Next Article in Journal
Australians’ Financial Wellbeing and Household Debt: A Panel Analysis
Previous Article in Journal
RETRACTED: Salhi (2021). The Relationship between CEO Psychological Biases, Corporate Governance and Corporate Social Responsibility. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 14: 317
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Google Search in Exchange Rate Models: Hype or Hope?

1
Economics Department, ESB Business School, Reutlingen University, 72762 Reutlingen, Germany
2
Reutlingen Research Institute (RRI), Reutlingen University, 72762 Reutlingen, Germany
3
Institute of Finance and Economics (IFE), Reutlingen University, 72762 Reutlingen, Germany
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2021, 14(11), 512; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14110512
Submission received: 12 September 2021 / Revised: 15 October 2021 / Accepted: 19 October 2021 / Published: 25 October 2021
(This article belongs to the Section Economics and Finance)

Abstract

:
This paper studies the power of online search intensity metrics, measured by Google, for examining and forecasting exchange rates. We use panel data consisting of quarterly time series from 2004 to 2018 and ten international countries with the highest currency trading volume. Newly, we include various Google search intensity metrics to our panel data. We find that online search improves the overall econometric models and fits. First, four out of ten search variables are robustly significant at one percent and enhance the macroeconomic exchange rate models. Second, country regressions corroborate the panel results, yet the predictive power of search intensity with regard to exchange rates vary by country. Third, we find higher prediction performance for our exchange rate models with search intensity, particularly in regard to the direction of the exchange rate. Overall, our approach reveals a value-added of search intensity in exchange rate models.
JEL Classification:
D82; D87

1. Introduction

Google processes over three billion queries per day and retains over sixty percent share in the web search market (Desjardins 2018). In 2004, the company launched Google Trends, a free internet facility where the search volume of keywords can be accessed by the public (Helft 2009). This new big data analytics tool is free, user-friendly, and offers data in nearly real time. As official records are published belatedly, online search data appears to be an attractive and timely source of information and opens the gate to new opportunities in empirical research.
The high and growing number of online users indicates that search intensity does reflect individual intentions and expectations (Ginsberg et al. 2009). Recent research papers prove the application of search data to be incrementally broad. For instance, Askitas and Zimmermann (2009) use Google data to forecast unemployment rates. Choi and Varian (2012) use web data to improve the forecast of automobile sales and Vaughan and Chen (2015) use it to identify business cycle turning points. Different in scope and methodology but related to our research is the work by Bulut (2017) and Chai et al. (2018).
In this research, we generalize the exchange rate model by Dornbusch (1976b) with online search intensity metrics and study the predictive power of online data and exchange rates.
We utilize search intensity in order to exhibit the expectation channel of exchange rate movements. Our theoretical approach is based on the well-known (augmented-)overshooting model in the exchange rate literature, which relies on different macroeconomic fundamentals among the most relevant interest rates and inflation (Dornbusch 1976b). Subsequently, we extend the macroeconomic benchmark model by new online-search intensity metrics and examine the role of online data on exchange rate dynamics. Search intensity variables are generated by specific keywords which bear a certain relation to the macroeconomic variables and exchange rates. Thereafter, we evaluate the performance of the different models in regard to the prediction and forecasting performance. The panel regression consists of ten countries and quarterly data from 2004 to 2018. The main research question is whether search intensity improves the models’ performance.
The results reveal that online search intensity variables increase the model’s significance by lowering their standard errors. A single online search variable does add little, except for the following keywords: (a) Inflation, (b) GDP, (c) CPI, (d) job openings, and (e) (currency) exchange rate. Those search intensity variables are significant at 0.1 percent. Noteworthy, the keyword ’interest rate’ is highly significant when estimating the models with raw data only. The country specific regressions reveal that merely the keyword ‘currency+exchange rate’ denotes robustness across all countries.
Looking to the macroeconomic variables, we find strong significance for inflation, interest rate, money supply, relative price of non-tradable goods, debt-to-GDP and terms of trade. This is similar in the country specific regression exercise. The value-added of including online-search keywords is revealed by the outperforming nature of the search intensity-models in general. Nonetheless, conducting research with search data is bound by the quality of the keywords (Lazer et al. 2014). For instance, there could be more searches for the name ‘Apple’ because the word in themselves stands for the fruit and the name of the company.
Overall, there are three major contributions of this research work. First, we demonstrate that search intensity enhances exchange rate models in general, including the prediction and forecasting performance (Tables 6 and 7). Second, broadly defined search indices do not provide a value-added because keyword aggregation eliminates the singularity of the information and narrows the variance (Tables 6 and 7). Third, integrating search intensity in macroeconomic models positively affects the direction of in-sample forecasting (Table 8). On a side note, we corroborate empirical findings in the literature when focusing on the macroeconomic variables alone.
This paper unveils novel insights into the challenging realm of exchange rate economics. Understanding exchange rates is a critical issue in understanding the interplay of the financial and real economy. Hence, this subject is of paramount relevance not only for central banks and governments, but also for businesses and financial investors.
This paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, we review the literature on exchange rates as well as on online data. The data and methodology are prescribed in Section 3. In a series of subsections, we explain the design of different search indices, the different regression models as well as the findings of pre-testing in regard to our panel data. Section 4 contains the main findings. We discuss the results and analyse the policy implications, including limitations. Finally, Section 5 concludes the paper.

2. Literature Review

The dynamic movement of a currency is a spinal question in international economics. In the past decades, economists have examined exchange rate behavior from partly orthogonal angles utilizing either a theoretical or empirical approach.

2.1. Exchange Rate Literature

Theoretical exchange rate models date back to the classical and keynesian schools of thought (Cassel 1918; Dornbusch 1976a; Dornbusch and Krugman 1976; Mundell 1968). Due to fixed exchange rates during the Gold Standard and the Bretton Woods System, most empirical research started after the 1970s (Clark and MacDonald 1998).
For the first time, our empirical study aims to address the complexity of the stochastic nature of exchange rate dynamics by introducing a new determining behavioral variable: Online search intensity. The following literature review highlights work closely related to ours. Note, there are already seminal papers and good reviews in that field (Berkowitz and Giorgianni 2001; Clarida and Gali 1995; Mark 1995; Rogoff 1995; Rossi 2013).
A seminal work on exchange rates is the approach by Mundell and Fleming devised around the 1960s. The Mundell-Fleming model describes the relationship between a country’s exchange rate, its output, and interest rate in an open economy. Mundell (1963) states that the behavior of the exchange rate depends crucially on the economy and vice versa.
Intuitively, when money supply increases or equivalently interest rates decline, we expect a special transition process. On the one hand, a monetary expansion increases the output. Ceteris paribus, high GDP growth renders a country´s currency more attractive and leads to an appreciation. On the other hand, a monetary expansion causes capital outflows due to lower interest rates, as investments abroad become relatively more appealing. With a lower supply of foreign exchange, the home currency depreciates. This depreciation makes exports relatively cheap, which increases net exports, and, in turn, increases the total domestic output. This represents the impact of monetary policy under floating exchange rates while assuming perfect capital mobility.
The Mundell-Fleming approach, however, fails to explain the performance of major currencies. The model assumes the purchasing power parity (PPP), which proves to be wrong under certain circumstances, such as in the short term. The PPP assumption implies constant exchange rates when, to all intents and purposes, market participants experience rather high volatilities (Brissimis et al. 2005; Liang 1998; Rogoff 1995). The inconclusiveness led to the development of other models, such as the exchange rate overshooting model by Dornbusch (1976b).
This model is based on a slow adjustment of prices and consistent expectations. In the end, the model captures the phenomena of short term overshooting of exchange rates above their long-run equilibrium. Thus, the exchange rate volatility is partly attributed to market inefficiencies. Dornbusch (1976b) maintains that volatility is intrinsic to the market as the exchange rate responds to changes in monetary policy disproportionally to compensate for slow-adjusting prices. Hence, an expansionary monetary policy leads to lower interest rates and an exchange rate movement. In the short term, we expect an depreciation of the exchange rate. However, in the long-run, we expect a appreciation due to further stimulus or, in other words, the first-order effect overshoots only in the short-run. In Rogoff (2002) words, the “initial excess depreciation leaves room for the ensuing appreciation needed to simultaneously clear the bond and money markets”. Our intention when utilizing online search intensity, is to attain a better understanding of the role of expectations on the exchange rate dynamics as well as the interplay to both the goods and money market.
As with every theoretical approach, the overshooting model is not a complete picture of reality. Hooper and Morton (1982), Driskill (1981) and Buiter and Miller (1981), for instance, extended the model to overcome some of its restrictions, such as allowing for changes in the long-run real exchange rate, imperfect substitutability between domestic and foreign assets, and non-zero inflation. Moreover, contemporary theoretical research by Gray (1976) and Fischer (1977) study the idea of sticky-price open economy models in order to explain the exchange rate dynamics. Frankel (1979) developed a similar model and, as a consequence, the overshooting model is sometimes described as the Dornbusch-Frankel model. A difference between the two is that Frankel (1979) argues that exchange rates are driven by their real interest rate differentials and not their nominal. In our paper, we estimate an overshooting model and an augmented-overshooting model including search intensity.
The theoretical exchange rate models’ often display weak or inconclusive empirical performance. For instance, Meese and Rogoff (1983) compare in a seminal article the out-of-sample forecasting accuracy of various structural models. They find that all, including the overshooting model, perform rather poorly in comparison to the simple random walk model—termed naive forecast. Their results constitute what is known as the “disconnecting puzzle” in international finance. Indeed, their modeling exercises fail to establish a significant link between real exchange rates and economic fundamentals. A later study finds similar results when analyzing modern models under certain horizons for certain criteria (Cheung et al. 2005). The results from Meese and Rogoff (1983) demonstrate that market expectations of exchange rates are relevant, however, expectations are difficult to measure. The timely availability of search intensity, however, gives the measurement of expectations in this literature a new lease of life.
Molodtsova and Papell (2009) show that exchange rate models can beat a random walk in an out-of-sample forecasting exercise. Sarno and Schmeling (2014) document that fundamental exchange rate models have predictive power, but their performance relies heavily on the currency and forecast horizon. Kouwenberg et al. (2017) develop a model of selected fundamentals regardless it only works for 5 out of 10 currencies, implying that it does not beat a random walk. An approved notion is that fundamentals matter in the long-run but not in the short-run (Mark 1995; Mark and Sul 2001). Engel and West (2005) state that the expectations about future macroeconomic fundamentals drive exchange rates much more than lagged fundamentals do. Their findings relate to research of Andersen et al. (2003) that find strong evidence of exchange rates reacting to news. The results support the fact that exchange rates are conditioned by both macroeconomic fundamentals on the one hand and market expectations on the other.
The disparity in ideas surrounding empirical exchange rate research can be traced back to the limitation of the studies. Indeed, the context of foreign exchange markets is challenging, especially given their high interconnectedness in globalized and interconnected markets as well as the multidimensionality and stochastic nature of exchange rates. Understanding or predicting the behavior of exchange rates still represents a tall order up until today. The literature suggest that there are other—partly hidden— forces at work. Those forces are either not adequately considered or measured within the existing empirical models. On that extent, this paper aims to contribute to the literature by including a factor which thus far has been turned a blind eye to: The people´s attention measured through online-search intensity. We reveal that macroeconomic fundamentals and search intensity are significant drivers alike.

2.2. Literature on Search Data

There is strong evidence on the usefulness of online search data. Shim et al. (2001) find that consumer’s online search patterns predict their posterior purchases. Thus, information seeking behavior measures expectations and the potential demand of customers. Google data, as the world’s leading search engine, particularly provide search intensity data via the tool of Google Trends (Choi and Varian 2012). Since 2004, Google publishes search data on every keyword instantaneously. Several papers have demonstrated the usefulness of search data successfully. Firstly, there is a seminal study that accounts for the power of search data by predicting flu dynamics (Ginsberg et al. 2009). Since then, the number of publications using search data is flourishing (Jun et al. 2017).
Online search data has been proven to be useful in a whole raft of different fields. For instance Vaughan and Romero-Frias (2013) find a significant correlation between search volume of a university’s name and its academic reputation. Althouse et al. (2011) show that search queries predict dengue incidences, such as other influenza-like diseases (Ginsberg et al. 2009). In economics, Ettredge et al. (2005) examine U.S. unemployment trends and establish a significant correlation between job search data and unemployment. Da et al. (2011) propose a new method of capturing investor interest using search frequency, and Jun et al. (2017) demonstrate how Google Trends helps companies discover the perceptions consumers have about brands.
Yet, there is only one paper related to our work on the entwinement of search intensity and exchange rates. Bulut (2017) finds that Google Trends surpass structural models in predicting the direction of exchange rates. He concludes that the out-of-sample forecast of Google models offers better predictions for five currency pairs when compared to structural models. However, when compared to the random walk, neither Google models nor structural models perform to a similar extent. Our research differs from Bulut’s in several aspects. First, our data has more currencies and a longer time period. Hence, our panel is significantly larger and thus permits to draw a more complete picture. Second, we investigate the impact of a large sample of different search keywords and even integrate newly computed aggregate search intensity indices. Third, we utilize two well-established exchange rate models, such as the overshooting model and the augmented-overshooting model with and without search intensity. Fourth, our paper estimates the models and studies their prediction as well as the forecasting performances. Furthermore, and in contrast to Bulut (2017), our work does not rely on the PPP assumption and includes more elaborated search metrics. Last but not least, we study the exchange rate determination first and not merely the forecasting power.
Yet, research with search intensity is not free from limitations. Goel et al. (2010) claim, for instance, that there is little gain in prediction when the tool is used in forecasting. Vaughan and Chen (2015) are comparing Google Trends with the Baidu Index and find that Google data verges on futility if the number of people is relatively reduced in a certain territory. Lazer et al. (2014) raise questions about the nature of predictions and argue that web search is not reliable to replace traditional methods. While not all studies have significant results, Jun et al. (2017) stress that online search has advantages in terms of immediacy and objectivity. All in all, much of the quality of search data depends on the research question and methodology.

3. Data and Methodology

We utilize a strongly balanced panel to estimate different models over a quarterly time series which begins in 2004, the earliest year Google Trends data is available, and extends until 2018. The panel consists of the following ten countries: Australia, Canada, China, Germany, Japan, Mexico, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom (UK) and United States (US). The sample represents ten of the twenty most traded currencies in the world (BIS 2016). Germany represents the major economy for the Euro currency. Integrating all Eurozone countries would be more appropriate to better capture the Euro exchange, yet, we leave this task partially to future research.
For each country, we analyze the following macroeconomic variables: Real exchange rate (RRT); money supply (MM); gross domestic product (GDP); interest rate (IR); consumer price index (CPI); relative price of non-tradable goods (PNT); government debt-to-GDP (DBT); terms of trade (TOT) and net foreign assets (NFA). The debt-to-GDP and money supply data is from the OECD database (OECD 2018). All other variables are gathered from the International Monetary Fund financial statistics (IMF 2018). Because debt-to-GDP is only available annually, we conduct a cubic spline interpolation in order to disaggregate the observations into a higher frequency. As data availability differs across countries and time, some missing data points are present.1

3.1. Measuring Search Intensity

This paper includes online search intensity (SI), streamed from Google Trends. Search data is a proxy for measuring attention on exchange rates or related variables respectively. Google provides information on the search volume for any specific search term. The data represent the ratio of online searches made for a specific keyword in a given geographical region within a specific period to the total number of online searches made under the same specifications. The resulting time series of search intensity is scaled in the range of 0 to 100. Each search index number represents the relative popularity of a keyword (Google 2018). One of the difficulties of working with search data is selecting the appropriate set of keywords. Naccarato et al. (2018) state that a selection based on an objective and adequate method delivers useful results. Our keyword selection criteria are: (i) Keywords have to represent the major macroeconomic fundamentals of exchange rates; (ii) keywords coincide with search terms suggested by Google’s algorithm; and (iii) keywords are representative to similar studies in this literature.
Table 1 contains the list with all search keywords utilised in our study. These terms were selected using the aforementioned parameters and directly or indirectly affect the macroeconomic fundamentals and hence the exchange rate.
After gathering the search intensity variables, we obtain for each keyword, i, a time-series S I i , t over time t. One way to incorporate the search intensity to the model is by adding each single search term. This is labelled the sum of search intensity ( S I t Σ ) . A second way is to include aggregate search indices, for instance the mean of certain search terms ( S I t C A T ¯ ) . Among others, we include the mean of all inflation query data ( I N ¯ ) , the average of interest rate queries ( I R ¯ ) , and the mean of consumption queries ( C O N ¯ ) . Hence, we first obtain two trivial search intensity variables:
S I t Σ = S I t I N F + S I t G D P + S I t C P I + S I t I R + S I t L O A N + S I t A T M + S I t J O + S I V C + S I t S H O P + S I t E x R
S I t C A T ¯ = S I t I N F ¯ + S I t I R ¯ + S I t C O N ¯ ,
where the acronyms denote the following search keywords: Search intensity of inflation (SI-INF), search intensity of gross domestic product (SI-GDP), search intensity of consumer price index (SI-CPI), search intensity of interest rate (SI-IR), search intensity of loan (SI-LOAN), search intensity of automated teller machine (SI-ATM), search intensity of job opening (SI-JO), search intensity of vacation (SI-VC), search intensity of shopping (SI-SHOP), and search intensity of exchange rate (SI-ExR). Both aggregate measures are based on disaggregated search queries over time.
Nonetheless, we design four more sophisticated online search intensity indices. First, we follow Chen et al. (2001) and define an abnormal average change in S I i , t , computed by
A C S I i , t = S I i , t A V S I i | t 4 , t 1 S D A V S I i | t 4 , t 1 ,
where A V S I i | t 4 , t 1 and S D A V S I i | t 4 , t 1 are the mean and standard deviation of SI for series i over the past 4 quarters, respectively. An ACSI search index, that measures the relative search to the average of the past 4-quarters, signifies an abnormally high (low) attention on the respective search expression.
Second, we follow the seminal paper by Da et al. (2011) and define:
L A S I i , t = log ( S I i , t ) log ( M e d i a n ( S I i | t 4 , t ) ) .
In short, L A S I i , t measures the logarithmic value of search intensity (SI) of a search expression i minus the logarithmic value of the median of search intensity during the previous quarter.
Third, we follow a related idea in the seminal work by Baker et al. (2016). We compute an aggregate search intensity index (SII) that is standardized and normalized in a range of 0 to 100. In the first step, we divide the S I i , t by the time-series standard deviation σ i for all search terms for all t. This creates a new time-series labeled S S i , t . Secondly, we compute for each search term and time the normalized time-series according to
N S S i , t = ( S S i , t min S S i , t ) × 100 ( max S S i , t min S S i , t ) .
Next, we compute the mean over all N S S i , t in each quarter in order to obtain the aggregate search intensity index S I I t .
Fourth, we compute our own aggregate search index labelled average standardized search intensity ( A S S I i , t ) . In a first step, we compute the quarterly means, defined as S S ¯ i , t , of the standardized search ( S S i , t ) . Second, we compute the difference of the search volume variables divided by the standard deviation—with the formula: A S S I i , t = ( S I i , t S S ¯ i , t ) / σ i .
We utilize the following six search indices S I n d e x i , t M 1 M 6 in our econometric models: (M1) S I t Σ , (M2) S I t C A T ¯ , (M3) A C S I i , t , (M4) L A S I i , t , (M5) S I I t , and (M6) A S S I i , t . All search indices are based on search data and represent an attention measure for the macroeconomic drivers of the exchange rate. We include these indices as control variables in our two macroeconomic exchange rate models. Thus, we regress the exchange rate in a panel set, consisting of countries i over time t in respect to two different models ( M o d e l i , t t y p e ) and the set of six search indices ( S I n d e x i , t M 1 M 6 ). The model is specified as follows
E x c h a n g R a t e i , t = α i , t + β 1 M o d e l i , t t y p e + β 2 S I n d e x i , t M 1 M 6 + ϵ i , t ,
where we assume i.i.d. for the error term ϵ i , t . All abbreviations and variables names are listed at the end of the paper.

3.2. Econometric Methodology

Next, we describe the two types of exchange rate models in more detail. The macroeconomic fundamentals of the overshooting model are the price level, output, money supply, and interest rate (Dornbusch 1976b). Our regression of the overshooting model is similar to Cheung et al. (2005), where the variables are as previously described. The term ϵ t is the standard error and is normally distributed N ( 0 , σ ϵ 2 ) .
The ’Overshooting Model’ (OM) captures the overshooting channel via I R i , t and assumes that PPP holds merely in the long run. Our econometric equation follows this idea but incorporates the exchange rate equilibrium relationship as described by Clark and MacDonald (1998) or in work by Ewards (1989):
M o d e l i , t O M : = η M M M i , t + η G G D P i , t + η I I R i , t + η C C P I i , t ,
The second econometric model is an augmented-overshooting model. We define the regression equation of the ‘Augmented Model’ (AM) as follows
M o d e l i , t A M : = M o d e l i , t O M + β P N T i , t + γ D B T i , t + ρ T O T i , t + ζ N F A i , t .
Equation (8) incorporates the Balassa-Samuelson effect via P N T t and the portfolio balance effect via D B T t and N F A t .2
Whether a country’s currency appreciates or depreciates depends ultimately on the perceived desirability of holding that currency. Therefore, one can conceive the variables in Equations (7) and (8) as the major macroeconomic exchange rate determinants. If a nation’s inflation or debt levels are considerably high, the desirability for that currency will be low, or, in other words, there is a tendency of a weak currency. The relative price of non-tradable goods, the terms of trade, and net foreign assets reflect the country’s productivity, economic health, and demand for the country’s goods and services. All of this influences the country’s currency demand. Everything else constant, the better the productivity and economic situation, the higher the desirability for holding the currency.
As a measure of market expectations, we include search intensity as described previously. The idea that web search represents collective attention is established by recent research, among others by Ettredge et al. (2005), Ginsberg et al. (2009) and Da et al. (2011).
Ultimately, we describe the fourteen variants of our econometric regression models. Firstly, we distinguish between the two benchmark models, consisting of the ‘Overshooting Model’ (OM) in Equation (7) and the ‘Augmented Model’ (AM) in Equation (8). In order to simplify the terminology, we re-label X i , t j : = M o d e l i , t j , where j denotes either the OM- or AM-model. Both benchmark models capture the pure macroeconomic fundamentals, as denoted in Equation (9). Secondly, we estimate an extended model and include our six search indices. Equation () denotes the models with search intensity metrics (M1) S I t Σ , (M2) S I t C A T ¯ , (M3) A C S I i , t , (M4) L A S I i , t , (M5) S I I t , and (M6) A S S I i , t . Thus, we obtain two regression equations based on either the pure macroeconomic models or the extended models by six search indices,
E x R i , t X i , t j = α + β 1 X i , t j + ϵ i , t
E x R i , t X i , t j , M 1 M 6 = α + β 1 X i , t j + β 2 S I n d e x i , t M 1 M 6 + ϵ i , t ,
where E x R i , t denotes the respective exchange rate, X i , t j denotes the macroeconomic O M —or A M —model, and S I n d e x represents the six search indices for each country i over time t. We test the hypothesis whether search intensity enhances the models.

3.3. Prediction and Forecasting Methodology

A rigorous evaluation of the prediction and forecasting performance of our model reveals a final insight about the use and quality of online search data. First, we evaluate the prediction of our two best models with search data in comparison to the economic benchmark models. We run the prediction by utilizing the estimated coefficients from above and compute the confidence intervals of 95%. In the end, we compare the real exchange rate with the performance of the model prediction:
E x R p r e X i , t j = α ^ + β 1 ^ X i , t j + ϵ i , t
E x R p r e X i , t j , M 1 , M 6 = α ^ + β 1 ^ X i , t j + β 2 ^ S I n d e x i , t M 1 , M 6 + ϵ i , t
where X i , t j is always the A M -model because it is outperforming the narrow OM-model.
Second, we compute an in-sample forecast of the exchange rate over four quarters. In the forecasting exercise, we compare the forecasting of our benchmark model and the models with search intensity as well as a specified ARIMA-Model and the naive forecast of a random walk. According to standard lag-tests, we use an ARIMA(2,0,1) model. The forecasting equations are:
E x R i , t + 1 X j = α ^ + β 1 ^ X i , t j + ϵ i , t , Basic forecast E x R i , t + 1 X j , M 1 , M 6 = α ^ + β 1 ^ X i , t j + β 2 ^ S I n d e x i , t M 1 , M 6 + ϵ i , t , SI forecast E x R i , t + 1 X j = ρ E x R t X j + ρ 2 E x R a t e t 1 X j + ϵ i , t + ν ϵ i , t 1 , ARIMA forecast E x R i , t + 1 X j = E x R a t e i , t X j , Naive forecast .
In order to evaluate the forecasting performance, we compute the square errors of each forecast Π i , t = [ E x R i , t f o r e c a s t E x R i , t ] 2 and the sum of square errors Π i = t [ E x R i , t f o r e c a s t E x R i , t ] 2 . We evaluate the forecasting performance by testing the null-hypothesis of Π i , t and Π i to be zero. A rejection of the null-hypothesis in regard to a zero mean-square error identifies the models with insufficient forecasting performance.

3.4. Panel Regression Pre-Testing

Our econometric approach utilizes a large panel such as those applied in the empirical exchange rate literature by Sarno and Schmeling (2014) or Mark and Sul (2001). Nevertheless, before estimating our fourteen models, we apply several pre-tests for multi-collinearity, heteroscedasticity, autocorrelation, omitted variables, and stationarity.3
First, by looking to the time-series properties, we note the problem of non-stationarity for some of our variables. Stationarity means that the probability distributions of the variables are stable over time and have no unit roots. To verify stationarity, we conduct the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test, the Fischer-type test and the Im-Pesaran-Shin test (Choi 2001; Im et al. 2003).4 Indeed, three of our macroeconomic variables display some non-stationarity: Money supply, debt-to-GDP and net foreign assets. In order to correct for non-stationarity, we compute the log-difference.5 The process of de-trending yields stationary variables in the end.
Multicollinearity arises when predictor variables are correlated. We use the rule of thumb that correlation should not have a variance inflation factor (VIF) above a value of 8 (Chatterjee and Hadi 1986). We observe a mild multicollinearity between the two variables net foreign assets and money supply. This problem is tackled by excluding the variable N F A , which has the highest VIF, being of approximately 8. After this adjustment the models are free of multicollinearity (Appendix A Table A2).
In order to test for heteroscedasticity, we apply the Breusch-Pagan test (Breusch and Pagan 1979, 1980; Cook and Weisberg 1983) as well as the modified Wald test. None of the tests can reject heteroscedasticity in our panel (Appendix A Table A3 and Table A4; Appendix B). Similarly, we use the Wooldridge test in order to check for autocorrelation (Drukker 2003). We cannot reject autocorrelation either (Appendix A Table A5). For both issues we apply the standard techniques including robust estimation with panel-corrected standard errors and autoregressive terms.6 Finally, the Ramsey REST test does reject omitted variables in our models (Appendix A Table A6).
Last but not least, when deciding between the different panel regression techniques, we utilize the Breusch-Pagan test and the Hausman-Test. The Hausman test specifies whether a fixed effects (FE) or random effects (RE) model is appropriate. The FE model allows for variances in the intercept parameter, while the RE model is a special case where the heterogeneity across countries is treated as random. The Breusch-Pagan test compares the pooled OLS regression with a random effects model. In virtually all cases the fixed effects model is selected, except in one case in which it is rejected (Appendix A Table A7 and Table A8). Consequently, the appropriate choice for our panel data is the fixed effects model. As in the exchange rate literature, we presume that the variables reject endogeneity. A lack of instrumental variables hinders the formal process of controlling for endogeneity.

4. Results

In a first step, we estimate the OM-model and AM-model with different panel estimation techniques.7 It follows from the Hausman test that the fixed-effects model delivers consistent estimates for the OM-model. For the AM-model we utilize the random-effects.
While the sign of the coefficients follow our expectations, their p-values and respectively significance denote the impact of the variables on the exchange rate (Table 2). At first glance, we can observe that the interest rate, I R i , t , is robustly positive and significant across all models. This highlights the robust importance of the interest rate channel to the exchange rate dynamics. Similarly, the consumer price index (CPI) is negative, however, not robust in all models. Likewise, we find highly robust and significant coefficients across all models for the relative price of non-tradable goods and terms-of-trade. In general, this confirms the importance of the macroeconomic variables in determining the exchange rate as proposed by Dornbusch (1976b).
Moreover, the augmented model confirms the famous Balassa-Samuelson effect. Indeed, the relative price of non-tradable goods impacts the real exchange rate through changes in real costs (Balassa 1964; Samuelson 1964).8 Finally, GDP growth is not significant but the debt-to-GDP ratio is significant at 1 percent similarly to Cheung et al. (2005). A potential reason for the insignificance of GDP growth is its aggregate nature.
Having selected the consistent panel estimator, we estimate all model variants, including the search intensity indices. For all models, the regression output reveals that search intensity model 1 and model 6 deliver the best results (Table 3 and Appendix C Table A14).9 Note, search intensity model 1 includes all search intensity data for each keyword. Under search intensity model 6, we include our metric of the average standardized search intensity index, A S S I i , t . Both models outperform the benchmark macroeconomic OM- or AM-model respectively. Noteworthy, both search intensity models 1 and 6 have the highest R-square10 and highly significant F-statistics.
The regression results of the pure exchange rate models with the macroeconomics variables only are reported in Table 4 and Table 5. Both Tables illustrate the well-known results from the exchange rate literature. All coefficients and effects of the pure macroeconomics exchange rate variables are as expected. Consequently, the exchange rate models are sufficiently well-specified.
In a second step, we compare the estimates of the OM- and AM-model with search intensity model 6, meaning the search metric A S S I i , t (Table A13, Table A14 and Table A15).11 This confirms that search intensity enhances the estimation performance such as robustness and significance of our models. Interestingly some of the A S S I i , t indices are highly significant, particularly the keyword ‘exchange rate’. Therefore, a higher search intensity for the respective currency, which represents the online attention about the currency, significantly affects the market exchange rate. This finding is highly robust across all models.
Indeed, the predictive power of search intensity S I t Σ and A S S I i , t is impressive. Interestingly, our aggregate search intensity indices, such as S I t C A T ¯ , are mostly insignificant. This could be due to the information loss during the aggregation process. The remaining three online search indices A C S I i , t , L A S I i , t and S I I t are rather insignificant too. This underscores that the specific choice of keywords and the design of the search intensity index have a major impact on the final outcome.
In this paper, we follow the online search literature by defining the most appropriate keywords in order to have comparable results (Bank et al. 2011; Takeda and Wakao 2013; Vlastakis and Markellos 2012). Nonetheless, a more systematic method or theory of selecting relevant keywords is an open research question. Vaughan and Chen (2015) finds that search indices have different predictive power in different countries.
Therefore, we estimate country specific regressions of the overshooting model and augmented-overshooting model for each country. Results are in the Appendix C in Table A19, which summarize the estimation results for the benchmark model. Similarly, Table A20 and Table A23 illustrate search intensity model 1 with all disaggregated search intensity variables. In Table A21 and Table A24 we report search intensity model 6 with our A S S I i , t search variables. The results show that the interest rate is at least significant at 1 percent in eight of ten countries, the relative price and terms of trade in six of ten countries, the debt-to-GDP ratio in five of ten countries, and the money supply, GDP and net foreign assets in three of ten countries. Noteworthy, the direction of those significant macroeconomic fundamentals vary from currency to currency (Table A19 and Table A22). The results confirm the previous findings of the macroeconomic variables. In the OM-model search intensity variables are significant particularly for the keyword ‘exchange rate’ (Table A20). In the AM-model, however, search intensity is significant only for the keyword exchange rate in three out of nine countries (Table A23). Even though the search intensity model 6 has a similar pattern, our search intensity variables have a higher significance across most countries.
Indeed, the overshooting model delivers mixed results, however, the augmented-overshooting model has significant results for all countries with an R-square in the range of [ 0.53 ; 0.89 ] . Notably, search intensity variables are particularly significant in the US (Table A20 and Table A21). The results for the other countries are rather mixed, yet having Germany, Japan, Mexico and the UK with high significance. This can be explained by Vaughan and Chen (2015) because online search data is better in countries where the market share of Google’s search engine is high, particularly in Western democracies and English speaking countries.
The AM-model including search intensity variables stand out in regard of the adjusted R-square in a range of [ 0.77 ; 0.91 ] and highly significant F-statistics (Appendix C Table A23 and Table A24). All findings corroborate that online search intensity covers market expectations in a similar way than news does as explored by Andersen et al. (2003), however, the results vary significantly across countries.
At a first stage, we conclude that search intensity improves the estimation results and the overall fit of the models. Yet, we have findings indicating that some search variables offer minor explanatory value. In our view, further research could address this issue through a more systematic method to gather the relevant keywords.

4.1. Performance of Model Prediction and Forecasting

In a next step, we evaluate the prediction performance of search intensity model 1 and model 6 in comparison to the benchmark macroeconomic OM- and AM-models. Juxtaposing the prediction of the exchange rates, we find evidence that the predictive power is raised significantly in models including search intensity. The exchange rate prediction for each country is almost always inside the 95% confidence intervals. On the contrary, the benchmark OM- and AM-models devoid of search intensity perform significantly inferior. A detailed evaluation of the prediction error is represented in Table 6. The smaller prediction errors in models 1 and 6 with the search intensity variables confirm the usefulness of search data under a prediction exercise.
Surprising, however, is the forecasting performance. Table 7 and particularly Table 8 corroborate that models with search intensity outperform those lacking it. The hypothesis that the forecasting error is of zero cannot be rejected for most of the models with search intensity data. On the contrary, the forecasting error of the macroeconomic benchmark model or ARIMA model is significantly different to zero (Table 8). Nonetheless, the naive forecast is tantamount to that of our two top models 1 and 6. Not surprisingly, the confidence intervals under forecasting are rather wide in contrast to the naive forecast. However, looking to the forecasting direction, we interestingly find that our models do predict the direction better than the naive forecast (Table 8).
Finally, we apply a forecasting exercise by using a vector error correction (VEC) model (Figure 1 and Figure 2). The VEC models broadly corroborate the prediction and forecasting performance from the previous exercises. The models including search intensity are almost always significant, while the pure macroeconomic models pale into insignificance. Note, we only illustrate the forecasting- and VEC-model for the US due to high Google search intensity and longer timeseries data in the US (Figure 1 and Figure 2).12 All in all, we find first evidence that search intensity might enhances the prediction and forecasting of exchange rate models.

4.2. Limitations

Panel data are a prefect tool for studying exchange rate dynamics across countries and time. Nevertheless, one obstacle is missing data points in large panel sets. However, we minimize this issue by using quarterly data over fourteen years and 10 countries. In this study, we have further limitations due to the availability of the search intensity data. Google provides data from the year of 2004 onwards. Thus, our sample starts in 2004 and runs until 2018. Moreover, there is an unsolved limitation of possible structural breaks during the time period of 14 years and across various countries. This issue is up to future research. In the near future, as the time range of online data enlarges and as the timing of structural breaks is feasible, we plan to enhance the research by practical applications.
Last but not least, when working with online search data, the choice of keywords is critical (Naccarato et al. 2018). Different search terms deliver partly different outputs. So far, there is no universal method of selecting keywords. Yet, even search data has internal flaws. Google Trends is using sampling methods, which might affect the data by a few percentage points from day to day according to Choi and Varian (2012). This creates replication problems if data is downloaded at different times.

5. Conclusions

In today’s post-coronavirus economy, the challenges of the globalized supply chains and the respective exchange rate dynamics has come to the foreground. Much like the sunlight to flowers to grow, the exchange rates is key to international trade, economic and political stability in an interconnected and globalized world. Modeling exchange rates, however, is a rather tedious and sophisticated task due to complex non-linear dynamics. Most of the time, the literature argues that the naive forecast is the best prediction of exchange rates in the short-run. Yet, we show that exchange rate models augmented by online search intensity metrics enhance the estimation as well as the prediction and forecasting performance of standard macroeconomic models. In some instances, our generalized exchange rate models even beat the gold-standard of the naive forecast.
Our paper reveals the following results: Some single-word online search queries appear to be of high relevance. Particularly the keywords ‘interest rate’ and ‘exchange rate’ are robust and significant across almost all models. Indeed, we find that four out of ten search variables are robustly significant at one percent and enhance the macroeconomic exchange rate models. Furthermore, one of our newly created search metrics are beneficial, particularly our A S S I -metric. Moreover, we demonstrate that the country regressions corroborate the panel results, yet the predictive power of search intensity in regard to exchange rates vary by country. Finally, we find higher prediction performance for our exchange rate models with search intensity, particularly in regard to the direction of the exchange rate forecast.
Overall, our approach reveals a value-added of search intensity in exchange rate models. The practicality and benefits of online search cannot be understated. As the field develops and some of its limitations are overcome, big data analytics will enhance present exchange rate models. A more thorough keyword selection process might pave the way for a more systematic evaluation in future. In the end, we might obtain a better understanding of the complex non-linear currency dynamics in the global economy.

Author Contributions

B.H. and L.d.S. equally contributed to this research article. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

We are grateful that the publication fee was financed by Albert-Ludwigs-Universität Freiburg, Universitätsbibliothek, Geschäftsstelle des Konsortiums Baden-Württemberg. We have not received further external funding for the research project.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Data is available from authors upon request.

Acknowledgments

We are very grateful to our research assistant Adrian Elsässer Briones who has been editing a preliminary paper version.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Abbreviations

Abbreviations and Variables used in this manuscript:
RRTReal exchange rate
NRTNominal exchange rate
MMMoney Supply
dmmLog-difference of MM
GDPGross Domestic Product
IRInterest rate
CPIConsumer Price Index
PNTRelative price of non-tradable goods
DBTDebt-to-GDP ratio
ddbtLog-difference of DBT
TOTTerms of Trade
NFANet foreign assets
dnfaLog-difference of NFA
SISearch Intensity
SI-INFSearch Intensity of Inflation
SI-GDPSearch Intensity of GDP
SI-CPISearch Intensity of CPI
SI-IRSearch Intensity of Interest Rate
SI-LOANSearch Intensity of Loan
SI-ATMSearch Intensity of ATM
SI-JOSearch Intensity of Job Opening
SI-VCSearch Intensity of Vacation
SI-SHOPSearch Intensity of Shopping
SI-ExRSearch Intensity of Exchange Rate
S S i , t Standardized search defined by S I i , t divided by σ i
S S ¯ i , t Quarterly means of S S i , t
S I t Σ Aggregate sum of all search intensities
S I t C A T ¯ Mean of each search category
A C S I i , t Abnormal average change in search intensity
L A S I i , t Logarithmic difference of S I i , t
S I I i , t Aggregate normalized mean value of search intenstiy
A S S I i , t Difference of S I i , t and S S ¯ i , t

Appendix A

Table A1. Summary statistics.
Table A1. Summary statistics.
VariableMean(Std. Dev.)Min.Max.N
NRT100.195(11.807)66.326130.573560
RRT99.743(11.146)69.283132.054560
MM107.72(35.901)33.641249.786560
dmm1.84(1.53)−1.5018.519550
GDP0.537(0.845)−5.222.704532
IR1.935(2.312)−210.05543
CPI1.005(0.007)0.9721.036560
PNT1.012(0.037)0.9081.177560
DBT0.852(0.511)0.1852.388460
ddbt0.001(0.018)−0.2840.033451
ToT1.009(0.131)0.6161.498474
NFA99.856(8.793)71.986134.897560
dnfa0.456(1.368)−12.2376.618550
SI-INF47.754(18.979)692.333560
SI-GDP50.965(14.454)1793.667560
SI-CPI45.892(18.973)696.333560
SI-IR48.085(15.188)589560
SI-LOAN48.132(22.33)597560
SI-ATM44.246(24.275)199.333560
SI-JO44.92(20.134)096.333560
SI-SHOP58.042(16.645)296.667560
SI-ExR29.958(22.78)097.333560
Table A2. Test of Multi-collinearity (VIF Values).
Table A2. Test of Multi-collinearity (VIF Values).
VariablePooled OLSPooled OLSPooled OLSPooled OLS
OM Model 1AM Model 1OM Model 2AM Model 2
IR1.342.341.211.36
CPI1.211.211.201.70
MM1.160.79
Log(Money) 1.121.15
GDP1.041.041.081.09
DBT 1.87
Log(Debt) 1.11
ToT 1.27 1.05
RNT 1.101.13
Mean VIF1.181.441.151.29
Table A3. Breusch-Pagan (LM) test for heteroscedasticity.
Table A3. Breusch-Pagan (LM) test for heteroscedasticity.
Variablechi2-Valuep-Value
Pooled OLS OM Model 128.130.00
Fixed-Effect OM Model 1553.270.00
Pooled OLS OM Model 27.960.00
Pooled OLS AM Model 13.410.06
Fixed-Effect AM Model 1219.810.00
Pooled OLS AM Model 28.030.00
Table A4. Modified Wald Test for group (panel) heteroscedasticity.
Table A4. Modified Wald Test for group (panel) heteroscedasticity.
Variablechi2-Valuep-Value
Fixed-Effect OM Model 1230.580.00
Fixed-Effect AM Model 1214.660.00
Table A5. Wooldridge test for autocorrelation in panel data.
Table A5. Wooldridge test for autocorrelation in panel data.
VariableF-Statisticp-Value
Fixed-Effect OM Model 1239.080.00
Fixed-Effect AM Model 1186.570.00
Table A6. Ramsey REST test for omitted variables in panel data.
Table A6. Ramsey REST test for omitted variables in panel data.
VariableF-Statisticp-Value
Pooled OLS OM Model 11.430.23
Pooled OLS OM Model 25.130.00
Pooled OLS AM Model 12.380.07
Pooled OLS AM Model 23.760.01
Table A7. Breusch-Pagan LM test for random effects.
Table A7. Breusch-Pagan LM test for random effects.
Variablechi2-Statisticp-Value
OM Model 11451.870.00
OM Model 21371.340.00
AM Model 11707.500.00
AM Model 20.001.00
Table A8. Hausman test for panel data.
Table A8. Hausman test for panel data.
Variablechi2-Statisticp-Value
OM Model 129.090.00
OM Model 2289.520.00
AM Model 1−596.811.00
AM Model 251.390.00

Appendix B. Figures about Country- and Time-Effects

Figure A1. Scatter Plot for Country Effects.
Figure A1. Scatter Plot for Country Effects.
Jrfm 14 00512 g0a1
Figure A2. Scatter Plot for Time Effects.
Figure A2. Scatter Plot for Time Effects.
Jrfm 14 00512 g0a2
Figure A3. US—Exchange Rate Prediction.
Figure A3. US—Exchange Rate Prediction.
Jrfm 14 00512 g0a3

Appendix C

Table A9. Panel Regression OM-Fixed-Effects and AM-Random-Effects Models 1.
Table A9. Panel Regression OM-Fixed-Effects and AM-Random-Effects Models 1.
OM-ModelOM-FE ModelAM-ModelAM-RE Model
MM0.02410.162 ***0.0484 **0.175 ***
(0.0152)(0.0233)(0.0172)(0.0280)
GDP0.5451.161 *−0.1460.173
(0.467)(0.522)(0.445)(0.462)
IR1.478 ***0.3201.907 ***1.445 ***
(0.299)(0.254)(0.280)(0.296)
CPI−214.1 ***−169.0 *−51.38−90.08
(62.70)(70.25)(63.37)(64.92)
SI-INF 2.603 *** 2.618 ***
(0.658) (0.659)
SI-GDP 2.704 *** 1.874 **
(0.597) (0.618)
SI-CPI −1.161 −0.397
(0.685) (0.618)
SI-IR −2.058 *** −0.743
(0.575) (0.521)
SI-LOAN −3.525 *** 0.750
(0.661) (0.716)
SI-ATM −0.178 1.108
(0.538) (0.657)
SI-JO −1.231 * −1.990 ***
(0.554) (0.579)
SI-VC −0.967 * −0.210
(0.487) (0.476)
SI-SHOP 2.071 ** 0.212
(0.656) (0.701)
SI-ExR −3.985 *** −6.330 ***
(0.734) (0.835)
PNT 99.67 ***158.2 ***
(13.14)(16.03)
DBT 0.7163.632 *
(1.250)(1.513)
ToT 25.72 ***10.93 **
(3.545)(3.711)
Constant310.4 ***256.3 ***15.36−5.667
(62.91)(70.32)(66.40)(67.82)
Observations515515447447
Standard errors in parentheses, FE = Fixed-Effects, RE = Random-Effects. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A10. Panel Regression OM-Fixed-Effects and AM-Fixed-Effects Models 2.
Table A10. Panel Regression OM-Fixed-Effects and AM-Fixed-Effects Models 2.
OM-ModelOM-FE ModelAM-ModelAM-FE Model
Log(MM)0.4650.724 *0.722 *0.766 **
(0.331)(0.331)(0.291)(0.296)
GDP0.3170.02500.0291−0.247
(0.463)(0.448)(0.387)(0.373)
IR1.303 ***1.288 ***1.573 ***1.560 ***
(0.245)(0.321)(0.214)(0.281)
CPI−221.4 ***−161.5 **−114.9−92.27
(62.23)(59.56)(64.56)(61.05)
SI-INF −1.414 −0.659
(0.823) (0.737)
SI-GDP 2.644 *** 1.364 *
(0.567) (0.541)
SI-CPI −4.106 *** −4.661 ***
(0.810) (0.690)
SI-IR −0.681 −0.0611
(0.605) (0.551)
SI-LOAN −0.609 0.821
(0.715) (0.826)
SI-ATM 2.099 * 0.0191
(0.933) (0.903)
SI-JO −1.510 ** −1.158 *
(0.551) (0.503)
asgvc 0.198 −0.143
(0.504) (0.455)
SI-SHOP 1.225 * 0.289
(0.528) (0.569)
SI-ExR −3.072 *** −3.102 ***
(0.639) (0.649)
PNT 83.83 ***115.6 ***
(13.61)(16.01)
Log(Debt) 51.53 **62.29 ***
(18.96)(18.19)
ToT 36.93 ***30.16 ***
(3.989)(4.069)
Log(NFA) 0.2120.479
(0.299)(0.290)
Constant319.1 ***265.3 ***88.7354.30
(62.41)(59.77)(66.21)(62.60)
Observations506506438438
Adjusted R 2 0.0450.1750.3140.406
Standard errors in parentheses, FE = Fixed-Effects. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A11. Panel Regression Table OM Model 1.
Table A11. Panel Regression Table OM Model 1.
Model OLSModel PAModel FEModel REModel ML
MM0.0374 *0.02340.02190.02410.0230
(0.0149)(0.0158)(0.0155)(0.0152)(0.0152)
GDP1.700 **0.5070.4240.5450.483
(0.569)(0.481)(0.465)(0.467)(0.463)
IR0.479 *1.504 ***1.562 ***1.478 ***1.521 ***
(0.237)(0.311)(0.308)(0.299)(0.301)
CPI−101.3−215.8 ***−219.3 ***−214.1 ***−216.8 ***
(79.89)(64.44)(62.08)(62.70)(61.81)
Constant196.2 *312.2 ***315.0 ***310.4 ***313.3 ***
(79.89)(64.68)(62.29)(62.91)(62.06)
sigma(u)
Constant 8.224 ***
(1.899)
sigma(e)
Constant 8.220 ***
(0.259)
Observations515515515515515
Adjusted R 2 0.028 0.044
F4.640 9.163
Standard errors in parentheses, FE = Fixed-Effects, RE = Random-Effects, PA = Pooled, ML = Maximum-Likelihood. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A12. Panel Regression Table AM Model 2.
Table A12. Panel Regression Table AM Model 2.
Model OLSModel PAModel FEModel REModel ML
dmm0.3230.716 *0.722 *0.3230.716 *
(0.336)(0.290)(0.291)(0.336)(0.286)
GDP−0.4390.01670.0291−0.4390.0178
(0.499)(0.388)(0.387)(0.499)(0.383)
IR1.142 ***1.568 ***1.573 ***1.142 ***1.568 ***
(0.207)(0.211)(0.214)(0.207)(0.208)
CPI−15.66−112.8−114.9−15.66−112.9
(82.58)(64.73)(64.56)(82.58)(63.90)
PNT127.9 ***86.04 ***83.83 ***127.9 ***85.85 ***
(14.04)(13.53)(13.61)(14.04)(13.40)
ddbt98.26 ***53.44 **51.53 **98.26 ***53.28 **
(24.07)(19.01)(18.96)(24.07)(18.78)
ToT19.80 ***35.55 ***36.93 ***19.80 ***35.67 ***
(3.191)(3.900)(3.989)(3.191)(3.901)
dnfa0.3960.2180.2120.3960.218
(0.387)(0.300)(0.299)(0.387)(0.296)
Constant−36.3485.4088.73−36.3485.66
(83.78)(66.38)(66.21)(83.78)(65.54)
sigma(u)
Constant 6.217 ***
(1.520)
sigma(e)
Constant 6.478 ***
(0.221)
Observations438438438438438
Adjusted R 2 0.261 0.314
F20.31 27.01
Standard errors in parentheses, FE = Fixed-Effects, RE = Random-Effects, PA = Pooled, ML = Maximum-Likelihood. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A13. Panel Regression Table Fixed-Effects OM Models 1.
Table A13. Panel Regression Table Fixed-Effects OM Models 1.
Model 1Model 2Model 3Model 4Model 5Model 6Model 7
MM0.02190.0913 ***0.02850.02180.03000.02320.0906 ***
(0.0155)(0.0240)(0.0204)(0.0161)(0.0169)(0.0156)(0.0241)
GDP0.4240.3290.4370.2290.1920.3820.320
(0.465)(0.448)(0.475)(0.477)(0.481)(0.467)(0.449)
IR1.562 ***1.669 ***1.565 ***1.522 ***1.529 ***1.519 ***1.655 ***
(0.308)(0.327)(0.313)(0.313)(0.316)(0.311)(0.329)
CPI−219.3 ***−170.1 **−222.5 ***−225.6 ***−228.2 ***−219.3 ***−170.3 **
(62.08)(59.15)(62.53)(62.64)(64.15)(62.08)(59.21)
SI-INF −0.0533
(0.0427)
SI-GDP 0.174 ***
(0.0384)
SI-CPI −0.166 ***
(0.0412)
SI-IR −0.0392
(0.0391)
SI-LOAN −0.0729 *
(0.0351)
SI-ATM 0.0624
(0.0366)
SI-JO −0.0584 *
(0.0259)
SI-SHOP 0.128 ***
(0.0342)
SI-ExR −0.162 ***
(0.0292)
S I I N F ¯ 0.0226
(0.0500)
S I I R ¯ −0.0186
(0.0565)
S I C O N ¯ 0.0128
(0.0568)
ACSI-INF −0.108
(0.142)
ACSI-GDP 0.0385
(0.238)
ACSI-CPI 0.0571
(0.236)
ACSI-IR −0.182
(0.200)
ACSI-LOAN −0.230
(0.142)
acgat 0.0588
(0.177)
ACSI-JO 0.222
(0.158)
ACSI-VC 0.0814
(0.139)
ACSI-SHOP −0.0387
(0.144)
ACSI-ExR −0.183
(0.141)
LASI-INF −1.627
(4.321)
LASI-GDP −0.522
(5.630)
LASI-CPI 1.040
(4.544)
lagir −3.059
(4.996)
LASI-LOAN −3.668
(4.022)
LASI-ATM −2.021
(3.298)
LASI-JO 10.27 *
(4.094)
LASI-VC −1.640
(4.056)
LASI-SHOP −4.963
(4.594)
LASI-ExR −3.809
(2.653)
SII −0.0688
(0.0695)
ASSI-INF −1.005
(0.812)
ASSI-GDP 2.494 ***
(0.557)
ASSI-CPI −3.182 ***
(0.789)
ASSI-IR −0.598
(0.594)
ASSI-LOAN −1.649 *
(0.788)
ASSI-ATM 1.481
(0.895)
ASSI-JO −1.150 *
(0.526)
ASSI-VC 0.174
(0.486)
ASSI-SHOP 2.119 ***
(0.571)
ASSI-ExR −3.698 ***
(0.665)
Constant315.0 ***262.0 ***316.6 ***321.9 ***323.5 ***318.2 ***262.0 ***
(62.29)(59.25)(62.67)(62.86)(64.45)(62.37)(59.31)
Observations515515515509501515515
Adjusted R 2 0.0440.1790.0390.0470.0440.0440.178
F9.16310.315.2503.4483.2717.5269.567
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A14. Panel Regression Table Fixed-Effects AM Models 2.
Table A14. Panel Regression Table Fixed-Effects AM Models 2.
Model 1Model 2Model 3Model 4Model 5Model 6Model 7
dmm0.722 *0.762 *0.4760.803 **0.815 **0.752 **0.766 **
(0.291)(0.295)(0.302)(0.297)(0.313)(0.289)(0.296)
GDP0.0291−0.245−0.0960−0.113−0.162−0.131−0.247
(0.387)(0.373)(0.392)(0.404)(0.409)(0.391)(0.373)
IR1.573 ***1.554 ***1.836 ***1.494 ***1.533 ***1.515 ***1.560 ***
(0.214)(0.280)(0.233)(0.229)(0.243)(0.214)(0.281)
CPI−114.9−90.67−119.0−152.1 *−141.9 *−120.1−92.27
(64.56)(60.77)(64.24)(66.06)(68.06)(64.25)(61.05)
PNT83.83 ***114.9 ***98.81 ***79.73 ***82.46 ***96.13 ***115.6 ***
(13.61)(15.84)(15.19)(14.38)(15.00)(14.51)(16.01)
ddbt51.53 **61.48 ***55.12 **52.77 **52.27 **50.25 **62.29 ***
(18.96)(17.99)(18.94)(19.16)(19.57)(18.86)(18.19)
ToT36.93 ***30.13 ***37.15 ***35.02 ***36.05 ***35.99 ***30.16 ***
(3.989)(4.063)(3.959)(4.179)(4.327)(3.988)(4.069)
dnfa0.2120.4620.3470.3180.1820.2410.479
(0.299)(0.285)(0.302)(0.317)(0.320)(0.298)(0.290)
SI-INF −0.0347
(0.0388)
SI-GDP 0.0947 *
(0.0374)
SI-CPI −0.246 ***
(0.0363)
SI-IR −0.00445
(0.0362)
SI-LOAN 0.0371
(0.0370)
SI-ATM −0.000647
(0.0369)
SI-JO −0.0562 *
(0.0246)
SI-SHOP 0.0177
(0.0341)
SI-ExR −0.136 ***
(0.0285)
S I I N F ¯ −0.0974 *
(0.0410)
S I I R ¯ 0.0359
(0.0446)
S I C O N ¯ −0.114 *
(0.0562)
ACSI-INF 0.000416
(0.122)
ACSI-GDP −0.213
(0.232)
ACSI-CPI 0.213
(0.223)
ACSI-IR −0.110
(0.185)
ACSI-LOAN −0.316
(0.207)
ACSI-ATM 0.0392
(0.172)
ACSI-JO 0.293
(0.180)
ACSI-VC 0.127
(0.117)
ACSI-SHOP 0.442 *
(0.224)
ACSI-ExR −0.0865
(0.144)
LASI-INF 3.364
(4.018)
LASI-GDP −10.61 *
(5.296)
LASI-CPI 5.982
(4.447)
LASI-IR −6.452
(4.638)
LASI-LOAN −3.693
(3.866)
LASI-ATM 2.447
(3.705)
lagjo 2.730
(3.710)
LASI-VC 1.369
(3.972)
LASI-SHOP −0.695
(5.218)
LASI-ExR 0.487
(2.492)
SII −0.158 *
(0.0670)
ASSI-INF −0.659
(0.737)
ASSI-GDP 1.364 *
(0.541)
ASSI-CPI −4.661 ***
(0.690)
ASSI-IR −0.0611
(0.551)
ASSI-LOAN 0.821
(0.826)
ASSI-ATM 0.0191
(0.903)
ASSI-JO −1.158 *
(0.503)
ASSI-VC −0.143
(0.455)
ASSI-SHOP 0.289
(0.569)
ASSI-ExR −3.102 ***
(0.649)
Constant88.7353.0086.54132.6118.390.2254.30
(66.21)(62.39)(65.70)(68.08)(69.65)(65.86)(62.60)
Observations438438438433426438438
Adjusted R 2 0.3140.4080.3250.3070.2990.3210.406
F27.0119.1520.8812.1011.5124.8918.05
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A15. Panel Regression Table Fixed-Effects OM Models (HAR).
Table A15. Panel Regression Table Fixed-Effects OM Models (HAR).
Model 1Model 2Model 3Model 4Model 5Model 6Model 7
MM−0.004110.009590.01090.0009410.00408−0.003470.0102
(0.0338)(0.0355)(0.0343)(0.0341)(0.0347)(0.0338)(0.0356)
GDP−0.0498−0.130−0.0763−0.109−0.121−0.0659−0.132
(0.158)(0.160)(0.159)(0.159)(0.163)(0.159)(0.160)
IR1.324 ***1.231 ***1.274 ***1.438 ***1.378 ***1.301 ***1.225 ***
(0.341)(0.344)(0.340)(0.342)(0.355)(0.342)(0.344)
CPI−21.27−28.94−25.17−29.71−30.34−21.19−28.74
(16.54)(16.84)(16.82)(16.84)(17.29)(16.55)(16.87)
SI_INF −0.00245
(0.0161)
SI_GDP 0.0203
(0.0175)
SI_CPI 0.0124
(0.0183)
SI_IR −0.0595 ***
(0.0179)
SI_LOAN −0.00457
(0.0176)
SI_ATM 0.0117
(0.0188)
SI_JO 0.0217
(0.0175)
SI_SHOP 0.0199
(0.0167)
SI_ExR −0.0233
(0.0210)
S I I N F ¯ 0.00480
(0.0168)
S I I R ¯ −0.0740 **
(0.0286)
S I C O N ¯ 0.0319
(0.0265)
ACSI-INF −0.0206
(0.0399)
ACSI-GDP 0.132
(0.0715)
ACSI-CPI 0.0310
(0.0682)
ACSI-IR −0.165 **
(0.0579)
ACSI-LOAN −0.0118
(0.0417)
ACSI-ATM 0.0261
(0.0544)
ACSI-JO 0.0424
(0.0466)
ACSI-VC 0.0264
(0.0393)
ACSI-SHOP 0.0413
(0.0445)
ACSI-ExR −0.0304
(0.0464)
LASI-INF −0.242
(1.425)
LASI-GDP 1.343
(1.804)
LASI-CPI 0.957
(1.463)
LASI-IR −5.140 **
(1.619)
LASI-LOAN −0.753
(1.357)
LASI-ATM 0.252
(1.330)
LASI-JO 2.132
(1.215)
LASI-VC 0.413
(1.226)
LASI-SHOP 1.250
(1.589)
LASI-ExR −0.400
(1.141)
SII −0.0345
(0.0352)
ASSI-INF −0.0493
(0.306)
ASSI-GDP 0.297
(0.254)
ASSI-CPI 0.235
(0.348)
ASSI-IR −0.909 ***
(0.273)
ASSI-LOAN −0.108
(0.395)
ASSI-ATM 0.257
(0.469)
ASSI-JO 0.414
(0.363)
ASSI-VC 0.0527
(0.196)
ASSI-SHOP 0.347
(0.285)
ASSI-ExR −0.550
(0.484)
Constant120.0 ***125.9 ***124.0 ***127.5 ***128.0 ***121.5 ***125.6 ***
(17.23)(17.79)(17.65)(17.47)(17.89)(17.31)(17.85)
Observations515515515509501515515
Adjusted R 2
F
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A16. Panel Regression Table AM Model 2 (Robust and HAR).
Table A16. Panel Regression Table AM Model 2 (Robust and HAR).
Model OLSModel FEModel REModel FE-HARModel RE-HARModel GLS(h)Model GLS(p)
GDP−0.4310.137−0.4310.02730.02120.106−0.0173
(0.558)(0.636)(0.532)(0.153)(0.153)(0.376)(0.148)
IR1.516 ***2.413 *1.516 *2.211 ***2.099 ***1.439 ***2.041 ***
(0.236)(0.777)(0.604)(0.369)(0.354)(0.225)(0.323)
CPI−0.111−114.9−0.111−36.31−39.36 *6.738−41.17 *
(70.83)(83.95)(76.25)(20.05)(18.62)(58.05)(17.57)
PNT122.2 ***87.28122.2 ***81.84 ***86.78 ***108.2 ***90.49 ***
(14.34)(43.65)(35.76)(23.67)(19.52)(12.33)(17.12)
DBT−0.3724.985−0.3726.2390.04031.9654.727
(1.322)(7.994)(4.188)(6.983)(3.674)(1.133)(4.738)
ToT20.76 ***40.55 ***20.7618.90 ***20.58 ***25.34 ***20.81 ***
(3.577)(6.494)(13.36)(4.258)(3.951)(3.354)(3.792)
NFA0.1190.1280.1190.07640.1200.114 *0.120
(0.0654)(0.150)(0.113)(0.189)(0.128)(0.0535)(0.0988)
Constant−58.7664.09−58.7616.25 ***13.99−58.026.294
(75.75)(115.1)(116.2)(3.304)(29.23)(60.28)(26.29)
Observations447447447438447447447
Adjusted R 2 0.2410.333 0.131
F31.5099.01 11.57
Standard errors in parentheses, FE/RE-HAR = Fixed/Random-Effects heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation robust, GLS(h or p) = Generalized. Least Square Regression with heteroscedastic but uncorrelated error structure or panel-specific AR1 autocorrelation structure. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A17. Panel Regression Table Random-Effects OM Model 2 (HAR).
Table A17. Panel Regression Table Random-Effects OM Model 2 (HAR).
Model 1Model 2Model 3Model 4Model 5Model 6Model 7
GDP0.0212−0.0888−0.0341−0.0494−0.0747−0.0238−0.0935
(0.153)(0.155)(0.155)(0.156)(0.160)(0.156)(0.155)
IR2.099 ***1.799 ***1.909 ***2.047 ***2.108 ***1.978 ***1.795 ***
(0.354)(0.347)(0.343)(0.340)(0.357)(0.342)(0.347)
CPI−39.36 *−51.57 *−44.72 *−64.41 **−47.80 *−43.97 *−50.04 *
(18.62)(21.45)(21.64)(21.93)(22.51)(21.32)(21.59)
PNT86.78 ***74.17 ***74.26 ***79.59 ***75.29 ***77.02 ***74.07 ***
(19.52)(15.59)(15.58)(16.05)(16.15)(15.59)(15.60)
DBT0.0403
(3.674)
ToT20.58 ***20.37 ***21.23 ***20.51 ***21.57 ***21.13 ***20.52 ***
(3.951)(4.006)(4.019)(4.000)(4.083)(4.018)(4.014)
NFA0.120
(0.128)
dmm −0.110−0.148−0.119−0.0723−0.178−0.103
(0.140)(0.140)(0.141)(0.146)(0.141)(0.140)
ddbt 11.078.2678.8197.2788.55610.35
(15.59)(15.64)(15.51)(15.75)(15.68)(15.64)
dnfa 0.002390.06840.1340.02040.0911−0.00846
(0.135)(0.133)(0.137)(0.140)(0.133)(0.136)
SI_INF 0.00558
(0.0171)
SI_GDP 0.00445
(0.0188)
SI_CPI 0.0112
(0.0184)
SI_IR −0.0666 ***
(0.0182)
SI_LOAN −0.00624
(0.0199)
SI_ATM 0.00728
(0.0210)
SI_JO 0.0359 *
(0.0183)
SI_SHOP −0.000263
(0.0188)
SI_ExR −0.0509 *
(0.0229)
S I I N F ¯ −0.00489
(0.0170)
S I I R ¯ −0.0860 **
(0.0301)
S I C O N ¯ 0.0368
(0.0290)
ACSI-INF 0.00422
(0.0402)
ACSI-GDP 0.0773
(0.0791)
ACSI-CPI 0.0702
(0.0755)
ACSI-IR −0.206 **
(0.0632)
ACSI-LOAN −0.0723
(0.0727)
ACSI-ATM −0.0285
(0.0629)
ACSI-JO 0.171 **
(0.0612)
ACSI-VC 0.0411
(0.0385)
ACSI-SHOP 0.101
(0.0799)
ACSI-ExR −0.0236
(0.0532)
LASI-INF −0.0405
(1.642)
LASI-GDP −0.337
(1.988)
LASI-CPI 1.374
(1.622)
LASI-IR −5.998 ***
(1.740)
LASI-LOAN −0.777
(1.500)
LASI-ATM −0.619
(1.628)
LASI-JO 2.807 *
(1.259)
LASI-VC 1.597
(1.346)
LASI-SHOP −0.760
(2.087)
LASI-ExR −0.594
(1.166)
SII −0.0585
(0.0379)
ASSI-INF 0.0908
(0.325)
ASSI-GDP 0.0818
(0.273)
ASSI-CPI 0.214
(0.349)
ASSI-IR −1.031 ***
(0.278)
ASSI-LOAN −0.136
(0.445)
ASSI-ATM 0.114
(0.519)
ASSI-JO 0.681
(0.373)
ASSI-VC 0.137
(0.206)
ASSI-SHOP 0.0378
(0.319)
ASSI-ExR −1.211 *
(0.528)
Constant13.9953.84 *46.25 *58.79 **45.08 *43.04 *51.98 *
(29.23)(21.74)(22.07)(22.50)(22.85)(21.58)(21.93)
Observations447438438433426438438
Adjusted R 2
F
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A18. Panel Regression OM- And AM-Model 2 with Random-Effects (Robust).
Table A18. Panel Regression OM- And AM-Model 2 with Random-Effects (Robust).
OM-ModelOM-FE ModelAM-ModelAM-RE ModelModelAM_FEH2ModelAM_FEH7
dmm−0.183−0.141−0.140 −0.110−0.103
(0.131)(0.133)(0.133) (0.140)(0.140)
GDP−0.0508−0.139−0.1410.0212−0.0888−0.0935
(0.159)(0.160)(0.160)(0.153)(0.155)(0.155)
IR1.361 ***1.259 ***1.255 ***2.099 ***1.799 ***1.795 ***
(0.341)(0.345)(0.346)(0.354)(0.347)(0.347)
CPI−23.38−34.08 *−33.99 *−39.36 *−51.57 *−50.04 *
(16.69)(17.06)(17.09)(18.62)(21.45)(21.59)
SI_INF 0.000549 0.00558
(0.0165) (0.0171)
SI_GDP 0.0269 0.00445
(0.0178) (0.0188)
SI_CPI 0.00479 0.0112
(0.0187) (0.0184)
SI_IR −0.0659 *** −0.0666 ***
(0.0182) (0.0182)
SI_LOAN −0.0140 −0.00624
(0.0181) (0.0199)
SI_ATM 0.0212 0.00728
(0.0195) (0.0210)
SI_JO 0.0193 0.0359 *
(0.0184) (0.0183)
SI_SHOP 0.0201 −0.000263
(0.0166) (0.0188)
SI_ExR −0.0161 −0.0509 *
(0.0209) (0.0229)
ASSI-INF 0.00877 0.0908
(0.314) (0.325)
ASSI-GDP 0.391 0.0818
(0.257) (0.273)
ASSI-CPI 0.0908 0.214
(0.355) (0.349)
ASSI-IR −1.004 *** −1.031 ***
(0.278) (0.278)
ASSI-LOAN −0.314 −0.136
(0.404) (0.445)
ASSI-ATM 0.499 0.114
(0.488) (0.519)
ASSI-JO 0.380 0.681
(0.378) (0.373)
ASSI-VC 0.0243 0.137
(0.198) (0.206)
ASSI-SHOP 0.342 0.0378
(0.284) (0.319)
ASSI-ExE −0.377 −1.211 *
(0.481) (0.528)
PNT 86.78 ***74.17 ***74.07 ***
(19.52)(15.59)(15.60)
DBT 0.0403
(3.674)
ToT 20.58 ***20.37 ***20.52 ***
(3.951)(4.006)(4.014)
NFA 0.120
(0.128)
ddbt 11.0710.35
(15.59)(15.64)
dnfa 0.00239−0.00846
(0.135)(0.136)
Constant121.7 ***132.3 ***132.2 ***13.9953.84 *51.98 *
(16.99)(17.68)(17.72)(29.23)(21.74)(21.93)
Observations506506506447438438
Standard errors in parentheses, FE/RE = Fixed/Radome Effects, FEH = Fixed-Effects Robust Std. Errors. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A19. Panel Regression OM Model for Countries.
Table A19. Panel Regression OM Model for Countries.
AustraliaChinaCanadaGermanyJapanMexicoSwedenSwitzerlandUKUS
dmm1.732−1.0240.548−3.791 ***−15.03 ***0.133−0.813 *0.7282.047 *0.890
(1.299)(1.073)(1.298)(0.600)(3.935)(0.731)(0.390)(0.641)(0.932)(1.476)
GDP4.6601.933−20.59 **−0.912−1.1351.7671.942 **0.7074.991 ***0.923
(3.117)(1.620)(6.787)(0.515)(1.185)(1.158)(0.605)(1.320)(1.026)(1.851)
IR−2.248 **0.826−0.3904.133 ***−25.93 **2.077 **2.892 ***−6.669 ***3.101 ***0.908
(0.730)(0.748)(6.502)(0.384)(9.354)(0.700)(0.448)(0.716)(0.373)(0.625)
CPI600.6 *64.63−246.2−142.3−645.1 *−248.0−10.03−104.4−395.9 **−173.5
(293.5)(178.4)(187.4)(155.7)(244.9)(166.4)(111.4)(108.8)(129.2)(142.3)
Constant−506.928.06399.3 *242.5745.2 **335.3 *107.9205.3498.0 ***276.3
(295.1)(179.1)(189.3)(156.1)(245.0)(166.8)(111.3)(108.9)(130.0)(143.2)
Observations55522853525552535452
Adjusted R 2 0.114−0.0000.3470.7120.2980.1350.4860.6800.7590.015
F2.7351.0004.59533.186.4103.10813.0528.6442.630.810
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A20. Panel Regression OM Model with SI for Countries.
Table A20. Panel Regression OM Model with SI for Countries.
AustraliaChinaCanadaGermanyJapanMexicoSwedenSwitzerlandUKUS
dmm2.4480.3401.368−3.035 **2.8600.669−0.1080.4090.597−1.246
(1.468)(1.033)(0.836)(1.008)(3.806)(0.534)(0.395)(0.541)(1.297)(0.813)
GDP4.0350.955−5.698−1.176 *−1.265 *0.9711.825 **0.4243.415 **−0.534
(2.660)(1.472)(4.591)(0.532)(0.610)(0.814)(0.588)(1.269)(1.223)(1.083)
IR−0.198−1.435−1.9512.155 *−31.15 ***1.2903.079 ***−2.036 *4.607 ***1.620 **
(1.936)(1.041)(3.522)(0.859)(4.752)(1.087)(0.712)(0.992)(0.967)(0.531)
CPI888.0 **93.61−165.352.50−228.4−146.8−80.15−91.92−328.4 *−121.9
(279.3)(154.6)(115.1)(156.1)(135.2)(124.2)(93.32)(108.3)(139.5)(96.63)
SI-INF−0.3220.03490.1040.158−0.134−0.2580.1030.0462−0.0243−0.0745
(0.190)(0.150)(0.0798)(0.0787)(0.0686)(0.225)(0.0589)(0.0690)(0.125)(0.117)
SI-GDP−0.0808−0.08690.0917−0.09400.1010.0488−0.04830.04340.06570.222 *
(0.203)(0.111)(0.111)(0.0824)(0.0856)(0.273)(0.0701)(0.104)(0.129)(0.107)
SI-CPI−0.121−0.362 **0.109−0.0414−0.194−0.156−0.0552−0.181−0.1480.510 **
(0.184)(0.113)(0.130)(0.0784)(0.110)(0.173)(0.0551)(0.114)(0.106)(0.160)
SI-IR0.114−0.1650.240−0.129−0.128−0.0514−0.02990.0237−0.0791−0.0968
(0.133)(0.204)(0.234)(0.0719)(0.107)(0.216)(0.0844)(0.0657)(0.116)(0.121)
SI-LOAN−0.385−0.1780.05590.1310.0332−0.346 ***−0.1260.05210.2070.324 ***
(0.265)(0.131)(0.105)(0.0678)(0.104)(0.0915)(0.0735)(0.0711)(0.133)(0.0902)
SI-ATM0.134−0.281 *−0.309−0.159 *−0.06450.307−0.05300.145−0.313 *0.674 ***
(0.175)(0.135)(0.229)(0.0757)(0.0976)(0.162)(0.0808)(0.117)(0.126)(0.160)
SI-JO0.255 *−0.167−0.6670.0278−0.143−0.1410.158−0.06330.0479−0.248
(0.102)(0.0972)(0.315)(0.0676)(0.139)(0.150)(0.0822)(0.0643)(0.0651)(0.181)
SI-SHOP0.265−0.09180.140−0.08240.310 *0.3430.419 ***0.211 **−0.1760.362 ***
(0.164)(0.123)(0.136)(0.0625)(0.127)(0.200)(0.106)(0.0710)(0.116)(0.0884)
SI-ExR−0.0913−0.2240.266 *−0.0316−0.406 ***0.00885−0.05500.009530.2220.166 **
(0.115)(0.119)(0.0970)(0.0472)(0.0581)(0.0982)(0.0492)(0.0981)(0.126)(0.0607)
Constant−785.6 **78.85270.8 *58.03334.9 *225.6154.8174.5457.8 **118.6
(281.5)(159.7)(118.8)(156.2)(140.9)(125.6)(94.05)(105.2)(142.4)(95.06)
Obs.55522853525552535452
Adj. R 2 0.4520.5770.8650.7750.8540.6580.7000.8430.7970.802
F4.4296.34614.2914.7923.879.00210.1522.4216.9716.94
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A21. Panel Regression OM Model with ASSI for Countries.
Table A21. Panel Regression OM Model with ASSI for Countries.
AustraliaChinaCanadaGermanyJapanMexicoSwedenSwissUKUS
dmm2.411−0.05231.561−3.090 **2.5000.671−0.03130.3571.699−1.176
(1.455)(1.068)(0.786)(1.037)(3.719)(0.541)(0.386)(0.535)(1.232)(0.791)
GDP3.9290.953−3.980−1.143 *−1.564 *0.9921.803 **0.8063.148 **−1.163
(2.638)(1.459)(4.384)(0.550)(0.621)(0.836)(0.572)(1.282)(1.115)(1.110)
IR0.564−1.061−0.1352.117 *−32.83 ***1.2543.601 ***−2.095 *3.782 ***1.343 *
(2.003)(1.072)(3.435)(0.879)(4.738)(1.127)(0.752)(0.980)(0.919)(0.539)
CPI883.0 **177.8−133.371.37−262.1−150.6−145.8−93.54−278.3 *−156.6
(276.8)(166.6)(108.7)(170.4)(133.3)(128.4)(97.98)(107.0)(127.8)(95.95)
ASSI-INF−7.2370.1412.4552.975−2.250−4.8182.544 *1.397−0.952−0.0424
(3.670)(2.859)(1.437)(1.515)(1.281)(4.346)(1.138)(1.343)(2.163)(2.292)
ASSI-GDP−1.347−2.0192.227−1.4491.1920.806−0.5501.2110.8172.171
(2.909)(1.699)(1.576)(1.243)(1.218)(4.059)(0.989)(1.546)(1.694)(1.616)
ASSI-CPI−0.0891−6.420 **1.527−0.869−2.890−2.936−1.889−2.726−2.9896.331
(3.841)(2.148)(2.314)(1.531)(2.079)(3.331)(1.121)(2.198)(1.828)(3.500)
ASSI-IR1.871−2.3384.002−1.810−2.647−0.862−1.1380.620−1.710−1.505
(2.004)(3.072)(3.317)(1.207)(1.642)(3.359)(1.304)(1.003)(1.609)(1.787)
ASSI-LOAN−10.27−5.4122.1123.0780.422−7.573 **−3.887 *1.5651.5436.844 **
(6.001)(3.112)(2.232)(1.626)(2.275)(2.304)(1.705)(1.593)(2.881)(1.972)
ASSI-ATM4.895−5.734−6.500−3.718−3.1067.558−1.6850.655−7.319 *13.83 **
(4.395)(3.353)(5.204)(1.920)(2.480)(4.046)(1.920)(3.466)(2.774)(4.044)
ASSI-JO5.147 *−3.448−11.870.681−3.155−2.7513.270 *−1.1551.851−7.540
(2.044)(1.942)(5.964)(1.437)(2.732)(3.123)(1.611)(1.282)(1.226)(3.816)
ASSI-VC−3.5352.348−2.308−0.2562.695−0.410−1.3361.8563.826 **3.085
(2.668)(1.819)(1.301)(0.866)(1.575)(2.815)(0.751)(1.312)(1.247)(1.727)
ASSI-SHOP4.955−0.5922.217−1.3507.872 **5.6286.287 **3.888 **−2.8177.380 ***
(2.728)(2.159)(2.108)(1.055)(2.592)(3.419)(1.762)(1.197)(1.758)(1.618)
ASSI-ExR0.115−3.5976.898 **−0.655−8.503 ***0.303−0.322−0.6082.4183.933 **
(3.080)(2.938)(2.109)(1.111)(1.364)(2.367)(1.209)(2.283)(2.739)(1.348)
Constant−780.4 **−15.50231.739.20349.5 *230.0227.6 *168.8403.6 **163.4
(278.9)(174.4)(112.8)(170.4)(137.7)(130.7)(100.2)(103.9)(130.6)(95.78)
Obs.55522853525552535452
Adj. R 2 0.4620.5840.8830.7700.8610.6500.7160.8470.8320.813
F4.3146.11515.5213.4223.508.16110.1921.5019.7416.86
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A22. Panel Regression AM Model for Countries.
Table A22. Panel Regression AM Model for Countries.
AustraliaChinaCanadaGermanyJapanMexicoSwedenSwitzerlandUK
dmm0.2770.750−2.618 ***−6.7840.124−0.783 *0.140−0.661−0.447
(0.866)(0.519)(0.674)(5.287)(0.323)(0.300)(0.417)(0.997)(1.032)
GDP2.052−2.638 **0.09850.483−0.4391.726 ***−1.2973.298 **−1.414
(1.794)(0.947)(0.522)(1.117)(0.542)(0.472)(0.961)(0.990)(1.460)
IR1.782 *−3.958 ***3.290 ***−42.86 ***0.2433.103 ***−3.072 **4.811 ***1.608 ***
(0.809)(0.522)(0.586)(10.73)(0.377)(0.456)(0.936)(0.458)(0.416)
CPI305.856.57−16.35−657.8−74.39−39.73−253.3 **162.23.320
(189.4)(110.2)(173.9)(332.3)(65.18)(85.79)(71.37)(136.1)(143.7)
PNT191.3 ***6.358−9.541−146.3189.4 ***83.24 ***260.5 ***188.3 ***−95.05 *
(37.43)(33.72)(50.53)(154.6)(33.42)(12.61)(53.16)(41.77)(41.86)
ddbt−100.6−823.0 ***346.2 ***1455.1 **−18.85−1.093491.7 ***−100.2−378.4 **
(74.34)(130.2)(76.74)(484.0)(74.25)(13.57)(99.65)(68.78)(116.2)
ToT61.39 ***203.2 ***28.5334.7878.89 ***−80.14 ***22.48 ***−96.36241.7 ***
(7.108)(15.79)(48.31)(18.37)(10.30)(21.17)(5.610)(51.27)(38.33)
dnfa1.610 **−1.149 *−0.2551.204−0.914−0.4911.418−2.721 *0.245
(0.525)(0.464)(0.661)(1.461)(0.878)(0.547)(1.013)(1.040)(0.578)
Constant−469.0 *−160.796.23865.3 *−93.22130.764.38−155.4−42.88
(195.4)(113.5)(177.9)(363.4)(71.01)(92.48)(79.07)(151.9)(143.2)
Observations525248484551385252
Adjusted R 2 0.7420.7920.7820.5340.7450.7460.8960.8750.612
F19.3225.2222.127.73817.1119.4040.6345.5511.07
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A23. Panel Regression AM Model with SI for Countries.
Table A23. Panel Regression AM Model with SI for Countries.
AustraliaChinaCanadaGermanyJapanMexicoSwedenSwitzerlandUK
dmm−0.590−0.295−0.6433.074−0.366−0.07760.147−1.251−1.298 *
(1.163)(0.640)(1.044)(3.708)(0.363)(0.342)(0.436)(1.291)(0.637)
GDP0.848−2.061 *−0.161−0.234−0.4991.302 *−1.5722.988 *−0.518
(1.943)(0.967)(0.493)(0.593)(0.513)(0.537)(1.083)(1.175)(0.963)
IR2.185−2.236 *0.251−25.25 ***1.895 *2.334 **−0.8455.781 ***1.194 **
(1.520)(0.824)(1.010)(6.205)(0.770)(0.679)(1.421)(0.920)(0.433)
CPI334.650.81−130.822.74−88.84−50.87−260.7 **296.15.838
(219.0)(103.9)(173.2)(207.4)(72.28)(89.84)(90.99)(167.7)(116.9)
PNT187.8 **38.8463.03236.3183.5 **79.40 **371.6 ***198.9 **−80.23
(53.80)(31.81)(52.24)(117.5)(58.35)(24.03)(71.89)(66.22)(39.82)
ddbt−65.80−504.5 **474.0 ***913.9 **88.8915.87315.4 *−10.08−257.2 *
(82.97)(148.6)(104.1)(286.6)(73.12)(16.91)(130.4)(100.7)(98.08)
ToT54.18 ***163.2 ***−120.8 *−14.3577.59 ***−66.51 *−3.128−71.28130.9 ***
(8.782)(17.49)(54.49)(15.48)(9.742)(25.23)(11.68)(62.00)(32.32)
dnfa1.186−0.884 *−1.504 *−0.4440.000573−0.07232.468 *−4.263 **−0.151
(0.651)(0.427)(0.705)(0.844)(0.919)(0.557)(1.145)(1.531)(0.366)
SI-INF0.05180.00218−0.00659−0.0851−0.1640.04490.116 *0.0451−0.00463
(0.140)(0.0978)(0.0793)(0.0617)(0.110)(0.0505)(0.0515)(0.0981)(0.0980)
SI-GDP−0.274−0.0195−0.01520.03870.001610.00729−0.103−0.01890.0958
(0.143)(0.0736)(0.0725)(0.0980)(0.145)(0.0635)(0.0846)(0.107)(0.0891)
SI-CPI0.108−0.164 *0.0260−0.0987−0.00406−0.0585−0.1680.02860.215
(0.136)(0.0687)(0.0642)(0.112)(0.0811)(0.0482)(0.0995)(0.0877)(0.142)
SI-IR−0.0614−0.157−0.1420.08940.0224−0.01660.0832−0.06760.0502
(0.103)(0.117)(0.0842)(0.140)(0.117)(0.0758)(0.0582)(0.113)(0.107)
SI-LOAN0.109−0.04420.08890.1040.182−0.04420.09690.268 *0.149
(0.202)(0.0781)(0.0562)(0.104)(0.232)(0.0696)(0.0786)(0.103)(0.0931)
SI-ATM0.03090.0318−0.196 **−0.003280.115−0.0618−0.128−0.1890.528 ***
(0.139)(0.0866)(0.0641)(0.108)(0.101)(0.0688)(0.116)(0.153)(0.141)
SI-JO0.0989−0.1050.112−0.231−0.1330.116−0.08890.00254−0.235
(0.0759)(0.0535)(0.0694)(0.160)(0.0707)(0.115)(0.0642)(0.0665)(0.142)
SI-SHOP0.186−0.109−0.09400.324 *0.07950.1990.0310−0.233 *0.367 ***
(0.112)(0.0791)(0.0549)(0.126)(0.122)(0.105)(0.0775)(0.105)(0.0812)
SI-ExR−0.0449−0.0566−0.0143−0.455 ***0.0703−0.121 *0.02290.1130.118 *
(0.0901)(0.0768)(0.0418)(0.0683)(0.0834)(0.0530)(0.157)(0.121)(0.0505)
Constant−501.3 *−116.9299.6−158.5−88.08124.5−1.169−312.9−24.61
(215.2)(103.7)(188.1)(275.0)(69.16)(98.71)(101.3)(174.5)(111.8)
Observations525248484551385252
Adjusted R 2 0.7720.8740.8580.9000.8160.7910.9160.8900.884
F11.1521.9017.7225.8612.4912.1224.8525.2923.78
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table A24. Panel Regression AM Model with ASSI for Countries.
Table A24. Panel Regression AM Model with ASSI for Countries.
AustraliaChinaCanadaGermanyJapanMexicoSwedenSwitzerlandUK
dmm−0.550−0.312−0.6623.114−0.359−0.06620.186−0.354−1.292
(1.171)(0.646)(1.053)(3.642)(0.369)(0.345)(0.435)(1.245)(0.649)
GDP0.790−2.022 *−0.0927−0.544−0.4691.292 *−1.0123.396 **−0.557
(1.956)(0.978)(0.506)(0.620)(0.526)(0.542)(1.191)(1.100)(1.047)
IR2.538−2.274 *−0.000386−27.38 ***1.846 *2.513 **−1.0095.386 ***1.178 *
(1.596)(0.833)(1.081)(6.267)(0.792)(0.735)(1.421)(0.865)(0.467)
CPI346.497.69−91.10−37.03−98.97−74.40−247.3 *326.4 *1.423
(220.9)(127.4)(183.9)(207.8)(77.75)(97.16)(91.32)(155.7)(126.1)
PNT188.7 **35.3950.77227.0183.5 **76.20 **363.7 ***137.5 *−80.10
(54.13)(32.53)(55.58)(115.6)(59.29)(24.70)(71.87)(65.76)(40.43)
ddbt−55.00−526.8 **491.3 ***864.6 **86.8116.20332.7 *−19.01−258.5 *
(84.62)(153.8)(107.9)(283.5)(74.48)(17.06)(130.7)(93.30)(100.4)
ToT52.83 ***161.2 ***−112.9−17.0577.62 ***−63.22 *0.620−72.48129.9 ***
(9.007)(17.89)(56.14)(15.31)(9.897)(25.92)(12.10)(57.40)(34.24)
dnfa1.094−0.997 *−1.342−0.3930.01600.004961.824−4.535 **−0.143
(0.665)(0.465)(0.748)(0.830)(0.934)(0.574)(1.280)(1.422)(0.379)
ASSI-INF0.4620.148−0.406−1.453−3.0791.1272.438 *0.0850−0.0230
(2.765)(1.880)(1.571)(1.156)(2.115)(1.050)(0.996)(1.749)(1.989)
ASSI-GDP−3.997−0.700−0.3770.4970.2800.129−0.9340.1921.348
(2.080)(1.252)(1.081)(1.392)(2.224)(0.927)(1.318)(1.446)(1.357)
ASSI-CPI3.022−3.086 *0.389−1.015−0.0229−1.472−2.1890.2823.912
(2.890)(1.315)(1.238)(2.163)(1.569)(1.069)(2.084)(1.543)(3.157)
ASSI-IR−0.921−2.167−1.8050.2290.177−0.5071.136−1.2890.758
(1.568)(1.822)(1.386)(2.233)(1.845)(1.221)(0.888)(1.591)(1.643)
ASSI-LOAN1.771−1.4442.2892.2614.710−1.4852.6393.6393.286
(4.619)(1.895)(1.339)(2.273)(5.512)(1.734)(1.798)(2.310)(2.137)
ASSI-ATM1.6770.925−4.544 **−1.7082.934−1.534−4.643−5.05012.77 ***
(3.597)(2.133)(1.603)(2.813)(2.515)(1.685)(3.131)(3.441)(3.535)
ASSI-JO2.055−2.1812.552−4.374−2.5902.169−1.4530.895−4.896
(1.540)(1.091)(1.473)(3.169)(1.466)(2.355)(1.322)(1.281)(3.305)
ASSI-VC−1.4950.757−0.5612.116−0.761−0.4921.2612.669 *0.169
(1.935)(1.171)(0.807)(1.457)(1.918)(0.734)(1.145)(1.034)(1.627)
ASSI-SHOP3.347−1.534−1.4617.476 **1.2213.1900.248−4.054 *6.198 ***
(1.899)(1.395)(0.933)(2.503)(2.085)(1.779)(1.306)(1.619)(1.616)
ASSI-ExR−0.251−1.114−0.0863−9.938 ***1.585−2.293−0.09982.1902.700 *
(2.294)(1.786)(1.021)(1.556)(1.931)(1.395)(3.613)(2.558)(1.180)
Constant−513.6 *−161.0264.1−101.3−76.95150.5−16.79−282.8−19.01
(217.1)(125.0)(196.5)(272.9)(75.66)(106.9)(101.8)(162.0)(125.6)
Observations525248484551385252
Adjusted R 2 0.7690.8720.8560.9030.8100.7870.9170.9060.880
F10.4420.3516.4725.4511.4411.2823.7928.2321.81
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.

Notes

1
Appendix A contains the summary statistics of all variables in detail.
2
First we include N F A t in our regression models. However, N F A t creates a multi-collinearity problem with the highest VIF-factor of 8.81 . Thus, we drop N F A t from our main regression models. Upon request, we provide the estimates including N F A t .
3
In order to check the robustness of our regression, we estimate the fourteen variants based on our row data as well ( M o d e l R o w D a t ). The results are largely robust. The Tables are in the online Appendix.
4
Alternatively we conduct Kao’s cointegration test (Kao 1999).
5
All non-stationary variables must be transformed into stationary. This is done through a process called differencing: y t : = ln ( x t + 1 ) ln ( x t ) .
6
We also check the standard Prais-Winsten test-statistics.
7
Table 5 and Table A12 represent the output of the basic regression model.
8
The variable N F A and its significance was discussed by Branson and Henderson (1985), who argue that changes in net holdings of foreign asset directly affect a country’s currency.
9
Results for the estimates with non-transformed data are reported in the Appendix C (Table A13).
10
Note, however, R-square can be rather meaningless (Blackwell 2005).
11
In addition, Table A9 and Table A10 summarize the results of our first regression exercise.
12
All other country related impulse response functions are available upon request.

References

  1. Althouse, Benjamin M., Yih Yng Ng, and Derek A. T. Cummings. 2011. Prediction of dengue incidence using search query surveillance. PLOS Neglected Tropical Diseases 5: 12–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Andersen, Torben G., Tim Bollerslev, Francis X. Diebold, and Clara Vega. 2003. Micro effects of macro announcements: Real-time price discovery in foreign exchange. American Economic Review 93: 38–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Askitas, Nikolaos, and Klaus F. Zimmermann. 2009. Google econometrics and unemployment forecasting. Applied Economics Quarterly 55: 107–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  4. Baker, Scott R., Nicholas Bloom, and Steven J. Davis. 2016. Measuring Economic Policy Uncertainty. Quarterly Journal of Economics 131: 1593–636. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Balassa, Bela. 1964. The purchasing-power partiy doctrine: A Reappraisal. Journal of Political Economy 72: 584–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Bank, Matthias, Martin Larch, and Georg Peter. 2011. Google search volume and its influence on liquidity and returns on german stocks. Financial Markets and Portfolio Management 25: 239–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Berkowitz, Jeremy, and Lorenzo Giorgianni. 2001. Long-horizon exchange rate predictability? Review of Economics and Statistics 83: 81–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. BIS. 2016. Triennial Central Bank Survy. Basel: Bank for International Settlements. [Google Scholar]
  9. Blackwell, J. Lloyd. 2005. Estimation and testing of fixed-effect panel-data systems. Stata Journal 5: 202–7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Branson, William H., and Dale W. Henderson. 1985. The specification and influence of asset markets. In Handbook of International Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier, vol. 2, pp. 749–805. [Google Scholar]
  11. Breusch, T. S., and A. R. Pagan. 1979. A simple test for heteroscedasticity and random coefficient variation. Econometrica 47: 1287–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Breusch, T. S., and A. R. Pagan. 1980. The lagrange multiplier test and its application to model specification in econometrics. Review of Economic Studies 47: 239–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Brissimis, Sophoeles N., Dimitris A. Sideris, and Fragiska K. Voumvaki. 2005. Testing long-run purchasing power partiy under exchange rate targeting. Journal of International Money and Finance 24: 959–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  14. Buiter, Willem H., and Marcus Hay Miller. 1981. Monetary policy and international competitiveness. Oxford Economic Papers 33: 303–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Bulut, Levent. 2017. Google trends and the forecasting performance of exchange rate models. Journal of Forecasting 37: 303–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Cassel, G. 1918. Abnormal deviations in international exchanges. Economic Journal 28: 413–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Chai, Daniel, Mengjia Dai, Philip Gharghori, and Barbara Hong. 2021. Internet search intensity and its relation with trading activity and stock returns. International Review of Finance 30: 282–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Chatterjee, Samprit, and Ali S. Hadi. 1986. Influential observations, high leverage points, and outliers in linear regression. Statistical Science 1: 379–93. [Google Scholar]
  19. Chen, Joseph, Harrison Hong, and Jeremy C. Stein. 2001. Forecasting crashes: Trading volume, past returns, and conditional skewness in stock prices. Journal of Financial Economics 61: 345–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Cheung, Yin-Wong, Menzie D. Chinn, and Antonio Garcia Pascual. 2005. Empirical exchange rate models of the nineties: Are any fit to survive? Journal of International Money and Finance 24: 1150–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Choi, Hyunyoung, and Hal Varian. 2012. Predicting the present with google trends. Economic Record 88: 2–9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Choi, In. 2001. Unit root tests for panel data. Journal of International Money and Finance 20: 249–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Clarida, Richard, and Jordi Gali. 1995. Sources of real exchange rate fluctuations: How important are nominal shocks? Canargie-Rochester Series on Public Policy 41: 1–56. [Google Scholar]
  24. Clark, Peter B., and Ronald MacDonald. 1998. Exchange rates and economic fundamentals: A methodological comparison of BEERs and FEERs. In Equilibrium Exchange Rates. Boston: Kluver, vol. 69, pp. 285–322. [Google Scholar]
  25. Cook, R. Dennis, and Sanford Weisberg. 1983. Diagnostics for heteroscedasticity in regression. Biometrika 70: 1–10. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Da, Zhi, Joseoh Engelberg, and Pengjie Gao. 2011. In search of attention. Journal of Finance 66: 1461–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Desjardins, Jeff. 2018. How Google Retains More Than 90% of Market Share. New York: Business Insider. [Google Scholar]
  28. Dornbusch, Rudiger. 1976a. Capital mobility. Flexible exchange rates and macroeconomic equilibrium. In Recent Issues in International Monetary Economics. Edited by Emil-Maria Claassen and Pascal Salin. Amsterdam: North Holland. [Google Scholar]
  29. Dornbusch, Rudiger. 1976b. Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. Journal of Political Economy 84: 1161–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Dornbusch, Rudiger, and Paul Krugman. 1976. Flexible exchange rates in the short run. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1976: 537–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Driskill, Robert A. 1981. Exchange-rate dynamics: An empirical investigation. Journal of Political Economy 89: 357–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Drukker, David M. 2003. Testing for serial correlation in linear panel-data models. Stata Journal 3: 169–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Engel, Charles, and Kenneth D. West. 2005. Exchange rates and fundamentals. Journal of Political Economy 113: 485–517. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  34. Ettredge, Michael, John Gerdes, and Gilbert Karuga. 2005. Using web-based search data to predit macroeconomic statistics. Communications of the ACM 48: 87–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Ewards, Sebastian. 1989. Real Exchange Rates, Devaluation, and Adjustment. Cambridge: MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
  36. Fischer, Stanley. 1977. Long-term contracts, rational expectations, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy 85: 191–205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  37. Frankel, Jeffery A. 1979. On the mark: A theory of floating exchange rates based on real interest differentials. American Economic Review 69: 610–22. [Google Scholar]
  38. Ginsberg, Jeremy, Matthew H. Mohebbi, Rajan S. Patel, Lynnette Brammer, Mark S. Smolinski, and Larry Brilliant. 2009. Detecting influenza epidemics using search engine query data. Nature 457: 1012–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  39. Goel, Sharad, Jake M. Hofman, Sebastien Lahaie, David M. Pennock, and Duncan J. Watts. 2010. Predicting Consumer Behavior with Web Search. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 41: 17486–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  40. Google. 2018. How Trends Data Is Adjusted. Mountain View: Google. [Google Scholar]
  41. Gray, Jo Anna. 1976. Wage indexation: A macroeconomic approach. Journal of Monetary Economics 2: 221–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  42. Helft, Miguel. 2009. Google’s new tool is meant for marketers. New York Times, August 6. [Google Scholar]
  43. Hooper, Peter, and John Morton. 1982. Fluctuations in the dollar: A model of nominal and real exchange rate determination. Journal of International Money and Finance 1: 39–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  44. Im, Kyung So, M. Hashem Pesaran, and Yongcheol Shin. 2003. Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics 115: 53–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. IMF. 2018. Macroeconomic and Financial Data. Available online: https://www.imf.org/en/Data (accessed on 15 April 2021).
  46. Jun, Seung-Pyo, Tae-Eung Sung, and Hyun-Woo Park. 2017. Forecasting by analogy using the web search traffic. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 115: 37–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  47. Kao, Chihwa. 1999. Spurious regression and residual-based tests for cointegration in panel data. Journal of Econometrics 90: 1–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Kouwenberg, Roy, Agnieszka Markiewicz, Ralph Verhoeks, and Remco C. J. Zwinkels. 2017. Model uncertainty and exchange rate forecasting. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 52: 341–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  49. Lazer, David, Ryan Kennedy, Gary King, and Alessandro Vespignani. 2014. The parable of google flu: Traps in big data analysis. Science 343: 1203–5. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Liang, Hong. 1998. Real Exchange Rate Volatility: Does the Nominla Exchagne Raate Regime Matter? Working Paper. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, pp. 1–38. [Google Scholar]
  51. Mark, Nelson C. 1995. Exchange rates and fundamentals: Evidence on long-horizon predictability. American Economic Review 85: 201–18. [Google Scholar]
  52. Mark, Nelson C., and Donggyu Sul. 2001. Nominal exchange rates and monetary fundamentals: Evidence from a small post-Bretton woods panel. Journal of International Economics 53: 29–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Meese, Richard A., and Kenneth Rogoff. 1983. Empirical exchange rate models of the seventies: Do they fit out of sample? Journal of International Economics 14: 3–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Molodtsova, Tanya, and David H. Papell. 2009. Out-of-sample exchange rate predictability with Taylor rule fundamentals. Journal of International Economics 77: 167–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Mundell, Robert A. 1963. Capital mobility and stabilization policy under fixed and flexible exchange rates. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science 29: 475–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Mundell, Robert. 1968. International Economics. New York: Macmillan. [Google Scholar]
  57. Naccarato, Alessia, Stefano Falorsi, Silvia Loriga, and Andrea Pierini. 2018. Combining official and Google Trends data to forecast the Italian youth unemplyment rate. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 130: 114–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. OECD. 2018. OECD Main Economic Indicators (Mei). Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. [Google Scholar]
  59. Rogoff, Kenneth. 1995. The purchasing power parity puzzle. Journal of Economic Literature 34: 647–68. [Google Scholar]
  60. Rogoff, Kenneth. 2002. Dornbusch’s Overshooting Model after Twenty-Five Years. IMF Staff Papers 01-39. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
  61. Rossi, Babara. 2013. Exchange rate predictability. Journal of Economic Literature 51: 1063–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  62. Samuelson, Paul. 1964. Theoretical notes on trade problems. The Review of Economics Statistics 46: 145–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Sarno, Lucio, and Maik Schmeling. 2014. Which fundamentals drive exchange rates? A cross-sectional perspective. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 46: 267–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  64. Shim, Soyeon, Mary Ann Eastlick, Sherry L. Lotz, and Patricia Warrington. 2001. An online prepurchase intentions model: The role of intention to search. Journal of Retail 77: 397–416. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Takeda, Fumiko, and Takumi Wakao. 2013. Googe search intensity and its relationship with returns and trading volume of Japanese stocks. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 27: 1–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Vaughan, Liwen, and Esterban Romero-Frias. 2013. Web search volume as a predictor of academic fame: An exploration of google trends. Journal of the Association for Information Science and Technology 65: 707–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  67. Vaughan, Liwen, and Yue Chen. 2015. Data mining from web search queries: A comparison of google trends and baidu index. Journal of the Associaton for Information Science and Technology 66: 13–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Vlastakis, Nikolaos, and Raphael N. Markellos. 2012. Information demand and stock market volatility. Journal of Banking and Finance 36: 1808–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. US—Forecasting Errors.
Figure 1. US—Forecasting Errors.
Jrfm 14 00512 g001
Figure 2. US—VEC-Model Forecasting.
Figure 2. US—VEC-Model Forecasting.
Jrfm 14 00512 g002
Table 1. Google Trends Keyword Selection.
Table 1. Google Trends Keyword Selection.
EnglishGermanyJapaneseFrenchChineseSwedishSpanish
inflationInflationインフレーションinflation通貨膨脹inflationinflación
CPIVPI消費者物価指数IPC消費者物價指數KPIIPC
GDPBIP国内生产总值PIB國內生產總值BNPPIB
interest rateZinssatz利率taux d’intérêt利率räntesatstasa de interés
loanKreditクレジットcrédit借款kreditcrédito
ATMGeldautomat現金自動支払機Distribute-ur de billets自動提款機bankomatcajero
job openingStellenangebot求人Offre d’emploi職缺lediga jobboferta de trabajo
vacationUrlaub休暇vacance假期ferievacacionas
shoppingeinkaufenショッピングshopping購物shoppingcompras
exchange rateWechselkurs為替相場taux de change汇率växelkurstipo de cambio
appreciationAufwertung再評価réévaluation重估omvärderingrevaluación
Table 2. Panel Regression Table Random-Effects AM Models.
Table 2. Panel Regression Table Random-Effects AM Models.
Model 1Model 2Model 3Model 4Model 5Model 6Model 7
MM0.071 ***0.190 ***0.172 ***0.156 ***0.153 ***0.174 ***0.195 ***
(0.0176)(0.0379)(0.0373)(0.0338)(0.0340)(0.0326)(0.0380)
GDP0.2010.127−0.0410.031−0.063−0.0730.107
(0.370)(0.352)(0.376)(0.386)(0.389)(0.368)(0.352)
IR2.732 ***2.702 ***2.464 ***2.497 ***2.590 ***2.474 ***2.679 ***
(0.318)(0.316)(0.328)(0.340)(0.355)(0.324)(0.316)
CPI−106.400 *−74.090−82.890−92.770−112.600 *−82.920−74.210
(52.830)(49.560)(52.920)(54.810)(56.520)(52.160)(49.510)
PNT77.780 ***98.240 ***35.87027.95032.38045.490 *93.23 ***
(12.380)(21.540)(20.700)(20.150)(20.390)(19.180)(21.800)
DBT4.53915.16 ***8.593 **8.578 **9.033 **9.370 **15.94 ***
(2.750)(2.996)(2.991)(3.111)(3.218)(2.971)(3.043)
ToT40.020 ***34.820 ***43.84 ***43.290 ***44.250 ***43.21 ***35.140 ***
(4.038)(4.070)(4.176)(4.536)(4.666)(4.123)(4.071)
NFA −0.243−0.441 **−0.381 **−0.368 **−0.445 ***−0.267
(0.135)(0.133)(0.136)(0.139)(0.129)(0.136)
SI-INF 0.00243
(0.0359)
SI-GDP 0.0605
(0.0355)
SI-CPI −0.167 ***
(0.0352)
SI-IR −0.00556
(0.0356)
SI-LOAN 0.0286
(0.0341)
SI-ATM −0.0266
(0.0339)
SI-JO −0.0669 **
(0.0230)
SI-SHOP 0.0427
(0.0330)
SI-ExR −0.238 ***
(0.0310)
S I I N F ¯ −0.0503
(0.0423)
S I I R ¯ −0.0896
(0.0493)
S I C O N ¯ −0.0172
(0.0526)
ACSI-INF −0.111
(0.116)
ACSI-GDP −0.0773
(0.202)
ACSI-CPI 0.109
(0.209)
ACSI-IR −0.0987
(0.176)
ACSI-LOAN −0.158
(0.170)
ACSI-ATM 0.0259
(0.156)
acgjo −0.0147
(0.141)
ACSI-VC 0.143
(0.113)
ACSI-SHOP 0.0734
(0.124)
ACSI-ExR −0.0731
(0.128)
LASI-INF 2.131
(3.886)
LASI-GDP −8.505
(4.978)
LASI-CPI 3.865
(4.112)
LASI-IR −5.502
(4.293)
LASI-LOAN −1.986
(3.447)
LASI-ATM 0.790
(3.347)
LASI-JO 0.806
(3.504)
LASI-VC 3.210
(3.622)
LASI-SHOP 0.721
(4.693)
LASI-ExR −0.755
(2.429)
SII −0.229 ***
(0.0645)
ASSI-INF 0.0291
(0.680)
ASSI-GDP 0.859
(0.513)
ASSI-CPI −3.194 ***
(0.668)
ASSI-IR −0.106
(0.541)
ASSI-LOAN 0.639
(0.761)
ASSI-ATM −0.696
(0.823)
ASSI-JO −1.262 **
(0.466)
ASSI-VC 0.580
(0.410)
ASSI-SHOP 0.714
(0.549)
ASSI-ExR −5.479 ***
(0.706)
Constant70.81038.640124.0 *130.500 *143.400 *117.700 *43.020
(55.900)(56.860)(58.110)(59.200)(60.910)(56.780)(56.870)
Observations447447447441433447447
Adjusted R 2 0.3410.4650.3570.3310.3350.3690.466
F35.06024.25024.23013.56013.53030.91023.070
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table 3. Panel Regression Table Fixed-Effects OM Models.
Table 3. Panel Regression Table Fixed-Effects OM Models.
Model 1Model 2Model 3Model 4Model 5Model 6Model 7
dmm0.4650.722 *0.4160.5330.6620.4590.724 *
(0.331)(0.331)(0.349)(0.333)(0.347)(0.331)(0.331)
GDP0.3170.03000.3400.05210.06620.2580.0250
(0.463)(0.447)(0.474)(0.476)(0.482)(0.466)(0.448)
IR1.303 ***1.302 ***1.341 ***1.223 ***1.186 ***1.231 ***1.288 ***
(0.245)(0.318)(0.276)(0.253)(0.266)(0.253)(0.321)
CPI−221.400 ***−160.900 **−220.300 ***−230.600 ***−233.700 ***−221.800 ***−161.500 **
(62.230)(59.490)(62.630)(62.920)(64.440)(62.210)(59.560)
SI-INF −0.0756
(0.0432)
SI-GDP 0.184 ***
(0.0391)
SI-CPI −0.214 ***
(0.0423)
SI-IR −0.0444
(0.0398)
SI-LOAN −0.0259
(0.0318)
SI-ATM 0.0887 *
(0.0379)
SI-JO −0.0768 **
(0.0269)
SI-SHOP 0.0739 *
(0.0317)
SI-ExR −0.135 ***
(0.0280)
S I I N F ¯ −0.00631
(0.0483)
S I I R ¯ 0.0131
(0.0494)
S I C O N ¯ −0.0290
(0.0551)
ACSI-INF −0.0464
(0.148)
ACSI-GDP −0.0992
(0.264)
ACSI-CPI 0.123
(0.246)
ACSI-IR −0.231
(0.204)
ACSI-LOAN −0.384 *
(0.152)
ACSI-ATM 0.0895
(0.190)
ACSI-JO 0.310
(0.189)
ACSI-VC 0.124
(0.142)
ACSI-SHOP 0.177
(0.241)
ACSI-ExR −0.212
(0.155)
LASI-INF −2.160
(4.344)
LASI-GDP 0.458
(5.785)
LASI-CPI 2.923
(4.735)
LASI-IR −5.854
(5.167)
LASI-LOAN −5.952
(4.303)
LASI-ATM −0.488
(3.671)
LASI-JO 9.589 *
(4.196)
LASI-VC −0.283
(4.308)
LASI-SHOP −4.695
(4.801)
LASI-ExR −3.349
(2.760)
SII −0.0842
(0.0705)
ASSI-INF −1.414
(0.823)
ASSI-GDP 2.644 ***
(0.567)
ASSI-CPI −4.106 ***
(0.810)
ASSI-IR −0.681
(0.605)
ASSI-LOAN −0.609
(0.715)
ASSI-ATM 2.099 *
(0.933)
ASSI-JO −1.510 **
(0.551)
ASSI-VC 0.198
(0.504)
ASSI-SHOP 1.225 *
(0.528)
ASSI-ExR −3.072 ***
(0.639)
Constant319.100 ***265.000 ***319.300 ***329.200 ***331.800 ***323.700 ***265.300 ***
(62.410)(59.710)(62.870)(63.110)(64.640)(62.500)(59.770)
Observations506506506501494506506
Adjusted R 2 0.0450.1760.0390.0550.0420.0450.175
F9.14710.0105.2443.7183.1817.6099.291
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table 4. Panel Regression Table AM Model.
Table 4. Panel Regression Table AM Model.
Model OLSModel PAModel FEModel REModel ML
MoM0.03160.0715 ***0.0711 ***0.0484 **0.0715 ***
(0.0183)(0.0171)(0.0176)(0.0172)(0.0170)
GDP−0.4380.1920.201−0.1460.192
(0.496)(0.369)(0.370)(0.445)(0.367)
IR1.433 ***2.691 ***2.732 ***1.907 ***2.692 ***
(0.274)(0.310)(0.318)(0.280)(0.309)
CPI5.647−104.3 *−106.4 *−51.38−104.3 *
(70.42)(52.68)(52.83)(63.37)(52.39)
PNT110.1 ***79.27 ***77.78 ***99.67 ***79.22 ***
(13.56)(12.25)(12.38)(13.14)(12.20)
DBT−0.3683.9484.5390.7163.965
(1.101)(2.419)(2.750)(1.250)(2.425)
ToT20.55 ***38.90 ***40.02 ***25.72 ***38.94 ***
(3.500)(3.906)(4.038)(3.545)(3.916)
Constant−43.2768.4970.8115.3668.56
(73.43)(55.75)(55.90)(66.40)(55.44)
sigma(u)
Constant 6.569 ***
(1.595)
sigma(e)
Constant 6.375 ***
(0.215)
Observations447447447447447
Adjusted R 2 0.241 0.341
F21.18 35.06
Standard errors in parentheses, FE = Fixed-Effects, RE = Random-Effects, PA = Pooled, ML = Maximum-Likelihood. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table 5. Panel Regression Table OM Model.
Table 5. Panel Regression Table OM Model.
Model OLSModel PAModel FEModel REModel ML
dmm1.472 ***0.5650.4650.6310.537
(0.327)(0.337)(0.331)(0.326)(0.327)
GDP1.269 *0.3970.3170.4510.375
(0.574)(0.479)(0.463)(0.468)(0.461)
IR0.1101.231 ***1.303 ***1.181 ***1.252 ***
(0.224)(0.250)(0.245)(0.242)(0.243)
CPI−105.3−217.2 ***−221.4 ***−214.2 ***−218.4 ***
(79.00)(64.44)(62.23)(63.05)(61.96)
Constant202.6 *315.7 ***319.1 ***312.6 ***316.9 ***
(79.12)(64.66)(62.41)(63.24)(62.19)
sigma(u)
Constant 8.027 ***
(1.863)
sigma(e)
Constant 8.197 ***
(0.260)
Observations506506506506506
Adjusted R 2 0.054 0.045
F8.196 9.147
Standard errors in parentheses, FE = Fixed-Effects, RE = Random-Effects, PA = Pooled, ML = Maximum-Likelihood. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table 6. Prediction Performance Test.
Table 6. Prediction Performance Test.
BasicSI ModelASSI Model
Australia15.44 *20.2115.22
(4.530)(11.38)(7.984)
China3.2142.1240.994
(1.672)(1.931)(0.453)
Germany0.6185.0585.296
(0.598)(0.961)(1.503)
Mexico303.9 **16.3116.74
(40.64)(5.456)(5.496)
Swiss7.4475.2877.840
(5.900)(5.193)(6.309)
UK28.741.0511.488
(12.87)(0.624)(0.808)
Observations444
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table 7. Forecast Performance Test.
Table 7. Forecast Performance Test.
BasicARIMAModel ASSI PredictionNaive Forecast
Australia15.44 *9.04515.221.653
(4.530)(3.006)(7.984)(0.679)
China3.21410.740.9941.218
(1.672)(5.054)(0.453)(0.769)
Germany0.6183.4895.2968.192
(0.598)(1.968)(1.503)(4.582)
Mexico303.9 **23.6116.7448.86
(40.64)(14.75)(5.496)(22.59)
Swiss7.4475.9737.84012.81
(5.900)(3.515)(6.309)(9.440)
UK28.741.787 *1.4882.946
(12.87)(0.468)(0.808)(1.479)
Observations4444
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate; Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Table 8. Square-Mean Error of Forecasting after 1 year.
Table 8. Square-Mean Error of Forecasting after 1 year.
BasicARIMAModel ASSI ForecastNaive Forecast
Australia41.84 *25.61 *23.214.683 *
(10.80)(5.425)(13.45)(0.939)
Canada116.824.3313.749.497
(.)(7.666)(.)(4.573)
China8.387 *18.342.4463.448 *
(2.371)(8.670)(0.851)(1.014)
Germany0.93212.25 **8.893 *12.47
(0.304)(1.638)(1.700)(7.706)
Mexico796.8 *70.38 **50.82 *103.1
(173.1)(8.030)(10.00)(45.59)
Sweden0.080827.621.84117.59
(.)(11.92)(.)(7.193)
Swiss14.51 ***10.1815.30 ***15.92
(0.387)(4.638)(0.383)(12.02)
UK62.74 *4.574 *4.045 **7.058
(13.58)(1.359)(0.413)(2.227)
US319.369.42 **0.078033.53
(.)(8.401)(.)(18.23)
Observations4444
Standard errors in parentheses. Note: Independent variable is the Real Exchange Rate. In case of unreported std. errors. in the table, the regression algorithm either cannot compute or report errors well below zero. Source: Authors’ estimations. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Herzog, B.; dos Santos, L. Google Search in Exchange Rate Models: Hype or Hope? J. Risk Financial Manag. 2021, 14, 512. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14110512

AMA Style

Herzog B, dos Santos L. Google Search in Exchange Rate Models: Hype or Hope? Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2021; 14(11):512. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14110512

Chicago/Turabian Style

Herzog, Bodo, and Lana dos Santos. 2021. "Google Search in Exchange Rate Models: Hype or Hope?" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 14, no. 11: 512. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14110512

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop