Exacerbate China’s Carbon Emissions? Evidence Based on Dynamic Threshold Effect Analysis. Sci. Total Environ. 2020, 721, 137656. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Cheng, S.L.; Fan, W.; Chen, J.D.; Meng, F.X.; Liu, G.Y.; Song, M.L.; Yang, Z.F. The Impact of Fiscal Decentralization on CO2 Emissions in China. Energy 2020, 192, 116685. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Ding, Y.; McQuoid, A.; Karayalcin, C. Fiscal Decentralization, Fiscal Reform, and Economic Growth in China. China Econ. Rev. 2019, 53, 152–167. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Tu, L.H.; Padovani, E. A Research on the Debt Sustainability of China’s Major City Governments in Post-Land Finance Era. Sustainability 2018, 10, 1606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  55. Ahmad, E.; Singh, R.; Fortuna, M. Toward More Effective Redistribution: Reform Options for Intergovernmental Transfers in China; International Monetary Fund: Washington, DC, USA, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  56. Huang, Z.H.; Du, X.J. Government intervention and land misallocation: Evidence from China. Cities 2017, 60, 323–332. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Geng, B.; Zhang, X.L.; Liang, Y.; Bao, H.J.; Skitmore, M. Sustainable Land Financing in a New Urbanization Context: Theoretical Connotations, Empirical Tests and Policy Recommendations. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2018, 128, 336–344. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  58. Chiang, T.F.; Hou, J.; Tsai, P.H. Fiscal Incentives and Land Finance Cycles of Prefectures in China. World Econ. 2022, 45, 1262–1293. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Cai, M.N. Revenue, Time Horizon, and Land Allocation in China. Land Use Policy 2017, 62, 101–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  60. Chen, T.; Kung, J.K.S. Do Land Revenue Windfalls Create a Political Resource Curse? Evidence from China. J. Dev. Econ. 2016, 123, 86–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Zhang, B.B.; Li, J.X.; Tian, W.M.; Chen, H.B.; Kong, X.B.; Chen, W.; Zhao, M.J.; Xia, X.L. Spatio-temporal Variances and Risk Evaluation of Land Finance in China at the Provincial Level from 1998 to 2017. Land Use Policy 2020, 99, 104804. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Li, H.B.; Zhou, L.A. Political Turnover and Economic Performance: The Incentive Role of Personnel Control in China. J. Public Econ. 2005, 89, 1743–1762. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Landry, P.F. The Political Management of Mayors in Post-Deng China The Political Management of Mayors in Post-Deng China. Cph. J. Asian Stud. 2003, 17, 31–58. [Google Scholar]
  64. Van, D.K.D.; Lorentzen, P.; Mattingly, D. Racing to the Bottom or to the Top? Decentralization, Revenue Pressures, and Governance Reform in China. World Dev. 2017, 95, 164–176. [Google Scholar]
  65. Hong, T.; Yu, N.N.; Mao, Z.G. Does Environment Centralization Prevent Local Governments from Racing to the Bottom?—Evidence from China. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 231, 649–659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Qi, S.W.; Mao, H.; Zhang, J.D. Financial Pressure, Economic Stimulus, and Land Transfer for Investment Attraction—Empirical Evidence Based on Micro-Data of Industrial Land. Financ. Trade Econ. 2020, 41, 20–34. [Google Scholar]
  67. Wu, Y.; Heerink, N. Foreign Direct Investment, Fiscal Decentralization and Land Conflicts in China. China Econ. Rev. 2016, 38, 92–107. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Millimet, D.L. Assessing the Empirical Impact of Environmental Federalism. J. Reg. Sci. 2003, 43, 711–733. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Wang, L.; Wang, K.; Zhang, J.J.; Zhang, D.; Wu, X.; Zhang, L.J. Multiple Objective-oriented Land Supply for Sustainable Transportation: A Perspective from Industrial Dependence, Dominance and Restrictions of 127 Cities in the Yangtze River Economic Belt of China. Land Use Policy 2020, 99, 105069. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Jin, W.F.; Zhou, C.S.; Zhang, G.J. Characteristics of State-owned Construction Land Supply in Chinese Cities by Development Stage and Industry. Land Use Policy 2020, 96, 104630. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Guo, L.; Jiang, X.N. Decentralization of Environmental Management and Enterprises’ Environmental Technology Innovation: Evidence from China. Appl. Econ. 2022, 54, 4170–4186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Hao, Y.; Xu, L.; Guo, Y.X.; Wu, H.T. The Inducing Factors of Environmental Emergencies: Do Environmental Decentralization and Regional Corruption Matter? J. Environ. Manag. 2022, 302, 114098. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Li, G.L.; Zhou, Y.L. Environmental Decentralization, Local Government Competition and Green Development. Public Financ. Res. 2019, 10, 73–86. [Google Scholar]
  74. Ahmad, M.; Satrovic, E. Relating Fiscal Decentralization and Financial Inclusion to Environmental Sustainability: Criticality of Natural Resources. J. Environ. Manag. 2023, 325, 116633. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  75. Pang, W.; Sun, Y.D. Research on the Spatial Effect of Fiscal Decentralization and Promotion Incentive on Income Distribution. J. Shanxi Univ. Financ. Econ. 2018, 40, 1–14. [Google Scholar]
  76. Li, Q.; Li, X.H. Local Government Competition and Environmental Governance-the Regulation of Environmental Decentralization. J. Guizhou Univ. Financ. Econ. 2020, 3, 101–110. [Google Scholar]
  77. Reed, W.R.; Ye, H. Which Panel Data Estimator Should I Use? Appl. Econ. 2011, 43, 985–1000. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Aston, L.; Currie, G.; Kamruzzaman, M.; Delbosc, A.; Brands, T.; Oort, N.V.; Teller, D. Multi-city Exploration of Built Environment and Transit Mode Use: Comparison of Melbourne, Amsterdam and Boston. J. Transp. Geogr. 2021, 95, 103136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Majumder, S.C.; Rahman, M.H.; Martial, A.A.A. The Effects of Foreign Direct Investment on Export Processing Zones in Bangladesh Using Generalized Method of Moments Approach. Soc. Sci. Humanit. Open 2022, 6, 100277. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Cheng, Y.D.; Jia, S.H.; Meng, H. Fiscal Policy Choices of Local Governments in China: Land Finance or Local Government Debt? Int. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2022, 80, 294–308. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Lu, J.; Li, B.; Li, H. The Influence of Land Finance and Public Service Supply on Peri-urbanization: Evidence from the Counties in China. Habitat Int. 2019, 92, 102039. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Tang, P.; Shi, X.P.; Gao, J.L.; Feng, S.Y.; Qu, F.T. Demystifying the Key for Intoxicating Land Finance in China: An Empirical Study through the Lens of Government Expenditure. Land Use Policy 2019, 85, 302–309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Wang, L.O.; Wu, H.T.; Hao, Y. How Does China’s Land Finance Affect Its Carbon Emissions? Struct. Chang. Econ. Dyn. 2020, 54, 267–281. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Jiang, T. Mediating Effects and Moderating Effects in Causal Inference. China Ind. Econ. 2022, 410, 100–120. [Google Scholar]
  85. Li, J. Lan Impact of Fiscal Decentralization on Economic Growth Path: Evidence from China’s Urban Land Market. Habitat Int. 2014, 41, 307–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. Yang, J.D.; Yang, Q.J. Growth Pressures, Stimulus Plan and Industrial Land Transfer. Econ. Res. J. 2016, 51, 99–113. [Google Scholar]
  87. Fan, H.C.; Graff, Z.J.; Kou, Z.L.; Liu, X.Y.; Wang, H.H. Going Green in China: Firms’ Responses to Stricter Environmental Regulations; NBER Working Paper No. w26540; NBER: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  88. Justyna, L.C.; Socha, J.; Gruba, P.; Pietrzykowski, M. The Current State of Environmental Pollution with Sulfur Dioxide (SO2) in Poland Based on Sulfur Concentration in Scots Pine Needles. Environ. Pollut. 2020, 258, 113559. [Google Scholar]
  89. Wu, W.Z.; Zhou, A.L. The Causes for House Price Fluctuation: Rigid Demand, or Finance? Shandong Soc. Sci. 2021, 3, 126–132. [Google Scholar]
  90. Ran, Q.Y.; Wang, J.L.; Wang, W.L.; Yang, X.D. Land Finance, Technological Innovation and Green Development in China. J. Nanjing Univ. Financ. Econ. 2021, 04, 64–74. [Google Scholar]
  91. OECD. The Governance of Land Use in OECD Countries: Policy Analysis and Recommendations; OECD Publishing: Paris, France, 2020; Volume 24. [Google Scholar]
  92. Lin, J.Y.; Long, C.H.; Yi, C.Z. Has Central Environmental Protection Inspection Improved Air Quality? Evidence from 291 Chinese Cities. Environ. Impact Assess. Rev. 2021, 90, 106621. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Henderson, J.V.; Su, D.L.; Zhang, Q.H.; Zheng, S.Q. Political Manipulation of Urban Land Markets: Evidence from China. J. Public Econ. 2022, 214, 104730. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. Bovet, J.; Reese, M.; Köck, W. Taming Expansive Land Use Dynamics–Sustainable Land Use Regulation and Urban Sprawl in a Comparative Perspective. Land Use Policy 2018, 77, 837–845. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. Fredriksson, P.G.; Wollscheid, J.R. Environmental Decentralization and Political Centralization. Ecol. Econ. 2014, 107, 402–410. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  96. Götze, V.; Hartmann, T. Why Municipalities Grow: The Influence of Fiscal Incentives on Municipal Land Policies in Germany and the Netherlands. Land Use Policy 2021, 109, 105681. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The influence of Chinese decentralization on construction land supply.
Figure 1. The influence of Chinese decentralization on construction land supply.
Land 12 00601 g001
Figure 2. Temporal and spatial evolution of urban construction land supply and environmental decentralization.
Figure 2. Temporal and spatial evolution of urban construction land supply and environmental decentralization.
Land 12 00601 g002
Table 1. Variable selection.
Table 1. Variable selection.
Variable TypeVariable NameVariable Connotation
Explained variableSupply scale of construction land (LS)Total area of construction land supply
Explanatory variableEnvironmental decentralization (ED)Local government environmental protection employees/national environmental protection employees
Special control variablesFiscal decentralization (FD)Local government per capita fiscal revenue/central government per capita fiscal revenue
Promotion incentive (FAI)Fixed asset investment/GDP
Environmental constraints (IPC)Industrial pollution control completed investment
Other control variablesEconomic development level (PGDP)Per capita GDP
Economic development level square (PGDP2)Square of per capita GDP
Population (POP)Total population
Land urbanization rate (URL)Built up area/land area
Proportion of secondary and tertiary industries (STI)(Secondary industry added value + tertiary industry added value)/GDP
Financial pressure (FP)(Local government fiscal expenditure—Local government fiscal revenue)/GDP
Table 2. Descriptive statistics of variables.
Table 2. Descriptive statistics of variables.
Variable NameUnitMeanStd. DevMinMax
lnLShectare8.6620.9534.79712.445
ED-0.9710.3530.4382.290
FD-1.1321.0080.3435.926
FAI-0.6620.2550.1311.564
lnIPC108 yuan2.2571.038−1.6934.658
lnPGDP104 yuan/person0.6730.611−0.9962.158
lnPGDP2104 yuan/person0.8270.9730.0004.657
lnPOP104 persons8.1610.7546.2809.365
URL-0.0230.1290.0002.500
STI-0.8810.0620.6580.995
FP-0.1150.0950.0080.636
Table 3. Basic estimation results.
Table 3. Basic estimation results.
VariablesFE1FE2FE3
ED1.035 *** (4.498)1.010 *** (4.967)0.543 ** (2.533)
FD0.394 *** (3.614)0.360 *** (3.059)
FAI1.427 *** (7.483)0.849 *** (4.033)
lnIPC−0.062 (−1.334)−0.115 ** (−2.530)
lnPGDP1.196 *** (3.223)
lnPGDP2−0.327 *** (−3.184)
lnPOP0.415 (0.584)
URL0.176 (1.135)
STI−4.661 *** (−2.955)
FP1.839 ** (2.207)
Cons7.242 *** (30.553)6.350 *** (27.700)7.729 (1.378)
Time-fixed effectYesYesYes
Province-fixed effectYesYesYes
R20.4030.5460.600
Obs390390390
Note: values in parentheses are t statistics; **, and *** represent that the coefficients are significant at the levels of 5%, and 1%, respectively.
Table 4. Robustness test results.
Table 4. Robustness test results.
VariablesFE4FE5FGLSFE6FE7FE8
ED0.720 *** (3.836)0.290 ** (2.072)
L.ED0.767 *** (3.247)
EAD0.013 (0.317)
ESD0.082 ** (2.481)
EMD0.038 (0.857)
FD0.174 * (1.688)0.360 *** (2.872)0.258 * (1.785)0.351 *** (2.907)0.392 *** (3.291)0.373 *** (3.026)
FAI0.361 * (1.958)0.833 *** (3.759)0.419 *** (3.470)0.743 *** (3.567)0.756 *** (3.658)0.760 *** (3.635)
lnIPC−0.045 (−1.126)−0.135 *** (−2.840)−0.086 *** (−2.994)−0.112 ** (−2.454)−0.112 ** (−2.468)−0.103 ** (−2.190)
Cons−2.067 (−0.421)8.909 (1.471)10.392 ** (2.106)8.066 (1.379)1.827 (0.294)6.324 (1.018)
Other control variablesYesYesYesYesYesYes
R20.8670.5790.5930.6000.593
Obs390360390390390390
Note: values in parentheses are t statistics; *, **, and *** represent that the coefficients are significant at the levels of 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
Table 5. Endogenous test results.
Table 5. Endogenous test results.
Variables2SLSSys-GMM
1st Step (ED)2nd Step (LS)
L.LS0.025 (0.323)
L.ED0.854 *** (14.334)
L2.ED−0.045 (−0.723)
ED0.869 *** (2.671)0.414 * (1.701)
FD−0.012 (−0.672)0.297 ** (2.153)0.459 ** (2.524)
FAI−0.044 (−1.367)0.885 *** (3.677)0.404 (1.611)
lnIPC−0.005 (−0.784)−0.147 *** (−2.874)−0.150 (−1.338)
Cons0.101 (0.108)7.290 (1.051)7.467 (1.445)
Other control variablesYesYesYes
Underidentification test22.274 (0.000)
Weak identification test137.478 (19.93)
Hansen J statistic1.664 (0.197)
AR(2)−0.83 (0.405)
Sargan test9.22 (0.324)
R20.7270.546
Obs330330330
Note: values in parentheses are t statistics; *, **, and *** represent that the coefficients are significant at the levels of 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively; the p values of Underidentification test, Hansen J statistic, AR(2) and Sargan test are in parentheses; the critical value of 10% significance is shown in the brackets of Weak identification test.
Table 6. Intermediary effect estimation results.
Table 6. Intermediary effect estimation results.
VariablesLFLRMLS (ED)LS (LF)LS (LRM)
ED0.341 *** (4.371)0.221 *** (4.205)1.035 *** (4.498)0.643 *** (2.950)0.904 *** (3.862)
LF1.148 *** (7.866)
LRM0.591 ** (2.539)
Cons0.122 (1.523)0.452 *** (8.346)7.242 *** (30.553)7.101 *** (32.373)6.974 *** (27.062)
Control variablesNoNoNoNoNo
R20.3240.8700.4030.4930.414
Obs390390390390390
Note: values in parentheses are t statistics; **, and *** represent that the coefficients are significant at the levels of 5%, and 1%, respectively.
Table 7. Subregional estimation results.
Table 7. Subregional estimation results.
VariablesFinancial PressureEconomic Growth PressureEnvironmental Protection Pressure
HighLowHighLowHighLow
ED0.609 * (1.666)0.396 (1.364)0.845 * (1.731)−0.007 (−0.033)0.245 (0.749)0.760 ** (2.325)
FD0.857 ** (2.108)0.263 * (1.753)0.300 * (1.783)−0.160 (−0.486)0.684 ** (2.342)0.195 (1.173)
FAI0.750 *** (2.709)0.661 ** (2.045)0.852 *** (2.692)0.745 ** (2.605)0.516 ** (2.580)1.567 *** (3.030)
lnIPC−0.041 (−0.782)−0.348 *** (−4.008)−0.182 ** (−2.064)−0.091 * (−1.905)−0.018 (−0.371)−0.349 *** (−4.123)
Cons−1.422 (−0.198)19.834 * (1.893)10.897 (1.144)−18.501 * (−1.819)−5.990 (−0.813)23.565 * (1.905)
Other control variablesYesYesYesYesYesYes
R20.7710.5060.5510.7800.7720.522
Obs195195195195195195
Note: values in parentheses are t statistics; *, **, and *** represent that the coefficients are significant at the levels of 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Han, L.; Wu, X.; Tang, P. Does Environmental Decentralization Affect the Supply of Urban Construction Land? Evidence from China. Land 2023, 12, 601. https://doi.org/10.3390/land12030601

AMA Style

Han L, Wu X, Tang P. Does Environmental Decentralization Affect the Supply of Urban Construction Land? Evidence from China. Land. 2023; 12(3):601. https://doi.org/10.3390/land12030601

Chicago/Turabian Style

Han, Lida, Xi Wu, and Peng Tang. 2023. "Does Environmental Decentralization Affect the Supply of Urban Construction Land? Evidence from China" Land 12, no. 3: 601. https://doi.org/10.3390/land12030601

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop