Next Article in Journal
Internal Control, Environmental Uncertainty and Total Factor Productivity of Firms—Evidence from Chinese Capital Market
Next Article in Special Issue
Import Tariff Reduction and Fiscal Sustainability: A Macro-Econometric Modelling for Ethiopia
Previous Article in Journal
Examining Predictors and Outcomes of Decent Work among Chinese Female Pre-Service Primary School Teachers
Previous Article in Special Issue
Impact of Trade Policy Uncertainty and Sustainable Development on Medical Innovation for Developed Countries: An Application of DID Approach
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Does Industrial Policy Reduce Corporate Investment Efficiency? Evidence from China

1
School of Economics, Zhejiang University, Hangzhou 310027, China
2
Bond Financing Headquarter, Haitong Securities Company Limited, Shanghai 200001, China
3
School of Economics & Academy of Financial Research, Zhejiang University, Hangzhou 310027, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2023, 15(1), 732; https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010732
Submission received: 1 December 2022 / Revised: 24 December 2022 / Accepted: 27 December 2022 / Published: 31 December 2022
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Business, Innovation, and Economics Sustainability)

Abstract

:
We investigate the impact and mechanism of industrial policy on corporate investment and investment efficiency. Using the micro-level data of A-share listed firms on China’s stock market from 2001–2020, we examine whether industrial policies have different effects on China’s state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and non-state-owned enterprises (non-SOEs). Moreover, we identify specific policy followers to further illustrate the impact of industrial policy on investment efficiency. The empirical results show that industrial policies promote investments among non-SOEs at the cost of reducing their investment efficiency, but have no effect on the investment and efficiency of SOEs. Government subsidy and inter-industry competition are the main mechanisms for the negative impact of industrial policy on investment efficiency. Moreover, target industrial policies reduce the investment efficiency of both SOE and non-SOE policy followers. Therefore, to achieve the goal of improving corporate investment efficiency and promoting sustainable economic development, policy-makers should pay more attention to the consequence of unnecessary government subsidy and excessive inter-industry competition.

1. Introduction

The investments of firms contribute to improving industry upgrading and adjusting industrial structure, thus play a crucial role in economic development. To achieve economic goals, policy-makers have enacted a series of industrial policies to guide corporate investment, optimize resource allocation and promote industrial structure adjustment [1]. In order to clarify the direction of economic and social development, China has implemented short- and medium-term national planning with a five-year horizon since 1953. During the 13th Five-Year Plan (2015–2020) for National Economic and Social Development (13th Five-Year Plan), target industries has experienced a rapid growth. According to the “Statistical Communiqué of the People’s Republic of China on the 2017 National Economic and Social Development” [2], with the support of a strategic emerging industries development plan, the value added of the industrial strategic emerging industries above the designated size increased by 11.0% during 2016–2017, and the innovation and profitability of these target industries have improved substantially. However, the “visible hand” of the government intervene is a double-edged sword [2,3]. Improper design or invalid implementation of industrial policies may distort the behavior of corporate investment, resulting in over-investment and investment inefficiency.
The Implement of the Five-Year Plan is deemed as an industrial policy to promote economic growth [4]. Generally, target industries mentioned by the Five-Year Plans will receive more resources and support, and hence experience a rapid growth. From the micro perspective, the investment decisions of firms belonging to the target industries can be influenced by the Five-Year Plans. Therefore, the effectiveness of industrial policies has an important impact on economic development. If industrial policies stimulate firms to make efficient investment, industry upgrading and resource allocation will be significantly improved [5,6]; otherwise, there will be overcapacity and redundant construction in some industries [7]. Most of the studies investigate the impact of industrial policies from the perspective of macroeconomic level [8,9,10]. There are few studies on the relationship between industrial policy fluctuations and firms’ investment and performance. Existing literature focuses on the impact of industrial policy on corporate investment [4,11], while the investment efficiency of firms is largely ignored.
We contribute to the literatures of industrial policy by exploring the relationship between industrial policy and corporate investment efficiency. Furthermore, we examine the different consequences of national and local industrial policy. As local policies formulated according to national policies may not match the local economic conditions, studies focusing on the impact of national industrial policies may overlook the role of local industrial policies in corporate investment [7,11,12]. Considering that Chinese firms are closely related to local government policies, we emphasize the influence of local industrial policies on firms’ investment and efficiency. In addition, there is a significant disparity between the status of SOEs and non-SOEs in China [13,14]. Although non-SOEs are the fundamental force of economic development and have grown rapidly in recent years, SOEs still have advantages in funding availability and market entry [15]. Hence, we investigate the responses of both SOEs and non-SOEs to industrial policies, respectively.
China has gone through thirteen Five-Year Plans, which provide a unique institution background for us to investigate the consequences of industrial policy on corporate investment efficiency. We hand-collect the documents of “The Five-Year Plan for National Economic and Social Development”, published by Chinese central and provincial government departments, covering the implement periods of 10th (2001–2005), 11th (2006–2010), 12th (2011–2015) and 13th (2015–2020) Five-Year Plans; then, we identify the target industries and match them with data on A-share listed firms to investigate the impact of industrial policy on corporate investment and investment efficiency. Our empirical results show that industrial policies have a heterogenous effect on the investment and efficiency of SOEs and non-SOEs. Industrial policies significantly motivate the investments of non-SOEs at the cost of reducing their investment efficiency. Meanwhile, industrial policies have little impact on the investment and efficiency of SOEs. Government subsidy and inter-industry competition are the main influence mechanism of the industrial policies on investment efficiency.
Moreover, we define the specific policy followers (firms in target industries that increase investment after the implement of supporting industrial policies) to further explore the impact of industrial policy on corporate investment efficiency. We find that the investment efficiency of policy followers has significantly reduced by the implement of industrial policies.
Our study makes several contributions. Firstly, we enrich the influence factors of corporate investment from the perspective of industrial policies. Existing literatures explore the determinants of corporate investment and investment efficiency from the view of firm-level. The investments of corporates are affected by the cost of capital [16,17,18,19], debt structure [20,21], manager characteristics [22,23] and political connections [24,25]. In addition, the information asymmetry caused by disclosure quality [26,27] and corporate governance [28,29] have a substantial effect on corporate investment efficiency. Our study focuses on the impact of industrial policy on corporate investment and investment efficiency to reveal how macroeconomic policies interact with corporate investment decisions. Secondly, we investigate how industrial policies affect corporate investment efficiency from the perspective of government subsidy and inter-industry competition. Finally, we test the investment efficiency of specific policy followers. Overall, our study provides a new insight on the impact of industrial policy on corporate investment and investment efficiency, and underlines the importance of the formulation of industrial policies.
The rest of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 provides the theoretical analysis and hypotheses development; Section 3 describes the sample selection, data sources and variable definitions; Section 4 presents the empirical results; Section 5 discusses the robustness checks; Section 6 makes some discussions; Section 7 concludes.

2. Literature Review and Hypothesis Development

The goal of industrial policies is to promote industry upgrading, which reflects economic development pattern. Industrial policies are often accompanied by preferential measures (such as increased financing opportunities, fewer industry barriers and relaxed administrative controls), which creates a favorable environment for firms to make related investments and may significantly affect their investment efficiency. Firms in the target industries can receive ongoing government subsidies and it is easier for them to obtain bank loans, compared to other firms [12,30]. Some firms can also take advantage of direct financing, such as bond issuance and secondary equity offering, to meet their funding needs [25]. Therefore, the implements of industrial policies send a positive signal to firms in the target industries, resulting in increased investments.
Considering the disparity in terms of financing and investing between SOEs and non-SOEs, the impact of industrial policies on corporate investment may vary with firms’ ownership status. The ownership status of SOEs includes central-controlled, local-controlled, city governments and state-owned assets management company. The financial discrimination view indicates that compared with non-SOEs, SOEs have more political connections and softer budget constraints, allowing them to acquire more long-term debts and bear lower funding costs [15,31]. However, firms targeted by industrial policies may obtain more government subsidies and financing opportunities, enabling non-SOEs in target industries to make long-term investments, such as purchase fixed assets and increase research and development investment [32]. In addition, SOEs usually have political connections, and it is easier for them to breach industrial barriers compared to non-SOEs [14]. It is difficult for non-SOEs to enter highly profitable industries, such as energy, finance, transportation and other monopolistic sectors; they account for only 20% in such industries [33]. Consequently, non-SOEs need to seek out political connections to secure economic benefits. For example, they actively respond to supportive industrial policies by increasing related investments, and exploit the favorable conditions to achieve the goal of profit maximization. Hence, we propose the following Hypothesis 1:
Hypothesis 1: 
Industrial policies have a positive effect on corporate investment. However, the positive effect may be heterogenous according to firms’ ownership status; industrial policies have no significant impact on the investment of SOEs, but a significant impact for non-SOEs.
In a perfect market, a firm’s optimal investment decision is based on the market value of the investment opportunities, which is reflected in Tobin’s Q ratio [34]. However, there exists government intervention, information asymmetry and agency problems, in reality. As a result, firms may deviate from the optimal investment level and make inefficient investment in an imperfect market [35]. To compensate for market failures and achieve economic goals, the government usually conducts administrative methods to affect the allocation of resource, and formulates corresponding policies.
Policies that encourage innovation and technological enhancement may contribute to firms’ performance, but otherwise lead to inefficiency and overcapacity [36]. When economic policy lacks clear guidelines, firms will be more cautious and avoid over-investment. Furthermore, differences in managerial style and investment strategy between SOEs and non-SOEs may also affect their investment efficiency [37]. To achieve social and political goals (such as reducing unemployment and promoting regional development), the government may intervene in the investment decisions of SOEs [25,38], which may even occur before the implement of industrial policies. Consequently, SOEs may make investment decisions without maximizing profit, and favorable industrial policies barely affect their investment efficiency. By contrast, the sales and labor productivity of non-SOEs dropped after their nationalization, resulting in a worse performance [39]. Non-SOEs aim to maximize profits without undertaking political tasks, making their investments more efficient than those of SOEs. However, firms in target industries will receive more government subsidies and bank loans than others [14,40]. This may induce non-SOEs to blindly cater to target industrial policies, without considering the return of investment. Accordingly, we propose Hypotheses 2:
Hypothesis 2: 
Industrial policies reduce corporate investment efficiency. However, the negative effect may vary with firms’ ownership status; industrial policies have no significant effect on the investment efficiency of SOEs, but a significant effect for non-SOEs.
The supportive industrial policies affect firms’ investment efficiency by affecting resource allocation, such as capital flows and inter-industry competition structure [41]. Generally, target industries are offered government support, including national special funds and preferential policies. Local industry upgrading is also supported by local government subsidies, which contributes to the career promotion of local politicians [42]. Due to information asymmetry, the government cannot fully capture the operation and prospect of firms that receive subsidies; thus, the allocation of resources is critical for economic growth. If the government misallocates resource to firms that have no comparative advantage in target industries, or there are some firms that make unnecessary investments in order to obtain subsidies, the investment efficiency will be distorted [30]. Moreover, government subsidies help to accelerate the development of emerging industries in the early stage of expansion, but have little impact on subsequent innovation and the increase in homogenized products, eventually causing overcapacity [43,44]. As the A-share listed firms in China’s stock market are qualified to certain profit requirements, our sample is relatively mature and has already experienced their first growth stage. Therefore, the government subsidy might have a negative impact on the investment efficiency of listed firms.
In addition to administrative intervention, inter-industry competition also plays a role in resource allocation, promoting the development of growth-oriented firms [45]. The imitation behavior of investments increases with the degree of inter-industry competition [46,47]. Thus, inter-industry competition reinforces the effect of industrial policies on firms’ investment efficiency [38]. Thus, we propose the following Hypothesis 3:
Hypothesis 3: 
The negative impact of industrial policies on the investment efficiency increases with the amount of government subsidies and the degree of inter-industry competition.
Industrial policies can reduce entry barriers and the cost of investment, resulting in market optimism and triggering an investment boom [48]. To investigate the impact of investment waves on corporate investment efficiency, we define specific policy followers in target industries based on firms’ annual reports, investment announcements and funding reports. The policy followers in target industries make investment decisions according to the guidelines of industrial policies to meet the preferences of investors. The herding behavior of policy followers can easily lead to inefficient investment, which generates overcapacity and impairs the effectiveness of industrial policies. Therefore, we present the following Hypothesis 4:
Hypothesis 4: 
Industrial policies have a negative effect on the investment efficiency of policy followers.
Based on these Hypotheses, the idea and structure of the study is generalized in Figure 1:

3. Data and Variable Definitions

3.1. Data

We hand-collect the 10th (2001–2005), 11th (2006–2010), 12th (2011–2015) and 13th (2015–2020) Five-Year Plans for National Economic and Social Development, published by Chinese provincial government departments covering the implement period of 2001 to 2020, and identify the target industries; then, we match the target industries with the balance sheet of A-share listed firms on China’s stock market according to year and the Guidelines on Industry Classification of Listed Companies, published by the China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) in 2001 [49]. To avoid the sample selection bias, we construct our sample by excluding the following firms: (1) special treatment firms; (2) financial firms considering their different balance sheet structure; (3) firms with missing data; (4) firms insolvent in the period; and (5) firms with less than three years of continuous data. Firm-level data is retrieved from the China Stock Market and Accounting Research (CSMAR) database and Wind databases, respectively. Finally, we build an unbalanced panel data set including 33,788 firm-year observations, including 886 SOEs and 1436 non-SOEs.

3.2. Variable Definitions

3.2.1. Dependent Variables

Inspired by existing literature [26,50], we estimated the following investment model in Equation (1) to calculate the optimal value of corporate investment, and then use the absolute residual to measure corporate investment efficiency (Inefficiency):
I n v e s t i , t = α 0 + α 1 I n v e s t i , t 1 + α 2 C F i , t 1 + α 3 T Q i , t 1 + α 4 A g e i , t 1 + α 5 S i z e i , t 1 + α 6 L e v e r a g e i , t 1 + α 7 R e t u r n i , t 1 + + α 8 M T B i , t 1 I n d u s t r y + Y e a r + ε i , t
where I n v e s t i , t is the investment of firm i in year t , measured as the capital expenditures divided by total assets at the beginning period [51,52,53]. C F i , t 1 is the operating cash flow of firm i in year t 1 ; T Q i , t 1 is the market value of equity divided by book value of assets of firm i in year t 1 [24,35]. A g e i , t 1 is the listing age of firm i in year t 1 ; S i z e i , t 1 is the log of total assets of firm i in year t 1 ; L e v e r a g e i , t 1 is the liability to asset ratio of firm i in year t 1 [26]; R e t u r n i , t 1 is the stock return of firm i in year t 1 and; M T B i , t 1 is the market value of equity, plus book value of assets, minus book value of equity, scaled by book value of assets [38]. I n d u s t r y and Y e a r are the industry and time fixed effects, respectively, and ε i , t is the residual term.
We then used the absolute residual to capture corporate investment efficiency ( I n e f f i c i e n c y i , t ), which is the deviation from optimal investment. A higher value of Inefficiency infers that firm making more inefficiency investment.

3.2.2. Independent Variables

Following the existing literature [4], we used the industrial policy dummy variable (IP) to identify whether a firm belongs to the target industry of Five-Year Plans. Specifically, based on the Guidelines on Industry Classification of Listed Companies, published by the CSRC in 2001 [49], when an industry is mentioned by key words, such as “vigorously develop”, “major push”, “focus on” and “strongly support” in the documents of Five-Year Plans, we define the industry as a target industry. We then define the industrial policy (IP) according to the firm’s industry classification. If firms belong to the target industry, then IP equals 1; otherwise, IP equals 0. In addition, we use the dummy variable Follower to define the policy follower. If a firm is in the target industry and its increased investment in year t is higher than that in year t 1 , then Follower equals 1; otherwise, Follower equals 0.
We also chose government subsidy (Subsidy) and inter-industry competition (HHI) to explore how industrial policy affects corporate investment and investment efficiency. The CSRC has required listed firms to disclose detailed data on government subsidy since 2007, so we measured government subsidy (Subsidy) as the amount of government subsidy divided by total assets [12,36], in which government subsidies are reported in the non-operating income items of the annual reports. We calculated the Herfindahl–Hirschman Index (HHI) to capture the inter-industry competition [54]. The HHI is calculated as the following Equation (2):
H H I = i = 1 n ( X i X ) 2   ,   and   X = i = 1 n X i
where X i is the operating income of firm i and n is the total number of firms in the industry. A high value of HHI means a great income difference within the industry, implying a high market concentration and a low degree of competition, and vice versa.

3.2.3. Control Variables

Referring to the previous empirical studies related to corporate investment [13,23,25], we used the following control variables for empirical estimation: The log of total assets (Size), measuring firm size; the operating income growth rate (Growth), measuring firm’s profitability; the liabilities to assets ratio (Leverage), measuring the debt structure; the operating cash flow (CF), measuring the liquidity level; the stock return (Return), measuring the market performance and; the ownership status of firm (SOE) equals 1, if firm is state-owned (including central-controlled, local-controlled, city governments and state-owned assets management company); otherwise, SOE equals 0. Table 1 provides definitions of the variables used in our paper:

3.3. Summary Statistics

We winsorize the continuous firm-level variables at the top and bottom 1%, which means that the observed values outside the 1% and 99% quantiles are replaced with observed values in those quantiles to exclude the effects of spurious outliers. The descriptive statistics of all variables are shown in Panel A of Table 2. The mean of the IPN is 0.5439, which means that 54.39% of the firms belong to the industries targeted by national industrial policies. The mean of IPL is 0.4305, which means that only 43.05% of the firms are supported by local industrial policies. Hence, firms benefit more from national rather than local industrial policies. Panel B compares the difference of corporate investment (Invest), investment efficiency (Inefficiency) and industrial policy (IP) between SOEs and non-SOEs. The investment of non-SOEs is significantly higher than SOEs, and the investment efficiency of non-SOEs is significantly lower than SOEs. This indicates that non-SOEs make more inefficient investment compared to SOEs. Moreover, SOEs are distributed in industries that get more support from Five-Year Plans of the central government. Non-SOEs are scattered in industries that are more supported by Five-Year Plans of provincial governments. Panel C reports the correlation matrix of key variables; the variance inflation factor (VIF) of these variables is less than 10, indicating there is no serious multicollinearity.

4. Empirical Results

We explore the impact of industrial policy on corporate investment or investment efficiency by estimating the following Equation (3):
Y i , t = β 0 + β 1 I P i , t + β 2 C o n t r o l s i , t 1 + I n d u s t r y + Y e a r + ε i , t
where Y i , t is the corporate investment (Invest) or investment efficiency (Inefficiency) of firm i at year t . I P i , t is the national (IPN) or local (IPL) industrial policy dummy variable, indicating whether firm i belongs to the target industries at year t . C o n t r o l s i , t 1 are the lagged control variables, including Size, Growth, Leverage, CF, Return and SOE. Industry and Year are the industry and time fixed effects, respectively. ε i , t is the residual term. We estimate Equation (3) using the Ordinary Least Squares method. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level in all specifications for heteroskedasticity [55].

4.1. Industrial Policy and Corporate Investment

Table 3 shows the results of using corporate investment (Invest) as the dependent variable in Equation (3). Columns (1), (2) and (3) show the impact of national industrial policies on the investment of the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. The coefficient of IPN for the full sample is significantly positive at a 1% statistical level, indicating that national industrial policy stimulates corporate investment. The coefficient of IPN for the SOE sample is insignificant, meaning that investment of SOEs is not affected by national industrial policy. The coefficient of IPN for the non-SOE sample is significantly positive at a 1% statistical level, showing that investment of non-SOEs is motivated by national industrial policy. Columns (4), (5) and (6) represent the effects of local industrial policies on the investments of the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. The coefficient of IPL is significantly positive in the full and non-SOE samples, but insignificant in the SOE sample. Overall, both national and local industrial policies have a positive impact on corporate investment, but the effect is heterogenous for SOEs and non-SOEs. Compared with non-SOEs, SOEs have more political connections, so their investment is less sensitive to policy shocks [51]. Hence, the positive effect of industrial policies is significant for non-SOEs, supporting our Hypothesis 1.
Moreover, the economic significance of local industrial policies on corporate investment is weaker than that of national industrial policies. Looking at the coefficient of the full sample, the coefficient of IPN is 0.0048, meaning that, ceteris paribus, compared with firms not supported by national industrial policy, the investment of target firms increases 0.48%. Meanwhile, the coefficient of IPL is 0.0024, indicating that, ceteris paribus, compared with firms not supported by local industrial policy, the investment of targeted firms increases 0.24%. The differences between national and local industrial policies can be explained by the hierarchical effect: local industrial policy is formulated according to national industrial policy, with weaker guidance and compulsory administration.

4.2. Industrial Policy and Corporate Investment Efficiency

Table 4 provides the results of using firms’ investment efficiency (Inefficiency) as the dependent variable in Equation (3). Columns (1), (2) and (3) are the impact of national industrial policies on the investment efficiency of the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. The coefficient of IPN for the full sample is significantly positive at a 1% statistical level, indicating that national industrial policy reduces the efficiency of corporate investment. The coefficient of IPN for the SOE sample is insignificant. The coefficient of IPN for the non-SOE sample is significantly positive at a 1% statistical level, which means that national industrial policy induces over-investment among non-SOEs. Columns (4), (5) and (6) show the effects of local industrial policies on the investment efficiency of the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. The coefficient of IPL is significantly positive in the full and non-SOE samples, but insignificant in the SOE sample. These results show that target industrial policies reduce financing constraints and industry barriers, which encourages non-SOEs to make arbitrary investment, but significantly reduces their investment efficiency. However, industrial policies have no effect on the investment efficiency of SOEs, consisting with our Hypothesis 2.
Furthermore, China’s economy has entered a new normal development state; the upgrading of industrial structure becomes the main driver of economic development. Hence, the corporate investment and investment efficiency may be affected by some other policies, such as the implementation of the Mass Entrepreneurship and Innovation Campaign in 2015. Inspired by previous studies, which explore the impact of policy on corporate investing and financing behavior [56], we consider the effect of the new normal of China’s economy and the implementation of the Mass Entrepreneurship and Innovation Campaign in 2015 on the relationship of industrial policies on corporate investment and investment efficiency. Table A1 and Table A2 in Appendix A reports the results of regressing corporate investment and investment efficiency on the industrial policy, with an additional control variable Dummy2015, respectively. Our findings are consistent after considering other policies.

4.3. The Influence Mechanism of Industrial Policy on Investment Efficiency

We explore the influence mechanism of industrial policies on corporate investment efficiency by estimating the following Equation (4):
I n e f f i c i e n c y i , t = γ 0 + γ 1 I P i , t + γ 2 M i , t + γ 3 I P i , t M i , t + γ 4 C o n t r o l s i , t 1 + I n d u s t r y + Y e a r + ε i , t
where I n e f f i c i e n c y i , t is the deviation from optimal investment of firm i at year t . I P i , t is the national (IPN) or local (IPL) industrial policy dummy variable, indicating whether the firm i belongs to target industries at year t . M i , t is the influence mechanism of industrial policy on investment efficiency, including government subsidy (Subsidy) and inter-industry competition (HHI). C o n t r o l s i , t 1 are the lagged control variables, including Size, Growth, Leverage, CF and Return. Industry and Year are the industry and time fixed effects, respectively. ε i , t is the residual term.

4.3.1. Government Subsidy

Table 5 reports the results of using government subsidy (Subsidy) as the mechanism variable in Equation (4). The coefficient of IPN and IPL are significantly positive, consisting with the baseline results. In Column (1), the interaction term IPN *Subsidy is significantly positive at a 5% statistic level, inferring that national industrial policy reduces firms’ investment efficiency by providing government subsidies. Similarly, Column (2) shows that government subsidies enhance the negative effect of local industrial policy on corporate investment efficiency. Therefore, the negative impact of industrial policies on the investment efficiency increases with the amount of government subsidy, supporting our Hypothesis 3. In addition, these results consist with the existing literature examining the relation of government subsidy and corporate investment efficiency [12].

4.3.2. Inter-Industry Competition

Table 6 provides the results of using inter-industry competition (HHI) as the mechanism variable in Equation (4). The coefficient of IPN and IPL are significantly positive, which is consistent with our Hypothesis 1 that industrial policies reduce investment efficiency. In Column (1), the interaction term IPN *HHI is significantly negative at a 1% statistic level, indicating that a higher inter-industry competition will lead to investment inefficiency (a smaller value of HHI means a higher competition). The coefficient of interaction term IPL *HHI in Column (2) illustrates that the negative impact of local industry policy on corporate investment efficiency increases with the degree of inter-industry competition. Thus, Hypothesis 3 is supported.

4.4. Policy Followers and Corporate Investment Efficiency

We also investigate the investment efficiency of firms that made investment decisions referencing to the guidance of industrial policies, defined as policy followers (Follower). Furthermore, we estimate the following Equation (5):
I n e f f i c i e n c y i , t = δ 0 + δ 1 F o l l o w e r i , t + δ 2 C o n t r o l s i , t 1 + I n d u s t r y + Y e a r + ε i , t
where I n e f f i c i e n c y i , t is the deviation from optimal investment of firm i at year t . F o l l o w e r i , t is the dummy variable identifying whether the firm i is a national (FollowerN) or local (FollowerL) policy follower at year t . (The definition of policy follower is described in Section 3.2.2) C o n t r o l s i , t 1 are the lagged control variables, including Size, Growth, Leverage, CF, Return and SOE. Industry and Year are the industry and time fixed effects, respectively. ε i , t is the residual term.
Table 7 shows the empirical results of Equation (5). Columns (1), (2) and (3) present the impact of national industrial policies on policy followers for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. The coefficients of FollowerN are all significantly positive at a 1% statistical level, which means that the investment efficiency of policy followers is negatively affected by national industrial policies. This finding holds for both SOE and non-SOE policy followers. Columns (4), (5) and (6) provide the results of the impact of local industrial policies on policy followers for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. The coefficients of FollowerL are all significantly positive at a 1% statistical level. These results reveal that national and local industrial policies induce policy followers to over-invest blindly, thus reducing their investment efficiency, supporting our Hypothesis 4.
Instead of using the absolute value of deviation from optimal investment as the measure of investment efficiency, we constructed a dummy variable OverInvest to capture whether industrial policies induced the over-investment of policy followers. If the residual of Equation (2) is positive, OverInvest equals 1; otherwise, OverInvest equals 0. We re-estimate Equation (5) by using OverInvest as the dependent variable. The empirical results are shown in Table A3 of Appendix B. The coefficients of FollowerN and FollowerL are all significantly positive at a 1% statistic level, indicating that national and local industrial policies indeed lead policy followers to over-invest.

5. Robustness Checks

The formulation of industrial policy is based on the economic developmental status quo, which is an important factor for corporate investment as well. To eliminate the simultaneous effects and reverse-causality problem, we conducted two-stage least squares regression. In addition, we applied different definitions for investment efficiency and policy follower to test the robustness of our findings.

5.1. 2SLS for the Endogenous Problem

There is a potential sample selection problem that may cause endogeneity. Specifically, the current structure and prospect of industry play a key role in drafting industrial policies. As the investment efficiency varies among industries, the goals of industrial policies in different industries will embody diversities. For example, some policies may target to improve traditional industries, while others focus on promoting emerging industries. Hence, the impact of industrial policy on corporate investment efficiency could be biased, resulting from confounding factors.
Inspired by Heckman’s two-stage selection model [57], we chose economic development and industry factors as the independent variables to calculate the fitted value of industrial policy (Fitted_IP) and Lambda in the first stage. In the second stage, we added the Lambda into Equation (3), and used Fitted_IP as the independent variable to re-estimate the empirical regression.
For the impact of national industrial policy on corporate investment and its efficiency, we use national GDP and industry profitability to estimate the fitted value of national industrial policy (Fitted_IPN) in the first stage. Table 8 reports the results of the second-stage regression. The coefficients of the Fitted_IPN are significantly positive for the full and non-SOE samples, but insignificant for the SOE sample. Although the coefficients of Lambda are significant in some columns, national industrial policy stimulates non-SOEs’ investment at the cost of reducing their investment efficiency, which is consistent with the baseline results in Table 3 and Table 4.
For the impact of local industrial policy on corporate investment and investment efficiency, we use national GDP, provincial GDP and industry profitability to estimate the fitted value of local industrial policy (Fitted_IPL) in the first stage. Table 9 reports the results of the second-stage regression. The coefficients of Fitted_IPL are significantly positive for the full and non-SOE samples, but insignificant for the SOE sample. These results prove that our Hypothesis 1 holds after considering the endogenous problem.

5.2. Change the Definition of Investment Efficiency

Alternatively, we define the investment efficiency as the sensitivity of investment expenditure to investment opportunity [58], and estimate the following Equation (6):
I n v e s t i , t = ω 0 + ω 1 I P i , t + + ω 2 T Q i , t 1 + ω 3 I P i , t T Q i , t 1 + ω 4 C o n t r o l s i , t 1 + I n d u s t r y + Y e a r + ε i , t
where I n v e s t i , t is the investment of firm i in year t , measured as the capital expenditures, divided by total assets at the beginning period.
I P i , t is the national (IPN) or local (IPL) industrial policy dummy variable, indicating whether firm i belongs to the target industries at year t . T Q i , t 1 is the market value of equity, divided by book value of assets of firm i in year t 1 . C o n t r o l s i , t 1 are the lagged control variables, including Size, Growth, Leverage, CF, Return and SOE. Industry and Year are the industry and time fixed effects, respectively. ε i , t is the residual term.
If the coefficient ω 3 of interaction term IP*TQ is significantly negative, industrial policy reduces corporate investment efficiency. Table 10 shows the results of using the sensitivity of investment expenditure to investment opportunity as the measure of investment efficiency. Columns (1), (2) and (3) present the impact of national industrial policy on investment efficiency of the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. The coefficients of IPN are positive, and the coefficients of IPN*TQ are negative for the full and non-SOE samples, indicating that national industrial policy increases corporate investment while reducing its efficiency. However, the investments and investment efficiency of SOEs are not affected by national industrial policy. Columns (4), (5) and (6) show that local industrial policy has a positive influence on investment, but a negative impact on efficiency for the full and non-SOE samples. Thus, our baseline results are robust to a different measure of investment efficiency.

5.3. Change the Definition of Policy Followers

Considering that increased corporate investment may result from other factors that are irrelevant to industrial policy (for example, a new patent or an unexpected technique breakthrough), we refined the definition of policy followers. If the increased investment of firm in target industry in year t is higher than the average of its increased investment in year t 1 and t 2 , the dummy variable Follower_R equals 1; otherwise, Follower_R equals 0. Table 11 presents the results of the impact of industrial policy on the investment efficiency of policy followers. The coefficients of Follower_RN and Follower_RL are all significantly positive at a 1% statistic level for all samples. Therefore, industrial policies reduce the investment efficiency of policy followers, supporting Hypothesis 4. In addition, to verify the accuracy of the definition of policy follower, we randomly check the investment announcements of corporations from the policy followers. We find that policy followers mention they make investments references to following national or local industrial policies.

6. Discussion

We investigate the impact of industrial policy on corporate investment and investment efficiency from the perspective of Chinese Five-Year Plans. Using four Five-Year Plans covering the periods from 2001 to 2020, we match the firm-level data with target industries of the industrial policies. We document compelling evidence of the negative effect of industrial policy on corporate investment efficiency. As one form of government intervention, the industrial policy stimulates corporate investment at the cost of reducing investment efficiency. However, we do not observe such evidence in SOEs.
Existing literatures find that government interventions significantly promote the investment of SOEs, and distort their optimal investment by political connections [25,35]. On the contrary, we argue that industrial policies harm investment efficiency of non-SOEs, due to economic policy uncertainty, which plays a crucial role in corporate investment [24,51,59]. Although non-SOEs targeted by industrial policy make inefficient investments, it may be a rational investment decision for them. Compared with SOEs, non-SOEs are less politically connected and it is harder for them to keep in touch with the government [60], thereby making it more difficult to track the industrial policy changes. When non-SOEs expose to supportive industrial policies, they may make investment decisions blindly to cater to policies.
Our study sheds light on the impact of industrial policy on investment efficiency of firms with different ownership status. Since non-SOEs face higher economic policy uncertainty, making more investments may be the best option for them, even though it will harm their investment efficiency. Hence, there is an urgent need for policy-makers to formulate reasonable policies to effectively guide the investment behavior of non-SOEs.

7. Conclusions

Based on the micro-level data of A-share listed firms on China’s stock market and the four Five-Year Plans during 2001 to 2020, we explored whether industrial policies have different effects on the investment and efficiency of SOEs and non-SOEs, respectively. Our findings provided a new insight on the impact of industrial policy, from the perspective of corporate investment and investment efficiency. Firstly, target industrial policies have a positive impact on investment of non-SOEs; however, they distort their investment efficiency. Moreover, compared to local industrial policies, national industrial policies have a stronger marginal effect on corporate investment and investment efficiency. Nevertheless, target industrial policies have no significant influence on the investment and efficiency of SOEs. Secondly, industrial policies affect corporate investment efficiency through government subsidy and inter-industry competition. The investment efficiency of non-SOEs decreases with the increase in the amount of government subsidy and the degree of inter-industry competition. Finally, industrial policies induce over-investment behaviors among policy followers, and have a negative effect on their investment efficiency, holding for both SOE and non-SOE policy followers.
Overall, industrial policies stimulate the investment of non-SOEs, by eliminating financial constraints and reducing industry barriers, but at the cost of reducing their investment efficiency. Therefore, to improve the effectiveness of industrial policies, governments should pay great attention to enhancing the investment efficiency of non-SOEs, by cutting down unnecessary government subsidies and preventing excessive inter-industry competition. More importantly, it is necessary to maintain the continuity and stability of industrial policies, which contribute to create favorable expectations for the investment decisions of non-SOEs, thereby avoiding inefficient investments. Given that industrial policies have little impact on the investment of SOEs, they will play an important part in smooth economic fluctuations. SOEs can maintain the investments of projects related to the macroeconomy and people’s livelihoods in a downward economic cycle.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, T.W. and H.Z.; Data curation, T.W. and R.W.; Methodology, T.W. and R.W.; Software, T.W. and R.W.; Supervision, H.Z.; Writing—original draft, T.W. and R.W.; Writing—review and editing, T.W. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

The study was conducted in accordance with the Declaration of Helsinki, and approved by the Institutional Review Board (or Ethics Committee) of Zhejiang University.

Informed Consent Statement

Informed consent was obtained from all subjects involved in the study.

Data Availability Statement

The data used in this study are available on request from the corresponding author.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Nomenclature

SOEsState-owned enterprises
Non-SOEsNon-state-owned enterprises
Five-Year PlanThe Five-Year Plan for National Economic and Social Development
National industrial policyThe Five-Year Plan for National Economic and Social Development, published by Chinese central government departments
Local industrial policyThe Five-Year Plan for National Economic and Social Development, published by Chinese provincial government departments
Policy followersFirms in target industries that increase investment after the implement of supporting industrial policies
CSRCChina Securities Regulatory Commission
CSMARChina Stock Market and Accounting Research

Appendix A

Inspired by previous studies which explored the impact of policy on corporate investing and financing behavior [56], we considered the effect of the new normal of China’s economy and the implementation of the Mass Entrepreneurship and Innovation Campaign in 2015 on the relationship of industrial policies on corporate investment and investment efficiency. Specifically, we defined a dummy variable Dummy2015 to capture the consequences of the policies in 2015. Dummy2015 equals 1 for years after 2015; otherwise, Dummy2015 equals 0. Table A1 reports the results of regress corporate investment on the industrial policy with an additional control variable Dummy2015. The coefficients of IPN and IPL are still significantly positive for total and non-SOE samples, but insignificant for SOE samples. The coefficients of Dummy2015 are significantly negative for all regressions, which means that firms make investment decisions more cautiously after the new normal of China’s economy and the implementation of the Mass Entrepreneurship and Innovation Campaign. The positive effect of industrial policies on corporate investment for non-SOEs is not affected by the policies in 2015. This is robust to our baseline results in Table 3.
Table A1. The impact of the new normal of China’s economy and the implementation of the Mass Entrepreneurship and Innovation Campaign on corporate investment.
Table A1. The impact of the new normal of China’s economy and the implementation of the Mass Entrepreneurship and Innovation Campaign on corporate investment.
Dependent Variable:
Invest
Independent Variable: IPNIndependent Variable: IPL
Total
(1)
SOE
(2)
Non-SOE
(3)
Total
(4)
SOE
(5)
Non-SOE
(6)
IP0.0064 ***0.00240.0101 ***0.0017−0.00090.0043 **
(0.0000)(0.1902)(0.0000)(0.1682)(0.6328)(0.0109)
Dummy2015−0.0242 ***−0.0288 ***−0.0207 ***−0.0258 ***−0.0292 ***−0.0233 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Size0.0025 ***0.00060.0041 ***0.0024 ***0.00060.0039 ***
(0.0000)(0.4778)(0.0000)(0.0001)(0.4971)(0.0000)
Growth0.0071 ***0.0064 ***0.0071 ***0.0071 ***0.0064 ***0.0072 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Leverage−0.0167 ***−0.0035−0.0254 ***−0.0171 ***−0.0035−0.0258 ***
(0.0000)(0.4806)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.4768)(0.0000)
CF0.0716 ***0.0952 ***0.0511 ***0.0715 ***0.0956 ***0.0502 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Return0.0056 ***0.0049 ***0.0060 ***0.0056 ***0.0049 ***0.0060 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
SOE−0.0077 *** −0.0075 ***
(0.0000) (0.0000)
Constant0.0614 ***0.0586 ***0.0560 ***0.0652 ***0.0605 ***0.0614 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Industry FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations30,79514,36916,42630,79514,36916,426
AdjustR20.12500.17420.10340.12390.17410.1013
This table reports the results of using corporate investment (Invest) as the dependent variable in Equation (3). For all regressions, we added Dummy2015 as a control variable to capture the effect of the new normal of China’s economy and the implementation of the Mass Entrepreneurship and Innovation Campaign in 2015. Columns (1), (2) and (3) present the impact of national industrial policies on the investments for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. Columns (4), (5) and (6) show the effects of local industrial policies on the investments for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. All variables are defined in Table 1. We control industry and year fixed effects for all of the regressions. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level, and p-statistics are reported in parentheses. ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 5 and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Table A2 shows the empirical results of regress investment efficiency on the industrial policy, with an additional control variable Dummy2015. The coefficients of IPN and IPL remain significantly positive for total and non-SOE samples, but insignificant for SOE samples. The coefficients of Dummy2015 are significantly negative for all regressions, indicating that the investment efficiency of firms experience a notable improvement after the new normal of China’s economy and the implementation of the Mass Entrepreneurship and Innovation Campaign. The negative role of industrial policies on investment efficiency for non-SOEs is robust to the policies in 2015, which is consistent with our baseline results in Table 4.
Table A2. The impact of the new normal of China’s economy and the implementation of the Mass Entrepreneurship and Innovation Campaign on investment efficiency.
Table A2. The impact of the new normal of China’s economy and the implementation of the Mass Entrepreneurship and Innovation Campaign on investment efficiency.
Dependent Variable:
Inefficiency
Independent Variable: IPNIndependent Variable: IPL
Total
(1)
SOE
(2)
Non-SOE
(3)
Total
(4)
SOE
(5)
Non-SOE
(6)
IP0.0033 ***0.00020.0061 ***0.00090.00010.0017 **
(0.0000)(0.8626)(0.0000)(0.1208)(0.9122)(0.0370)
Dummy2015−0.0062 ***−0.0091 ***−0.0040 ***−0.0070 ***−0.0092 ***−0.0055 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Size−0.0032 ***−0.0034 ***−0.0028 ***−0.0032 ***−0.0034 ***−0.0030 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Growth0.0035 ***0.0025 ***0.0038 ***0.0035 ***0.0025 ***0.0039 ***
(0.0000)(0.0003)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0003)(0.0000)
Leverage−0.0053 ***−0.0035−0.0061 ***−0.0055 ***−0.0035−0.0064 ***
(0.0008)(0.1291)(0.0055)(0.0006)(0.1276)(0.0038)
CF0.0251 ***0.0327 ***0.0195 ***0.0250 ***0.0327 ***0.0190 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Return0.0034 ***0.0026 ***0.0041 ***0.0034 ***0.0026 ***0.0041 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
SOE−0.0035 *** −0.0034 ***
(0.0000) (0.0000)
Constant0.0456 ***0.0460 ***0.0413 ***0.0475 ***0.0460 ***0.0449 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Industry FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations30,77914,36516,41430,77914,36516,414
Adjust R20.08670.11910.06750.08580.11910.0645
This table reports the results of using investment efficiency (Inefficiency) as the dependent variable in Equation (3). For all regressions, we add Dummy2015 as a control variable to capture the effect of new normal of China’s economy and the implementation of the Mass Entrepreneurship and Innovation Campaign in 2015. Columns (1), (2) and (3) present the impact of national industrial policies on the investment efficiency for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. Columns (4), (5) and (6) show the effects of local industrial policies on the investment efficiency for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. All variables are defined in Table 1. We control industry and year fixed effects for all of the regressions. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level, and p-statistics are reported in parentheses. ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 5 and 1 percent levels, respectively.

Appendix B

Table A3. The over-investment behavior of policy followers.
Table A3. The over-investment behavior of policy followers.
Dependent Variable: OverInvestIndependent Variable: FollowerNIndependent Variable: FollowerL
Total
(1)
SOE
(2)
Non-SOE
(3)
Total
(4)
SOE
(5)
Non-SOE
(6)
Follower0.5087 ***0.4916 ***0.5244 ***0.4909 ***0.4702 ***0.5085 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Size0.0385 ***0.0254 ***0.0515 ***0.0432 ***0.0247 ***0.0615 ***
(0.0000)(0.0005)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0049)(0.0000)
Growth0.0227 ***0.0283 ***0.0163 *0.0412 ***0.0417 ***0.0357 ***
(0.0008)(0.0055)(0.0756)(0.0000)(0.0025)(0.0007)
Leverage0.0977 ***0.1847 ***0.04970.04300.1071 **0.0269
(0.0002)(0.0000)(0.1550)(0.1421)(0.0242)(0.4729)
CF0.1569 ***0.2558 ***0.04750.07540.1853 **−0.0333
(0.0008)(0.0006)(0.4269)(0.1319)(0.0269)(0.5893)
Return−0.0510 ***−0.0563 ***−0.0447 ***−0.0390 ***−0.0461 ***−0.0362 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0006)(0.0002)
SOE−0.0316 *** −0.0440 ***
(0.0054) (0.0008)
Constant−0.0139−0.0474 *−0.0263−0.0010−0.0102−0.0479 *
(0.4309)(0.0906)(0.2187)(0.9621)(0.7697)(0.0563)
Industry FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations16,4087939846913,47458607614
Adjust R20.28300.27060.31000.26630.24850.2927
This table shows the robustness test by testing the over-investment behavior of policy followers. We constructed the dummy variable OverInvest to capture whether industrial policies induce the over-investment of policy followers. Specifically, if the residual of equation (2) is positive, the company over-invest and OverInvest equals 1; otherwise, OverInvest equals 0. Columns (1), (2) and (3) represent the investment efficiency of the national industrial policy followers for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. Columns (4), (5) and (6) provide the investment efficiency of local industrial policy followers for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level, and p-statistics are reported in parentheses. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels, respectively.

References

  1. Lv, P.; Spigarelli, F. The Determinants of Location Choice: Chinese Foreign Direct Investments in the European Renewable Energy Sector. Int. J. Emerg. Mark. 2016, 11, 333–356. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Firth, M.; Gong, S.X.; Shan, L. Cost of Government and Firm Value. J. Corp. Financ. 2013, 21, 136–152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Kline, P.; Moretti, E. Local Economic Development, Agglomeration Economies, and the Big Push: 100 Years of Evidence from the Tennessee Valley Authority. Q. J. Econ. 2014, 129, 275–331. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  4. Chen, D.; Li, O.Z.; Xin, F. Five-Year Plans, China Finance and Their Consequences. China J. Account. Res. 2017, 10, 189–230. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Kollmann, R.; Roeger, W.; Veld, J.I. Fiscal Policy in a Financial Crisis: Standard Policy versus Bank Rescue Measures. Am. Econ. Rev. 2012, 102, 77–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Wallsten, S.J. The Effects of Government-Industry R&D Programs on Private R&D: The Case of the Small Business Innovation Research Program. RAND J. Econ. 2000, 31, 82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Xu, R.; Shen, Y.; Liu, M.; Li, L.; Xia, X.; Luo, K. Can Government Subsidies Improve Innovation Performance? Evidence from Chinese Listed Companies. Econ. Model. 2022, 120, 106151. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Nolan, P. Globalisation and Industrial Policy: The Case of China. World Econ. 2014, 37, 747–764. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Hsieh, C.-T.; Klenow, P.J. Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India. Q. J. Econ. 2009, 124, 1403–1448. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Du, L.; Harrison, A.; Jefferson, G. FDI Spillovers and Industrial Policy: The Role of Tariffs and Tax Holidays. World Dev. 2014, 64, 366–383. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Chen, Y.-R.; Jiang, X.; Weng, C.-H. Can Government Industrial Policy Enhance Corporate Bidding? The Evidence of China. Pac.-Basin Financ. J. 2020, 60, 101288. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Hu, J.; Jiang, H.; Holmes, M. Government Subsidies and Corporate Investment Efficiency: Evidence from China. Emerg. Mark. Rev. 2019, 41, 100658. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Firth, M.; Malatesta, P.H.; Xin, Q.; Xu, L. Corporate Investment, Government Control, and Financing Channels: Evidence from China’s Listed Companies. J. Corp. Financ. 2012, 18, 433–450. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Claessens, S.; Feijen, E.; Laeven, L. Political Connections and Preferential Access to Finance: The Role of Campaign Contributions. J. Financ. Econ. 2008, 88, 554–580. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Cull, R.; Xu, L.C. Who Gets Credit? The Behavior of Bureaucrats and State Banks in Allocating Credit to Chinese State-Owned Enterprises. J. Dev. Econ. 2003, 71, 533–559. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Fama, E.F.; French, K.R. The Corporate Cost of Capital and the Return on Corporate Investment. J. Financ. 1999, 54, 1939–1967. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Duchin, R.; Ozbas, O.; Sensoy, B.A. Costly External Finance, Corporate Investment, and the Subprime Mortgage Credit Crisis. J. Financ. Econ. 2010, 97, 418–435. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Morellec, E.; Schürhoff, N. Corporate Investment and Financing under Asymmetric Information. J. Financ. Econ. 2011, 99, 262–288. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Babenko, I.; Lemmon, M.; Tserlukevich, Y. Employee Stock Options and Investment. J. Financ. 2011, 66, 981–1009. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Ozdagli, A.K. Financial Leverage, Corporate Investment, and Stock Returns. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2012, 25, 1033–1069. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Almeida, H.; Campello, M. Financial Constraints, Asset Tangibility, and Corporate Investment. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2007, 20, 1429–1460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Malmendier, U.; Tate, G. CEO Overconfidence and Corporate Investment. J. Financ. 2005, 60, 2661–2700. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Butler, A.W.; Cornaggia, J.; Grullon, G.; Weston, J.P. Corporate Financing Decisions, Managerial Market Timing, and Real Investment. J. Financ. Econ. 2011, 101, 666–683. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Gulen, H.; Ion, M. Policy Uncertainty and Corporate Investment. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2015, 29, 523–564. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  25. Alok, S.; Ayyagari, M. Politics, State Ownership, and Corporate Investments. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2020, 33, 3031–3087. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Biddle, G.C.; Hilary, G.; Verdi, R.S. How Does Financial Reporting Quality Relate to Investment Efficiency? J. Account. Econ. 2009, 48, 112–131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Biddle, G.C.; Callahan, C.M.; Hong, H.A.; Knowles, R.L. Do Adoptions of International Financial Reporting Standards Enhance Capital Investment Efficiency? SSRN J. 2013, volume, page. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Gompers, P.; Ishii, J.; Metrick, A. Corporate Governance and Equity Prices. Q. J. Econ. 2003, 118, 107–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Li, K.-F.; Liao, Y.-P. Directors’ and Officers’ Liability Insurance and Investment Efficiency: Evidence from Taiwan. Pac.-Basin Financ. J. 2014, 29, 18–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Zhang, H.; Li, L.; Zhou, D.; Zhou, P. Political Connections, Government Subsidies and Firm Financial Performance: Evidence from Renewable Energy Manufacturing in China. Renew. Energy 2014, 63, 330–336. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Brandt, L.; Li, H. Bank Discrimination in Transition Economies: Ideology, Information, or Incentives? J. Comp. Econ. 2003, 31, 387–413. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  32. Chen, C.J.P.; Li, Z.; Su, X.; Sun, Z. Rent-Seeking Incentives, Corporate Political Connections, and the Control Structure of Private Firms: Chinese Evidence. J. Corp. Financ. 2011, 17, 229–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Lin, J.Y.; Cai, F.; Zhou, L. Competition, Policy Burdens, and State-Owned Enterprise Reform. Am. Econ. Rev. 1998, 88, 422–427. [Google Scholar]
  34. Fazzari, S.M.; Hubbard, R.G.; Petersen, B.C.; Blinder, A.S.; Poterba, J.M. Financing Constraints and Corporate Investment. Brook. Pap. Econ. Act. 1988, 1988, 141. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Chen, S.; Sun, Z.; Tang, S.; Wu, D. Government Intervention and Investment Efficiency: Evidence from China. J. Corp. Financ. 2011, 17, 259–271. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Aghion, P.; Cai, J.; Dewatripont, M.; Du, L.; Harrison, A.; Legros, P. Industrial Policy and Competition. Am. Econ. J. Macroecon. 2015, 7, 1–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  37. Liao, G.; Chen, X.; Jing, X.; Sun, J. Policy Burdens, Firm Performance, and Management Turnover. China Econ. Rev. 2009, 20, 15–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Chen, Q.; Goldstein, I.; Jiang, W. Price Informativeness and Investment Sensitivity to Stock Price. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2007, 20, 619–650. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Huang, Z.; Li, L.; Ma, G.; Qian, J. The Reversal of Privatization in China: A Political Economy Perspective. J. Corp. Financ. 2021, 71, 102115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Wang, Y.; Wei, Y.; Song, F.M. Uncertainty and Corporate R&D Investment: Evidence from Chinese Listed Firms. Int. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2017, 47, 176–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Datta, S.; Iskandar-Datta, M.; Singh, V. Product Market Power, Industry Structure, and Corporate Earnings Management. J. Bank. Financ. 2013, 37, 3273–3285. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Piotroski, J.D.; Zhang, T. Politicians and the IPO Decision: The Impact of Impending Political Promotions on IPO Activity in China. J. Financ. Econ. 2014, 111, 111–136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Brollo, F.; Nannicini, T.; Perotti, R.; Tabellini, G. The Political Resource Curse. Am. Econ. Rev. 2013, 103, 1759–1796. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  44. Ding, Y.; Chen, G. How Do Innovation-Driven Policies Help Sports Firms Sustain Growth? The Mediating Role of R&D Investment. Sustainability 2022, 14, 15688. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Beaudry, C. Entry, Growth and Patenting in Industrial Clusters: A Study of the Aerospace Industry in the UK. Int. J. Econ. Bus. 2001, 8, 405–436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  46. Ozoguz, A.; Rebello, M.J.; Wardlaw, M. Information, Competition, and Investment Sensitivity to Peer Stock Prices. SSRN J. 2018, volume, page. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Castaño-Martínez, M.-S. Product Innovation and R&D Policy: The Case of the Transformation Industries in Developed and Developing. Int. Entrep. Manag. J. 2012, 8, 421–436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Komlenovic, S.; Mamun, A.; Mishra, D. Business Cycle and Aggregate Industry Mergers. J. Econ. Finan. 2011, 35, 239–259. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. China Securities Regulatory Commission. Guidelines on Industry Classification of Listed Companies; China Securities Regulatory Commission: Beijing, China, 2001.
  50. Richardson, S. Over-Investment of Free Cash Flow. Rev. Acc. Stud. 2006, 11, 159–189. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Wang, Y.; Chen, C.R.; Huang, Y.S. Economic Policy Uncertainty and Corporate Investment: Evidence from China. Pac.-Basin Financ. J. 2014, 26, 227–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Foucault, T.; Frésard, L. Cross-Listing, Investment Sensitivity to Stock Price, and the Learning Hypothesis. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2012, 25, 3305–3350. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Dougal, C.; Parsons, C.A.; Titman, S. Urban Vibrancy and Corporate Growth: Urban Vibrancy and Corporate Growth. J. Financ. 2015, 70, 163–210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. MacKay, P.; Phillips, G.M. How Does Industry Affect Firm Financial Structure? Rev. Financ. Stud. 2005, 18, 1433–1466. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  55. Petersen, M.A. Estimating Standard Errors in Finance Panel Data Sets: Comparing Approaches. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2009, 22, 435–480. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  56. Zhang, X.; Xu, L. Firm Life Cycle and Debt Maturity Structure: Evidence from China. Acc. Financ. 2021, 61, 937–976. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Heckman, J.J. Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error. Econometrica 1979, 47, 153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Baker, M.; Stein, J.C.; Wurgler, J. When Does the Market Matter? Stock Prices and the Investment of Equity-Dependent Firms. Q. J. Econ. 2003, 118, 969–1005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  59. Zhang, C.; Yang, C.; Liu, C. Economic Policy Uncertainty and Corporate Risk-Taking: Loss Aversion or Opportunity Expectations. Pac.-Basin Financ. J. 2021, 69, 101640. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Deng, Y.; Morck, R.; Wu, J.; Yeung, B. Monetary and Fiscal Stimuli, Ownership Structure, and China’s Housing Market; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2011; p. w16871. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Generalized research structure.
Figure 1. Generalized research structure.
Sustainability 15 00732 g001
Table 1. Variable definitions.
Table 1. Variable definitions.
VariableDefinition
InvestThe capital expenditures divided by total assets at the beginning period
InefficiencyThe absolute residual of Equation (1)
IPIf the firm belongs to the target national industrial policy, then IPN equals 1; otherwise, IPN equals 0 If the firm is targeted by local industrial policy, then IPL equals 1; otherwise, IPL equals 0
SubsidyThe log of government subsidy
HHIThe HHI index of the industry
FollowerIf the investment of the firm of target national industrial policy in year t is higher than in year t − 1, then FollowerN equals 1; otherwise, FollowerN equals 0. If the investment of the firm of target local industrial policy in year t is higher than in year t − 1, then FollowerL equals 1; otherwise, FollowerL equals 0
SizeThe log of total assets
GrowthThe operating income growth rate
LeverageThe ratio of liabilities to assets
CFThe operating cash flow
ReturnThe stock return
SOEThe ownership status of firm (SOE) equals 1 if firm is state-owned (including central-controlled, local-controlled, city governments and state-owned assets management company); otherwise, SOE equals 0
This table presents the definition of variables used in the paper.
Table 2. Summary statistics.
Table 2. Summary statistics.
Panel A. Descriptive statistics
MeanSt. DevMinMedianMaxObs.
Invest0.06310.06960.00020.04050.407133,680
Inefficiency0.03250.03710.00030.02150.220230,915
IPN0.54390.49810.00001.00001.000033,790
IPL0.43050.49520.00000.00001.000033,790
FollowerN0.43200.49540.00000.00001.000016,418
FollowerL0.43250.49540.00000.00001.000013,479
Subsidy0.10900.5322−2.11790.04353.159025,203
HHI0.15300.14790.02020.10881.000033,678
Size3.59941.31860.85543.43568.019733,707
Growth0.18340.4868−0.64120.10753.700933,706
Leverage0.46180.20490.05300.46510.945933,707
CF0.07980.1031−0.24270.06970.526433,703
Return0.19140.7030−0.7216−0.01123.435033,702
SOE0.45760.49820.00000.00001.000033,788
Panel B. The comparison between SOEs and non-SOEs
Mean of SOEMean of non−SOEDifferenceT value
Invest0.04730.0518−0.0045 ***−5.2472
Inefficiency0.03500.0363−0.0013 ***−2.6741
IPN0.55140.51540.0359 ***6.3251
IPL0.40770.4648−0.0571 ***−10.1185
Panel C. Correlation matrix
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)
Invest1
Inefficiency0.2791 ***1
IPC0.0437 ***0.0294 ***1
IPL−0.0056−0.0105 *0.2383 ***1
Size0.0317 ***−0.0925 ***−0.0958 ***0.0272 ***1
Growth0.1054 ***0.0877 ***0.0292 ***−0.0194 ***0.0097 *1
Leverage−0.0274 ***−0.0503 ***−0.0572 ***−0.0713 ***0.3461 ***0.0409 ***1
CF0.0702 ***0.0391 ***−0.0676 ***0.0886 ***0.1024 ***0.0110 *−0.2116 ***1
Return0.0411 ***0.0222 ***0.0237 ***−0.0147 ***−0.0609 ***0.1012 ***−0.0025−0.0305 ***1
This table displays summary statistics for key variables. Panel A shows the descriptive statistics of variables, Panel B presents the mean value test of SOEs and non-SOEs, and Panel C is the correlation matrix. All of the firm-level variables are winsorized at the 1% and 99% levels to mitigate the effects of outliers. The definitions of the variables are given in Table 1. * and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Table 3. The impact of industrial policy on corporate investment.
Table 3. The impact of industrial policy on corporate investment.
Dependent Variable: InvestIndependent Variable: IPNIndependent Variable: IPL
Total
(1)
SOE
(2)
Non-SOE
(3)
Total
(4)
SOE
(5)
Non-SOE
(6)
IP0.0048 ***0.00050.0088 ***0.0024 *0.00060.0041 **
(0.0006)(0.7793)(0.0000)(0.0554)(0.7571)(0.0145)
Size0.0038 ***0.0027 ***0.0047 ***0.0038 ***0.0027 ***0.0047 ***
(0.0000)(0.0034)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0033)(0.0000)
Growth0.0055 ***0.0048 ***0.0054 ***0.0055 ***0.0048 ***0.0055 ***
(0.0000)(0.0001)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0001)(0.0000)
Leverage−0.0179 ***−0.0042−0.0221 ***−0.0182 ***−0.0042−0.0228 ***
(0.0000)(0.3981)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.3930)(0.0000)
CF0.0775 ***0.0972 ***0.0612 ***0.0780 ***0.0973 ***0.0616 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Return0.0102 ***0.0080 ***0.0117 ***0.0102 ***0.0080 ***0.0117 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
SOE−0.0089 *** −0.0089 ***
(0.0000) (0.0000)
Constant0.0477 ***0.0413 ***0.0420 ***0.0492 ***0.0414 ***0.0449 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Industry FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations30,79514,36916,42630,79514,36916,426
Adjust R20.13420.18690.11540.13370.18690.1140
This table reports the results of using corporate investment (Invest) as the dependent variable in Equation (3). Columns (1), (2) and (3) present the impact of national industrial policies on the investments for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. Columns (4), (5) and (6) show the effects of local industrial policies on the investments of the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. All variables are defined in Table 1. We control industry and year fixed effects for all of the regressions. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level, and p-statistics are reported in parentheses. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Table 4. The impact of industrial policy on corporate investment efficiency.
Table 4. The impact of industrial policy on corporate investment efficiency.
Dependent Variable: InefficiencyIndependent Variable: IPNIndependent Variable: IPL
Total
(1)
SOE
(2)
Non-SOE
(3)
Total
(4)
SOE
(5)
Non-SOE
(6)
IP0.0027 ***−0.00060.0058 ***0.0013 **0.00080.0018 **
(0.0001)(0.5165)(0.0000)(0.0257)(0.3488)(0.0348)
Size−0.0024 ***−0.0023 ***−0.0023 ***−0.0024 ***−0.0023 ***−0.0023 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Growth0.0026 ***0.0018 **0.0029 ***0.0026 ***0.0018 **0.0029 ***
(0.0000)(0.0119)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0117)(0.0000)
Leverage−0.0068 ***−0.0039 *−0.0066 ***−0.0070 ***−0.0039 *−0.0070 ***
(0.0000)(0.0918)(0.0054)(0.0000)(0.0882)(0.0032)
CF0.0239 ***0.0303 ***0.0198 ***0.0242 ***0.0300 ***0.0202 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Return0.0063 ***0.0047 ***0.0075 ***0.0063 ***0.0047 ***0.0075 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
SOE−0.0043 *** −0.0043 ***
(0.0000) (0.0000)
Constant0.0411 ***0.0389 ***0.0376 ***0.0420 ***0.0382 ***0.0399 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Industry FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations30,77914,36516,41430,77914,36516,414
Adjust R20.09520.13140.07500.09470.13140.0726
This table reports the results of corporate investment efficiency (Inefficiency) as the dependent variable in Equation (3). Columns (1), (2) and (3) are the impact of national industrial policies on the investment efficiency of the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. Columns (4), (5) and (6) show the effects of local industrial policies on the investment efficiency of the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. All variables are defined in Table 1. We control industry and year fixed effects for all of the regressions. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level, and p-statistics are reported in parentheses. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Table 5. The mechanism influence of industrial policy: Government subsidy.
Table 5. The mechanism influence of industrial policy: Government subsidy.
Dependent Variable: InefficiencyIndependent Variable: IPNIndependent Variable: IPL
(1)(2)
IP0.0011 *0.0009 *
(0.0953)(0.0881)
IP*Subsidy0.0029 **0.0018 *
(0.0313)(0.0717)
Subsidy−0.0013−0.0006
(0.1832)(0.3853)
Size−0.0017 ***−0.0017 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)
Growth0.0026 ***0.0026 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)
Leverage−0.0092 ***−0.0094 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)
CF0.0241 ***0.0243 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)
Return0.0064 ***0.0064 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)
Constant0.0372 ***0.0375 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)
Industry FEYesYes
Year FEYesYes
Observations20,59020,590
Adjust R20.11450.1142
This table reports the mechanism of industrial policy affecting corporate investment efficiency through government subsidy (Subsidy). The independent variable in Columns (1) and (2) is national and local industrial policy, respectively. All variables are defined in Table 1. We control industry and year fixed effects for all of the regressions. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level, and p-statistics are reported in parentheses. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Table 6. The mechanism influence of industrial policy: Inter-industry competition.
Table 6. The mechanism influence of industrial policy: Inter-industry competition.
Dependent Variable: InefficiencyIndependent Variable: IPNIndependent Variable: IPL
(1)(2)
IP0.0020 ***0.0005 *
(0.0034)(0.0802)
IP*HHI−0.0086 ***−0.0071 ***
(0.0006)(0.0083)
HHI−0.0025−0.0005
(0.1912)(0.7564)
Size−0.0016 ***−0.0016 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)
Growth0.0020 ***0.0020 ***
(0.0001)(0.0001)
Leverage−0.0127 ***−0.0124 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)
CF0.0268 ***0.0269 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)
Return0.0055 ***0.0055 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)
Constant−0.0016 ***−0.0016 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)
Industry FEYesYes
Year FEYesYes
Observations24,04224,042
Adjust R20.06760.0671
This table reports the mechanism of industrial policy affecting corporate investment efficiency through inter-industry competition (HHI). The independent variable in Columns (1) and (2) is national and local industrial policy, respectively. All variables are defined in Table 1. We control industry and year fixed effects for all of the regressions. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level, and p-statistics are reported in parentheses. * and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Table 7. The impact of industrial policy on the investment efficiency of policy followers.
Table 7. The impact of industrial policy on the investment efficiency of policy followers.
Dependent Variable: InefficiencyIndependent Variable: FollowerNIndependent Variable: FollowerL
Total
(1)
SOE
(2)
Non-SOE
(3)
Total
(4)
SOE
(5)
Non-SOE
(6)
Follower0.0086 ***0.0073 ***0.0098 ***0.0084 ***0.0070 ***0.0095 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Size−0.0015 ***−0.0011 *−0.0016 ***−0.0012 ***−0.0012 **−0.0013 **
(0.0004)(0.0540)(0.0085)(0.0049)(0.0470)(0.0387)
Growth0.0031 ***0.0030 ***0.0028 ***0.0034 ***0.0023 **0.0038 ***
(0.0000)(0.0010)(0.0013)(0.0000)(0.0201)(0.0001)
Leverage−0.0119 ***−0.0057 *−0.0141 ***−0.0080 ***−0.0046−0.0079 **
(0.0000)(0.0702)(0.0000)(0.0002)(0.1381)(0.0129)
CF0.0189 ***0.0272 ***0.0126 **0.0195 ***0.0306 ***0.0111 **
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0150)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0321)
Return0.0048 ***0.0033 ***0.0063 ***0.0056 ***0.0033 ***0.0071 ***
(0.0000)(0.0004)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0016)(0.0000)
SOE−0.0060 *** −0.0044 ***
(0.0000) (0.0000)
Constant0.0390 ***0.0321 ***0.0371 ***0.0329 ***0.0295 ***0.0312 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Industry FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations16,4087939846913,47458607614
Adjust R20.13570.16140.12070.14220.17620.1276
This table reports the impact of the industrial policy on policy followers’ investment efficiency. Columns (1), (2) and (3) show the investment efficiency of the national industrial policy followers for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. Columns (4), (5) and (6) provide the results of local industrial policy followers for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. All variables are defined in Table 1. We control industry and year fixed effects for all of the regressions. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level, and p-statistics are reported in parentheses. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Table 8. Robustness check: 2SLS for national industrial policy.
Table 8. Robustness check: 2SLS for national industrial policy.
Dependent Variable: InvestDependent Variable: Inefficiency
Total
(1)
SOE
(2)
Non-SOE
(3)
Total
(4)
SOE
(5)
Non-SOE
(6)
Fitted_IPN0.0041 ***0.00020.0078 ***0.0022 ***−0.00070.0047 ***
(0.0023)(0.9147)(0.0001)(0.0013)(0.4092)(0.0000)
Size0.0045 ***0.0031 ***0.0056 ***−0.0016 ***−0.0017 ***−0.0014 ***
(0.0000)(0.0006)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0016)
Growth0.0054 ***0.0050 ***0.0053 ***0.0026 ***0.0019 ***0.0027 ***
(0.0000)(0.0001)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0049)(0.0000)
Leverage−0.0223 ***−0.0073−0.0280 ***−0.0100 ***−0.0061 ***−0.0108 ***
(0.0000)(0.1400)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0064)(0.0000)
CF0.0786 ***0.0981 ***0.0624 ***0.0230 ***0.0306 ***0.0177 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Return0.0101 ***0.0079 ***0.0117 ***0.0061 ***0.0045 ***0.0073 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
SOE−0.0079 *** −0.0038 ***
(0.0000) (0.0000)
Lambda0.0026 ***0.00080.0043 ***−0.0000−0.0012 *0.0011 *
(0.0018)(0.5206)(0.0003)(0.9598)(0.0541)(0.0939)
Constant0.0452 ***0.0401 ***0.0392 ***0.0385 ***0.0369 ***0.0348 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Industry FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations30,79014,36716,42330,77614,36316,413
Adjust R20.15110.19840.13700.11430.14530.0984
This table reports the results of second-stage regression for national industrial policy by using the two-stage selection model. We use national GDP and the profitability of the industry to estimate the fitted value of national industrial policy (Fitted_IPN) in the first stage. Columns (1), (2), and (3) provides the impact of national industrial policies on the investments for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. Columns (4), (5), and (6) provide the effects of national industrial policy on investment efficiency for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. All variables are defined in Table 1. We control industry and year fixed effects for all of the regressions. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level, and p-statistics are reported in parentheses. * and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Table 9. Robustness check: 2SLS for local industrial policy.
Table 9. Robustness check: 2SLS for local industrial policy.
Dependent Variable: InvestDependent Variable: Inefficiency
Total
(1)
SOE
(2)
Non-SOE
(3)
Total
(4)
SOE
(5)
Non-SOE
(6)
Fitted_IPL0.0027 **0.00080.0043 **0.0014 **0.00100.0017 **
(0.0313)(0.6445)(0.0106)(0.0129)(0.2336)(0.0320)
Size0.0045 ***0.0032 ***0.0057 ***−0.0016 ***−0.0017 ***−0.0013 ***
(0.0000)(0.0006)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0001)(0.0017)
Growth0.0054 ***0.0050 ***0.0054 ***0.0026 ***0.0019 ***0.0027 ***
(0.0000)(0.0001)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0048)(0.0000)
Leverage−0.0226 ***−0.0074−0.0287 ***−0.0101 ***−0.0061 ***−0.0112 ***
(0.0000)(0.1375)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0060)(0.0000)
CF0.0790 ***0.0981 ***0.0626 ***0.0233 ***0.0304 ***0.0180 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Return0.0101 ***0.0079 ***0.0117 ***0.0061 ***0.0045 ***0.0073 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
SOE−0.0078 *** −0.0038 ***
(0.0000) (0.0000)
Lambda0.0026 ***0.00080.0042 ***−0.0000−0.0011 *0.0011
(0.0020)(0.5081)(0.0003)(0.9199)(0.0568)(0.1046)
Constant0.0463 ***0.0399 ***0.0415 ***0.0391 ***0.0361 ***0.0366 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Industry FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations30,79014,36716,42330,77614,36316,413
Adjust R20.15090.19840.13610.11410.14540.0967
This table reports the results of second-stage regression for local industrial policy by using the two-stage selection model. We use national GDP, provincial GDP and industry profitability of the to estimate the fitted value of local industrial policy (Fitted_IPL) in the first stage. Columns (1), (2), and (3) provides the impact of local industrial policies on the investments for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. Columns (4), (5) and (6) provide the effects of local industrial policy on investment efficiency for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. All variables are defined in Table 1. We control industry and year fixed effects for all of the regressions. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level, and p-statistics are reported in parentheses. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Table 10. Robustness check: change the definition of investment efficiency.
Table 10. Robustness check: change the definition of investment efficiency.
Dependent Variable: InvestIndependent Variable: IPNIndependent Variable: IPL
Total
(1)
SOE
(2)
Non-SOE
(3)
Total
(4)
SOE
(5)
Non-SOE
(6)
IP0.0075 ***0.00620.0106 ***0.0029 **0.00360.0046 *
(0.0002)(0.1350)(0.0001)(0.0485)(0.2186)(0.0806)
IP*TQ−0.0007 *−0.0018−0.0006 **−0.0001 *−0.0013−0.0002 **
(0.0837)(0.1811)(0.0490)(0.0902)(0.3071)(0.0147)
TQ−0.0010 **−0.0009 *−0.0008 *−0.0013 **−0.0011 **−0.0009 *
(0.0253)(0.0599)(0.0527)(0.0493)(0.0470)(0.0945)
Size0.0047 ***0.0040 ***0.0056 ***0.0048 ***0.0041 ***0.0055 ***
(0.0000)(0.0001)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0001)(0.0000)
Leverage−0.00420.0161 ***−0.0120 **−0.00480.0157 ***−0.0127 ***
(0.2224)(0.0019)(0.0110)(0.1709)(0.0024)(0.0071)
MTB−0.0332 ***−0.0399 ***−0.0299 ***−0.0332 ***−0.0399 ***−0.0297 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Tangibility0.0559 ***0.0444 ***0.0608 ***0.0555 ***0.0441 ***0.0605 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
ROA0.1573 ***0.1976 ***0.1323 ***0.1566 ***0.1964 ***0.1327 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
SOE−0.0097 *** −0.0096 ***
(0.0000) (0.0000)
Constant0.0514 ***0.0454 ***0.0449 ***0.0542 ***0.0471 ***0.0485 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Industry FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations30,61514,31416,30130,61514,31416,301
Adjust R20.14800.20040.12860.14710.20010.1269
This table reports the robustness test by changing the measurement of investment efficiency. We define investment efficiency as the sensitivity of investment expenditure (Invest) to investment opportunities (TQ) [58]. Columns (1), (2) and (3) present the impact of national industrial policies on the investment efficiency for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. Columns (4), (5) and (6) show the effects of local industrial policies on the investment efficiency of the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. All variables are defined in Table 1. We control industry and year fixed effects for all of the regressions. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level, and p-statistics are reported in parentheses. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Table 11. Robustness check: change the definition of policy follower.
Table 11. Robustness check: change the definition of policy follower.
Dependent Variable: InefficiencyIndependent Variable: Follower_RNIndependent Variable: Follower_RL
Total
(1)
SOE
(2)
Non-SOE
(3)
Total
(4)
SOE
(5)
Non-SOE
(6)
Follower_R0.0118 ***0.0112 ***0.0120 ***0.0117 ***0.0108 ***0.0123 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Size−0.0014 ***−0.0011 **−0.0014 **−0.0010 **−0.0009−0.0012 *
(0.0010)(0.0436)(0.0287)(0.0200)(0.1354)(0.0549)
Growth0.0020 ***0.0021 **0.00150.0022 ***0.00070.0027 **
(0.0032)(0.0361)(0.1018)(0.0022)(0.3968)(0.0106)
Leverage−0.0071 ***−0.0032−0.0078 **−0.0051 **−0.0043−0.0032
(0.0015)(0.3116)(0.0262)(0.0170)(0.1455)(0.3192)
CF0.0187 ***0.0247 ***0.0127 **0.0180 ***0.0277 ***0.0105 **
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0158)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0449)
Return0.0045 ***0.0031 ***0.0061 ***0.0052 ***0.0027 **0.0067 ***
(0.0000)(0.0012)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0136)(0.0000)
SOE−0.0054 *** −0.0044 ***
(0.0000) (0.0000)
Constant0.0339 ***0.0288 ***0.0313 ***0.0289 ***0.0264 ***0.0268 ***
(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)(0.0000)
Industry FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year FEYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations14,5407213732712,40055296871
Adjust R20.14870.17560.13030.15200.19020.1336
This table reports the robustness check by changing the definition of policy follower. We refine policy followers (Follower_R) as the increased investment of firm in target industry if year t is higher than the average of their increased investment in year t − 1 and t − 2. Columns (1), (2) and (3) represent the investment efficiency of the national industrial policy followers for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. Columns (4), (5) and (6) provide the investment efficiency of local industrial policy followers for the full, SOE and non-SOE samples, respectively. All variables are defined in Table 1. We control industry and year fixed effects for all of the regressions. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level, and p-statistics are reported in parentheses. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10, 5 and 1 percent levels, respectively.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, T.; Wang, R.; Zhang, H. Does Industrial Policy Reduce Corporate Investment Efficiency? Evidence from China. Sustainability 2023, 15, 732. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010732

AMA Style

Wang T, Wang R, Zhang H. Does Industrial Policy Reduce Corporate Investment Efficiency? Evidence from China. Sustainability. 2023; 15(1):732. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010732

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Ting, Rujun Wang, and Hua Zhang. 2023. "Does Industrial Policy Reduce Corporate Investment Efficiency? Evidence from China" Sustainability 15, no. 1: 732. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010732

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop