Next Article in Journal
A Hybrid Model for Forecasting Realized Volatility Based on Heterogeneous Autoregressive Model and Support Vector Regression
Previous Article in Journal
Credibility Distribution Estimation with Weighted or Grouped Observations
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Moderating Role of Corporate Governance in the Relationship between Leverage and Firm Value: Evidence from the Korean Market

by
Ana Belén Tulcanaza-Prieto
1,*,
Younghwan Lee
2 and
Wendy Anzules-Falcones
3
1
Grupo de Investigación Lugar Medio Sociedad (LMS), Escuela de Negocios, Universidad de Las Américas (UDLA), Vía a Nayón, Quito 170124, Ecuador
2
Department of Business Administration, Kumoh National Institute of Technology, Gumi 39177, Republic of Korea
3
Grupo de Investigación Lugar Medio Sociedad (LMS), Carrera de Administración de Empresas, Facultad de Ciencias Económicas y Administrativas, Universidad de Las Américas (UDLA), Vía a Nayón, Quito 170124, Ecuador
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Risks 2024, 12(1), 11; https://doi.org/10.3390/risks12010011
Submission received: 16 November 2023 / Revised: 3 January 2024 / Accepted: 4 January 2024 / Published: 15 January 2024

Abstract

:
This study examines the moderating function of corporate governance (CG) to the relationship between leverage and firm value (FV) using Korean market data. The study employs ordinary least-squares panel data regressions and two methods to manage endogeneity problems. The findings show a meaningful negative relationship between leverage and FV. This relationship, however, disappears, when the interaction variable of leverage × CG is included in the econometric model. These results indicate that an effective CG mechanism may lessen the probability of either the entrenched management-decision-making behavior or the agency costs of debt and, therefore, the negative effect of debt to FV diminishes. Moreover, our data show that the relationship between leverage and FV becomes positive, even though insignificant, for firms with a high level of CG, whereas it stays significantly negative for firms with a low level of CG. We also find that leverage for firms with a high level of CG is lower than those firms with a low level of CG. These additional findings support our conclusion of the moderating role of CG, which also influences the firms’ risk, leverage, and FV. The authors recommend the implementation of a robust CG plan to decrease the information asymmetry and the agency leverage problem.

1. Introduction

Is corporate governance (CG) a moderating variable in the relationship between firm value (FV) and leverage? This inquiry has not been profoundly studied in the financial literature. Prior works usually focus on (1) the relationship between leverage and FV (Chen 2004; Cheng et al. 2010; González 2013; Jensen 1986; Opler and Titman 1994), (2) the relationship between FV and CG (Brown and Caylor 2006; Detthamrong et al. 2017; Tulcanaza-Prieto and Lee 2022b), and (3) the mediator role of leverage in the relationship between FV and CG (Detthamrong et al. 2017; Kijkasiwat et al. 2022). However, findings on the mediator role of leverage are not conclusive.
This study expands this mutual relationship to a concurrent relationship between leverage, CG, and FV. We address the question of whether CG moderates the effect of leverage on FV. This moderation relationship is important to study for the following reasons. First, effective CG provides financial efficiency because of the lower managers’ discretion over the financial resources of a firm which is also related to the optimum capital-structure composition, which will not be modified drastically given the supervisory role of agents, if any. Second, an effective CG structure might decrease the agency problem between parties because it introduces financial transparency, increases the reporting quality, and innovating with accountability and adequate control systems, which also shows the fundamental value of a firm, concluding with the increase in insider’s and outsider’s confidence and reliability. Third, CG introduces protection to shareholders’ rights, information disclosure, and reduces error management, which revises the final use of financial resources and reinforces the FV in the medium and long term.
This study introduces five individual CG characteristics, namely, shareholder rights, board structure, disclosure, audit organization, and management error, and an aggregate metric, which is the corporate governance score (CGS). Moreover, the dependent variables for FV are Tobin’s Q and the price-to-book ratio, while the independent variables are leverage and CG metrics, and it employs four control variables. The study ran ordinary least-squares (OLS) panel regressions and a two-stage least-square (2SLS) regression model and a generalized method of moments (GMM) to control the endogeneity problem. The sample is formed using 860 Korean firm-year observations during the 2017–2020 period, which follow the International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS). IFRS provide transparent and reliable accounting data and developed countries such as Australia, the United Kingdom, and the United States follow these international norms.
This paper supports three hypotheses. First, leverage and FV showed a significantly negative relationship, which is grounded in the entrenched management hypothesis and the agency cost of debt. Leverage is an important financial variable to control the operating cash flow and the discretion of managers. Second, CG significantly positively influenced FV because CG controls the firm’s risk through appropriate accountability and regulation systems, which also include transparency and information disclosure, providing long-term FV maximization. Third, CG moderates and decreases the negative relationship between debt and FV. Moreover, CG increases the firm’s transparency and/or decreases the disputes between managers and shareholders; therefore, managers might not take advantage of leverage to make selfish decisions. CG provokes efficiency and the maximization of FV due to its disciplinary mechanism that includes the permanent supervision of parties. Leverage might be controlled using effective CG mechanisms.
For a robustness check, we conduct additional regression analyses by dividing total firms into two groups according to the degree of CG. The first analysis shows that the negative relationship between leverage and FV loses its statistical significance for high-level firms, while it remains strong for low-level firms. These results indicate that an effective CG may act as a control variable for managers when they want to increase arbitrary financial debt. Therefore, it limits the agency conflicts of financial debt and reduces the negative effect on debt to FV accordingly, which is consistent with our previous conclusion. The second and third analyses contribute with a robustness check and control of the endogeneity problem by testing the results using 2SLS and GMM.
The contribution of the study is the identification of CG as an effective tool and moderator variable in the association between debt and FV. Effective CG might increase the FV, reduce the probability for managers to increase the firm’s leverage, and decrease the probability of scandals, fraud, manipulation of earnings, and unusual activities in a firm. In the presence of a high level of CG, managers may be restricted to access free cash flow and the budget of a firm may be controlled, which promotes the increase in firm performance. Strong-CG mechanisms may also prevent the management from absorbing bondholder’s wealth through over-indebtedness. From these findings, we conclude that firms with strong-CG levels do not inevitably show the FV deprivation related to capital structure modification. Moreover, the study presents two proxies for FV, which corroborate the research’s findings. The manuscript also covers a robustness check using the disaggregation of the sample in firms with high and low levels of CG, and it presents the results of 2SLS regressions models and GMM regressions to control endogeneity issues.
The manuscript presents the literature examination which supports three hypotheses in Section 2; Section 3 focuses on methodology development; sample statistics correspond to Section 4; and Section 5 covers the empirical findings and robustness check. The last section of the study discusses the results, presents conclusions, and suggests research lines for upcoming performance.

2. Literature Review

2.1. Leverage and FV

Jensen (1986) mentioned that the level of debt acts as a disciplinary financial tool. Moreover, more leverage raises FV until a specific point, and then the FV starts to decline (Lin and Chang 2011). Leverage can improve the FV because it compresses managers to make value-maximizing decisions. The agency cost of free cash flow is also reduced using leverage because managers might not exercise discretion over the corporate resources; thus, debt provides efficiency to the firm and shows a positive influence on internal capital markets (Wruck 1990). Some prior studies showed that lucrative firms increase their performance quality by rising their debt indicators, meaning a positive relationship between debt and FV (Abor 2005; Jensen 1986; Modigliani and Miller 1958; Ruland and Zhou 2005).
On the other hand, there are two views to study the negative relationship between leverage and FV. The traditional view of the pecking-order theory involves higher profitability and retained earnings, which declines the level of firm debt (González 2013). For instance, American highly leveraged firms have a tendency to experience lower operating profits than their competitors and lose market shares (Opler and Titman 1994). The management-entrenchment hypothesis implies that the entrenched managers have incentive enough to increase leverage beyond the optimal level. According to (Aggarwal et al. 2007; Harris and Raviv 1991), the entrenchment hypothesis stimulates managers to increase debt to inflate the elective influence of their equity securities and decrease the appropriation attempts by outside parties who may enlarge FV. Entrenched managers might also adopt excess leverage to use a signaling device to reveal an allegiance to sell assets or otherwise restructure, thereby displacing takeover attempts by third parties who might replace the firm assets to increase FV. The agency costs of debt may also motivate entrenched managers to enlarge leverage over and above the optimal point by taking large risks, hiring under investment, or milking properties. The higher the level of debt is, the more possibility there is for stockholders to engage in selfish strategies and the lower the FV will be, respectively. Previous studies in developing countries have shown a significant negative relationship between leverage and FV (Chen 2004; Ibhagui and Olokoyo 2018; Simon-Oke and Afolabi 2011). Therefore, the first hypothesis is as follows:
Hypothesis 1.
FV is negatively affected by leverage.

2.2. CG and FV

CG is an arrangement of direction and supervision that influences the firm’s goals. CG might act as a contract that governs the relationships between shareholders and managers. CG comprises the effective assessment of the firm’s risk. Good- and strong-CG mechanisms allow firms to (i) generate the firms’ value through operations, research, and innovation, which also includes financial wealth; (ii) offer accountability and satisfactory control systems; and (iii) introduce a status of consciousness and transparency (Detthamrong et al. 2017; Tulcanaza-Prieto and Lee 2022b). Moreover, CG can be considered a strategic tool in countries with weak legal atmospheres. The literature (Durnev and Kim 2005) mentioned that CG provides instruments to decrease the inadequacies and complications of the legal organization of nations.
Previous studies developed CG metrics according to the country’s environment, showing that CG might positively influence FV (Tulcanaza-Prieto et al. 2020b). The authors found that CG policies and practices positively influence FV in developed and emerging markets (Black et al. 2006; Brown and Caylor 2006; Gompers et al. 2003; Klapper and Love 2004; Tulcanaza-Prieto and Lee 2022b; Tulcanaza-Prieto et al. 2020b). The positive relationship between CG and FV is grounded in the agency model of divided payout because of the higher investor confidence, and, also, it generates a low cost of capital (La Porta et al. 2002). Moreover, the agency-cost problems and the opportunistic behavior of managers are reduced in firms with a high level of CG because these firms increase their transparency, disclose their public information, increase the reliability of their firms, and raise confidence in their decision-making process. Specifically, in the Korean market, most companies have controlling shareholders or families as an efficient tool of CG. It promotes efficient operations, increases the FV, and controls the actions of managers (Black et al. 2006; Lee et al. 2015; Yoon et al. 2006). Therefore, the second hypothesis is as follows:
Hypothesis 2.
FV is positively affected by CG practices.

2.3. Leverage, CG, and FV

The traditional view of management entrenchment states the relationship between leverage and FV, showing a negative relationship between both variables, which also is grounded in the agency cost of debt and the different interests between parties (shareholders and debtholders) based on the decisions made by management. Moreover, agency costs of debt might rise when the interests of shareholders and managers diverge, given an increase in the cost of debt. However, strong-CG mechanisms attempt to reduce this conflict of interest (Chan-Lau 2001; Jensen 1986).
If the entrenchment hypothesis is a dominant explanation, then CG practices may play a moderating role in loosening and breaking down the negative relationship between leverage and FV. The entrenched managers have access to firms’ information and have discretion over the leverage decisions of their firm. Information asymmetry generates monitoring and controlling difficulties with their actions. Specifically, entrenched managers fail to undergo discipline from the full range of corporate governance, which includes monitoring by the board committee, the takeover threat, and stock-based performance incentives. CG practices might act as effective corporate-control tools to reduce the probability of entrenched managers using discretion to decide to leverage above the optimal level, which may not necessarily reduce FV as a result.
CG structure has a vital influence on the degree of agency of costs of debt since it helps to mitigate the inefficiencies of capital allocations between business units, given the decrease in information asymmetries between parties (Altieri 2022). Moreover, the authors (Abdullah and Tursoy 2021) mentioned that CG significantly positively affects FV, while there is a negative relationship between a CG measurement (board size) and FV. However, these findings were weakened after the IFRS implementation in German firms, suggesting that both capital and CG structures cause better firm performance. The authors (Ngatno et al. 2021) showed that CG mechanisms in Indonesian firms act as a control and monitor the capital-structure decisions and decrease the agency costs of debt, given the presence of a commissioner and its optimal role in reducing the opportunistic behavior of managers, showing that effective CG decreases agency costs of debt, and, thus, the negative relationship between debt and FV is loosened.
Prior studies individually analyzed the relationship between (i) leverage and FV and (ii) FV and CG. However, there are not many articles about the concurrent relationship between leverage, CG, and FV. The objective of this paper is to show that CG might be considered a control tool that reduces the probability of taking an excessive risk by a firm (e.g., over leveraged) and improves, or at least diminishes the decrease in, FV. In this context, strong CG might provide the mechanisms to decrease the negative effect of leverage on FV and modify it into a positive because CG practices induce transparency, control, low discretion, and confidence in all management decisions and processes. When the information is transparent for all economic agents, the fundamental value of the firm might be shown to stakeholders, who believe in the administration’s decisions because of the stable income and low-risk-firm profile. Therefore, the third hypothesis is presented as follows:
Hypothesis 3.
Effective CG practices moderate the relationship between leverage and FV.

3. Empirical Design

3.1. CG Metrics

CG metrics are integrated using five CG characteristics (Standard & Poor’s Governance Services 2004), which are over 100 points each: (i) shareholder rights (CG1), (ii) board structure (CG2), (iii) disclosure (CG3), (iv) audit organization (CG4), and error management (CG5). The maximum value of CGS is 500, which is the aggregation of the five previous scores. In the Korean market, all firms adopted the IFRS, which improves accounting quality and decreases the frequency of transaction manipulation in the legal system and in financial statements (Ferentinou and Anagnostopoulou 2016).

3.2. Research Model

We used OLS-panel data-regression models with fixed effects (Nwakuya and Ijomah 2017) to investigate the relationship between leverage, CG, and FV in Korean non-financial firms. The dependent variable is FV measured using Tobin’s Q and price-to-book ratio (considered for the study as an alternative proxy to verify main findings), while the independent variables are leverage and CG metrics. The control variables are asset tangibility, size, firm liquidity, and net interest payment. The control variables were selected because they represent firm-specific variables, which explain the variance of FV and enhance the internal validity of the study, limiting the influence of confounding and other external variables. For instance, the tangibility of assets might be used as collateral, which also is related to a higher possibility of obtaining external financing (high leverage) and influence on the FV (Titman and Wessels 1988). Moreover, large firms are more diverse economically, showing less risk of bankruptcy, and their FV will maintain stability or increase its performance (Rajan and Zingales 1995). Liquidity might influence positively and negatively the capital-structure decisions. Liquidity ratios might be related to higher debt ratios by incurring short-term debt, while the high agency cost of liquidity reveals limits of debt financing provided by creditors, and the firm performance will be affected by the liquidity decisions (Ozkan 2001). Finally, the net interest payment is related to the net profit margin, showing that an increase in the firm’s stock value is reflected in a higher FV (Modigliani and Miller 1958).

3.2.1. Leverage and FV

In Equation (1), the coefficient β 1 measures the relationship between leverage and FV. If β 1 is negative, the pecking-order theory and agency-cost theory prevail in Korean firms.
F V i , t = β 0 + β 1 L e v i , t + β 2 T a n g i , t + β 3 S i z e i , t + β 4 L i q i , t + β 5 N e t I n t P a y i , t + j = 1 n β j I n d u s t r y i , t + k = 9 f β k Y e a r i , t + ε i , t ,
where F V i , t is composed of (1) T o b i n s   Q i , t denoted as T o b i n s   Q i , t = E q u i t y   m a r k e t   v a l u e   +   l i a b i l i t i e s   m a r k e t   v a l u e E q u i t y   b o o k   v a l u e   +   l i a b i l i t i e s   b o o k   v a l u e i , t , and (2) P r i c e t o b o o k i , t ratio, calculated using P r i c e t o b o o k   r a t i o i , t = M a r k e t   p e r   s h a r e B o o k   v a l u e   p e r   s h a r e i , t . L e v i , t is the debt ratio composed of total debt ratio L e v i , t , short-term debt ratio S t L e v i , t , and long-term debt ratio L t L e v i , t denoted as L e v i , t = C u r r e n t   l i a b i l i t i e s   +   N o n c u r r e n t   l i a b i l i t i e s T o t a l   a s s e t s i , t , S t L e v i , t = C u r r e n t   l i a b i l i t i e s T o t a l   a s s e t s i , t , L t L e v i , t = N o n c u r r e n t   l i a b i l i t i e s T o t a l   a s s e t s i , t , T a n g i , t = N e t   f i x e d   a s s e t s T o t a l   a s s e t s i , t is the asset tangibility, S i z e i , t = L o g T o t a l   a s s e t s i , t is the size of the firm represented with the natural logarithm of total assets, L i q i , t = C u r r e n t   a s s e t s C u r r e n t   l i a b i l i t i e s i , t is the firm liquidity, N e t I n t P a y i , t = I n t e r e s t   i n c o m e I n t e r e s t   e x p e n s e s T o t a l   a s s e t s i , t is the net interest payment. The dummy terms I n d u s t r y i , t and Y e a r i , t represent a firm’s industry (there are eight non-financial industries listed on the Korean Composite Stock Price Index [KOSPI]), and the year of information, respectively, and ε i , t is the error term. The subscripts i and t denote the firm and fiscal year, respectively.

3.2.2. CG and FV

In Equation (2), we expect a positive coefficient for β 1 because strong-CG practices might increase the FV through effective corporate control and confidence.
F V i , t = β 0 + β 1 C G S i , t + β 3 T a n g i , t + β 4 S i z e i , t + β 5 L i q i , t + β 6 N e t I n t P a y i , t + j = 1 n β j   I n d u s t r y i , t + k = 9 f β k   Y e a r i , t + ε i , t ,
where C G S i , t is the CGS of firm i in year t. It is composed of shareholder rights C G 1 i , t , board structure C G 2 i , t , disclosure C G 3 i , t , audit organization C G 4 i , t , and error management C G 5 i , t , and, thus, C G S i , t = L o g   ( C G 1 + C G 2 + C G 3 + C G 4 + C G 5 ) i , t for firm i in year t.

3.2.3. Leverage, CG, and FV

In Equations (3) and (4), coefficients β 1 and β 2 measure the relationship between (i) leverage and FV and (ii) CG and FV, respectively. In Equation (4), we introduce the interaction term C G S i , t × L e v i , t in our model. The coefficient β 3 is the result of our third hypothesis, which indicates the interaction effect of CG on the relationship between leverage and FV
F V i , t = β 0 + β 1 L e v i , t + β 2 C G S i , t + β 3 T a n g i , t + β 4 S i z e i , t + β 5 L i q i , t + β 6 N e t I n t P a y i , t + j = 1 n β j   I n d u s t r y i , t + k = 9 f β k   Y e a r i , t + ε i , t
F V i , t = β 0 + β 1 L e v i , t + β 2 C G S i , t + β 3 C G S i , t × L e v i , t + β 4 T a n g i , t + β 5 S i z e i , t + β 6 L i q i , t + β 7 N e t I n t P a y i , t + j = 1 n β j   I n d u s t r y i , t + k = 9 f β k   Y e a r i , t + ε i , t ,
where C G S i , t × L e v i , t is the interaction term between CG and the leverage of firm i in year t. The research representation of this manuscript is presented in Figure 1.

4. Sample Statistics

Our initial sample consists of 265 Korean non-financial firms listed on the KOSPI (Fama and French 1992) with 1060 firm–year observations during the 2017–2020 period. To be considered in the final sample, the firms must have shown completed financial information for four years (four financial periods). Moreover, extreme values and outliers were dropped in the initial sample using the interquartile-range method and confidence intervals with two standard deviations (Gujarati 1988). The final sample contains 860 firm–year observations of 215 Korean non-financial firms, resulting in 215 firm–year observations per year. The final database is formed by eight non-financial industries listed on the KOSPI. Table 1 shows the composition of the final sample.
The information on firms is obtained from the webpage of S&P and KisValue version 3.2 (Kis-Value Version 3.2 2018). KisValue is a financial database of Korean firms. IBM SPSS Statistics version 26 was employed as software to process all data and provide descriptive and inference statistics.
Table 2 describes all statistics for dependent, independent, and control variables. The dependent variables, Tobin’s Q and price-to-book ratio, are considered driving factors of investment decisions. The average value of Tobin’s Q is close to zero, showing that the stocks might be undervalued. The mean value of the price-to-book ratio is lower than one, suggesting solid investments in the long term given that many investors use the price-to-book ratio to find undervalued stocks, to be rewarded in the future. Moreover, the debt ratio can be interpreted as the proportion of a firm’s assets that are financed with debt. Its mean value is below one, meaning that a greater portion of the firm’s assets is funded using equity. Finally, the principal CG component is shareholders’ rights, given its mean value.
Table 3 shows that Tobin’s Q and price-to-book ratio had a significant negative and positive correlation with leverage and CG proxies, respectively. Moreover, leverage showed a significant positive linear association with board structure, disclosure, and audit organization, while it presented a significant negative correlation with CGS, shareholder rights, and error management. The correlation values themselves were not enough to increase the multi-collinearity problem (Gujarati 1988).

5. Regression Analysis

5.1. Relationship between Leverage and FV

Table 4 shows the results of linear regression between leverage and FV. There is a significant negative relationship between all leverage metrics and FV at the 1% level. Therefore, the first hypothesis of this study is accepted. Moreover, the F-statistic is significantly higher for all models and the Durbin–Watson statistic is close to 2.0.
The results are supported by two theories, the pecking order and the agency cost (Fama and French 1998; González 2013); thus, the level of debt acts as a disciplinary financial tool (Cheng et al. 2010). The authors (Jiraporn et al. 2008) showed that debt is an active mechanism to protect poor investors because leverage might substitute or accompany CG strategies to reduce agency conflicts.
The results show that financial distress is costly, meaning that leveraged firms will deal with the greatest operating problems. The authors (Opler and Titman 1994) showed that highly leveraged firms experience lower operating profits and lose market shares in American firms.
Similar findings were supported previously. The author (González 2013) showed a meaningful negative relationship between debt and firm performance using a sample of 39 developed and developing countries, suggesting that highly leveraged firms might show a deterioration in operating performance and FV. Moreover, he mentioned that the legal instruments and legal system might influence the degree of leverage in firms. The authors (Onaolapo and Kajola 2010) and (Pratomo and Ismail 2006) found that leverage has a significant negative effect on FV in Nigerian and Malaysian firms, respectively. Both studies showed the prevalence of agency theory.
The control variables Size and NetIntPay showed a significant positive effect in the regression model, while asset tangibility and liquidity performed a negative effect on FV. These findings revealed that managers’ decision depends on the levels of assets and liabilities (current and noncurrent for both cases). Managers prefer to cover interest and principal payments, which also decreases the managers’ discretion and limits the firm’s financial position. Moreover, large firms show higher FV, suggesting a positive relationship between size and FV.

5.2. Relationship between CG and FV

CG is the system of management and supervision to achieve the aims of the firm. It is considered the mechanism to evaluate and control the risk of a firm using appropriate accountability and regulation systems to guarantee that its application is successful. Strong-CG structures allow firms to generate added value through processes, innovation, and research activities. CG systems have improved permanently since the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis. CG is indispensable for firms to generate and increase a philosophy of consciousness, transparency, and accountability, which might include firms’ value creation and financial wealth (Detthamrong et al. 2017).
Table 5 confirmed that all CG metrics have a significant (at least at the 10% level) positive relationship with FV. Hypothesis 2 is accepted, showing that a suitable governance system decreases the firm’s depreciation, because of the decrease in the fight of interest between parties and the decay of information asymmetry. A strong-CG structure is an active instrument to show the fundamental value of a firm (Tulcanaza-Prieto and Lee 2022b).
Prior studies showed that firms adopt governance structure to maximize their FV (Black et al. 2006; Klapper and Love 2004; Liu et al. 2012; Tulcanaza-Prieto and Lee 2022a, 2022b). Notably, board directors and board structures monitor key activities and costs, review the organizational complexity, and approve strategic decisions (Liu et al. 2012; Uchida 2011). The board structure might offer improved admission to financial information and follow the decision-making process of managers, which increase the FV. Moreover, audit organization provides additional safeguards, meets required standards, and promotes best practices. Specifically, an audit committee decreases the asymmetry of the information problem between parties and improves the monitoring of management because it primarily oversees the financial-reporting process of the firm and ensures the high quality of corporate financial reporting. Firms with a competent audit organization might decrease their accounting scandals, which is traduced in a better FV in the short and long term (Aldamen et al. 2012; Klein 2002).
The defense of shareholder’s rights introduces additional monitoring of financial reports, raises the value of auditing standards, contributes to agendas of social responsibility, and raises transparency in financial reports, showing that extensive supervisory control decreases the probability of managers exercising discretion in all processes, which also increases the FV (Geiger and North 2013; Lopes 2018; Tulcanaza-Prieto et al. 2020a). Moreover, disclosure and error management are positively associated with FV because both characteristics provide efficiency and transparency in operational and financial procedures in a firm because of the higher information quality, the diversification of firms’ risk, and the reduction of consecutive errors, which also provide financial stability to the investors (Foerster et al. 2013).

5.3. Relationship between Leverage, CG (with Interaction Effect), and FV

The findings of Table 6 show a positive relationship between CG and FV and the interaction variable (leverage × CG) and FV, while all regressions show an insignificant positive relationship between leverage and FV. The interaction variable and FV show a statistically significant coefficient, suggesting that CG exercises a moderating effect in the relationship between leverage and FV because the significance of the CG coefficient prevails compared to the leverage coefficient. Therefore, Hypothesis 3 is accepted.
CG might reduce the agency problem because it provides the correct atmosphere of accountability, faith, and transparency in a firm. On one hand, firms with weak CG are more significantly leveraged than firms with strong CG, showing poorer FV (Jiraporn et al. 2012). On the other hand, strong-CG mechanisms might reduce agency costs and managers reduce the financial leverage of the firm, which also maximizes the FV (Wen et al. 2002). The results show that CG metrics exercise a significant positive influence on the FV, which also decreases the financial leverage of Korean firms. Our results imply that monitoring, supervising, and controlling tools are effective mechanisms to protect shareholders’ rights, promote transparency and reliability in firms, induce information disclosure, and reduce error management. Strong-CG tools reduce the individualistic conduct and performance of managers, provoking the increase in FV. Our results of the moderating effects of CG inductively support the management-entrenchment hypotheses and the agency costs of debt, motivating the negative relationship between leverage and FV.
Previous studies did not analyze the combined effect of CG, leverage, and FV. They tested separately the relationship between leverage and FV, and CG and FV. Other studies focused on financial leverage as a mediator variable in the relationship between FV and CG. These studies argued that CG does not influence FV directly, but rather modifies FV indirectly through financial leverage (Kijkasiwat et al. 2022). However, these findings were debated by (Detthamrong et al. 2017)’s study because they showed that financial leverage does not modify the effect of CG on FV in Thai small firms. However, they suggested (but did not prove) that CG exerts an indirect effect on FV via financial leverage. Our study covered this gap proving the moderating effect of CG in the relationship between FV and leverage. However, it is also important to notice that our conclusion could not be stable because of relatively high values of the variance inflation factor in explanatory variables (Marcoulides and Raykov 2018).

5.4. Robustness Tests

5.4.1. Analysis of the Leverage Difference between Firms with High and Low Levels of CG

The study employs Tobin’s Q as the main proxy for FV in the robustness check given it represents the market value of assets and its intrinsic value, showing its undervaluation or overvaluation to forecast the capital investment in the future. The study classified firms with high and low levels of CG according to their quartile. Firms with firm–year observations having a CGS higher than 2.26583 (quartile 3) were classified as firms with a high level of CG, whereas those with firm–year observations with a CGS lower than 2.14246 (quartile 1) were classified as firms with a low level of CG. Our sample is composed of 215 firm–year observations for each group. The sample was classified into two groups to recognize the level of predilection for financial leverage and its effect on FV.
Table 7 shows the results of the t-test for equality of means using independent samples. The average of all dependent and independent variables was statistically different for firms with high and low levels of CG, showing that the mean of Tobin’s Q in firms with strong CG was higher than its value in firms with weak CG, while the mean of leverage is lower in firms with a high level of CG than its value in firms with a low level of CG. CG mechanisms might influence managers to diminish their behavior and demotivate them to raise unnecessary financial debt. The interaction term between leverage and CG might lose the relationship between both variables. We expect a weak negative relationship for a strong-CG sample and a strong negative relationship for a weak-CG sample.
We compare the relationship between leverage and FV with strong-CG firms to that of weak-CG firms (Table 8).
CG practices might act as effective corporate-control tools to reduce the probability for entrenched managers to use discretion to decide to leverage above the optimal level, which may not necessarily reduce FV, respectively. Firms characterized by strong-CG practices may show a negative relationship between leverage and FV than those with weak-CG practices may do. On the other hand, if the negative relationship between leverage and FV is due to the traditional view, the discipline of CG practices may not be effective in moderating the relationship. We may not observe any statistical significance on the difference in the relationship between the two groups.
As we mentioned earlier, the agency costs of debt stimulate the negative relationship between leverage and FV, given that leverage inspires stockholders’ strategies against bondholders such as through enchanting large risks, engaging in under investment, or milking properties. The higher the level of leverage is, the more there is probability for stockholders to engage in selfish strategies, and the lower the FV is, respectively. Appropriate governance structures defend the interests of all stakeholders and include autonomy of the board, management, and committees, access to clear information, disclosure, and high-level audit boards, and thus, all mechanisms might reduce agency conflicts of debt, while a weak CG might increase information asymmetry and increase agency conflicts of debt. Therefore, CG could loosen the negative relationship between leverage and FV.
If the moderating role of CG on the relationship between leverage and FV is reinforced, the probability could decrease that the management exercises his or her discretion over the financial resources of a firm. We may observe that the level of leverage with strong CG is lower or at least not higher than with weak CG. If the moderating role of CG is true, it is also plausible that the chance for management to expropriate bondholders’ wealth (the source of agent costs of debt) would decrease. Therefore, management with a strong CG would have less incentive to increase leverage to take advantage of agency costs of debt than that with a weak CG. The level of leverage with a strong CG could be lower than that with a lower CG, respectively.

5.4.2. Analysis 2SLS Regression

To reinforce the conclusion that CG moderates the relationship between leverage and FV and to control the endogeneity problem, we employed Equations (5) and (6) using 2SLS regression analysis. Both equations provide econometric specifications (Black et al. 2006). In the first stage, we ran Tobin’s Q and CGS controlled by “Size_Dummy” and “Size”. In the second stage, we ran the model using the results from the first stage.
First stage:
C G S i , t = β 0 + β 1 T o b i n s   Q i , t + β 2 S i z e _ D u m m y i , t + β 3 S i z e i , t + ε i , t ,
Second stage:
T o b i n s   Q i , t = α 0 + α 1 C G S i , t + α 2 L e v i , t + α 3 T a n g i , t + α 4 S i z e i , t + α 5 L i q i , t + α 6 N e t I n t P a y i , t + j = 1 n α j   I n d u s t r y i , t + k = 8 f α k   Y e a r i , t + ε i , t ,
where “Size_Dummy” = 1, if total assets ≥ KRW 2 trillion, and 0 otherwise, given firms with assets of over KRW 2 trillion are obligatory to have an audit committee. The results of the second stage of 2SLS regression in Table 9 show a positive relationship between CG and FV, which supports the earlier findings (Hypothesis 2, Table 5 and Table 6). Moreover, the coefficient of the interaction term is significant and positive, suggesting that CG moderates the relationship between leverage and FV (Hypothesis 3, Table 6). CG reduces the likelihood for the management to raise exaggeratedly the firm’s leverage. CG might be considered an effective mechanism to reduce agency conflict between parties and decrease the opportunistic behavior of managers, which also increases the firms’ efficiency and raises the FV.
The introduction of CG policies in a firm increases transparency because of the access to public information; it decreases the agency costs; declines asymmetric information between parties; reduces the manager’s opportunistic behavior; increases the supervisory role of owners and shareholders; improves the quality of financial reporting; and elevates the reliability of firms. The authors (Kim et al. 2003; Persons 1995) argued that large firms usually show strong corporate mechanisms with internal control systems, which also decrease the possibility of fraud and unusual activities. Moreover, the size of a firm might be considered as an extra signal to sustain our third hypothesis that CG acts as a moderating variable and prevents excessive indebtedness in a firm.

5.4.3. Analysis of GMM Regression

We employ a second method to control the endogeneity problem, which is GMM with first-order difference models. GMM with one lag in the studied variable solves the endogeneity problem because it reduces the unobserved effects and creates equal-sided conditions between the explanatory variables and error term (Arellano and Bond 1991; Arellano and Bover 1995). Equations (7) and (8) show the test for the endogenous relationship between FV and leverage and FV and CGS.
T o b i n s   Q i , t = α 0 + α 1 L e v i , t 1 + α 2 T a n g i , t + α 3 S i z e i , t + α 4 L i q i , t + α 5 N e t I n t P a y i , t + ε i , t ,
T o b i n s   Q i , t = α 0 + α 1 C G S i , t 1 + α 2 T a n g i , t + α 3 S i z e i , t + α 4 L i q i , t + α 5 N e t I n t P a y i , t + ε i , t
The results of GMM are presented in Table 10. Findings revealed a negative relationship between leverage and FV (Hypothesis 1) and a positive relationship between CG and FV (Hypothesis 2). When the interaction term (Lev × CGS) is introduced in the model, there is a persistent positive effect of CGS over FV, while the negative relationship between leverage and FV is loosened by the moderating effect of CG (Hypothesis 3). We conclude that the agency cost of debt predicts a negative relationship between leverage and FV; however, CG might lessen the degree of the relationship between both variables using the properties of agency cost of debt.
The study did not employ the difference-in-difference method because this quasi-experimental technique compares changes in outcomes over time between two different populations, the treatment group and the comparison group (Gujarati 1988). However, in our sample, we do not differentiate both groups. We showed firms divided into firms with high and low levels of CG, using the third and first quartile values of CGS, but the general sample does not have a control group given the conditions to stay in the final sample (see Section 4).

6. Conclusions

This study analyzes the simultaneous relationship and joint effect between leverage, CG and FV using a sample of 860 firm–year observations of non-financial firms listed on the KOSPI from 2017 to 2020. We proved three hypotheses in the study using Tobin’s Q and price-to-book as proxies of FV. First, we found that the effect of leverage is significantly negative on FV, revealing the prevalence of the management-entrenchment hypothesis and the agency cost of debt. Second, we find that all six CG metrics exercise a significant and positive influence on FV. CG supervises, controls, and assesses the risk of a firm using an accurate accountability system. This result implies that CG may increase the FV using the implementation of innovation, research, transparency, high information quality, diversification of the firm’s risk, and added value in its products and services, which impact the long-term financial wealth of a firm. Appropriate CG structure may decrease the agency problem between parties, which results in influencing the fundamental value of a firm positively. Third, by introducing an interaction variable (Lev × CG), we showed that CG moderates the negative relationship between leverage and FV. Specifically, the leverage coefficient lost its significance in the presence of CG mechanisms, while CG and the interaction term significantly positively influence FV. These results indicate that the CG mechanism could exercise effective control in a firm. It reduces the opportunistic behavior of managers related to leverage so that firm performance is improved. Previous studies tested individually the relationship between leverage and FV, and CG and FV, or they introduced leverage as a mediator variable between CG and FV. However, their findings were not statistically supported given the insignificant influence of leverage in the relationship. Our manuscript shows the importance of CG as a mediator variable in the relationship between leverage and FV. This conclusion, however, may be premature, because the empirical design is limited to only one country and over four years. Moreover, another limitation of the study is the possibility of facing multicollinearity problems (especially in Table 6) given the higher values of the variance inflation factor.
Moreover, an additional analysis is conducted by dividing the total sample into two groups of high level of CG and low level of CG. We find the negative relationship between leverage and FV becomes weak for firms with a high level of CG, while it stays strong for firms with low levels of CG. This result is consistent with our conclusion that an effective CG mechanism may prevent managers from engaging in opportunistic behavior or transferring wealth from debt holders. We also find firms characterized by high-level CG are leveraged less than firms with low levels of CG. This result may imply that managers could give up debt financing to understand the difficulty of selfish decision making in an environment of high-level CG.
Furthermore, we employed a 2SLS regression model and GMM model to control the endogeneity problem. The results reinforced our previous findings that CG limited the managerial opportunistic behavior and improved FV, accordingly.
Previous studies did not test the joint relationship between CG, leverage, and FV. Generally, authors performed individual relationships between (i) CG and FV and (ii) leverage and FV. In the Indonesian market, Budiharjo (2021) showed that good CG (measured by the audit committee) and leverage positively influence FV. Similarly, Baihaqqi et al. (2023)’s findings revealed that leverage negatively influences FV while CG (measured by independent commissioner) does not affect FV, showing lower profits in higher leveraged firms and that an independent commissioner does not necessarily increase the effectiveness of firms. Finally, Memon et al. (2019) argued that optimal leverage and strong CG are essential tools for increasing the FV. The authors also considered the age of the firm in their models, proving that the degree of individual relationships between CG and FV, and leverage and FV depend on the firm age. Previous studies’ findings are aligned with our results of individual relationships between CG, leverage, and FV. However, our study provides the combined effect of variables. Moreover, our findings of the moderating role of CG are supported by the degree of effectiveness of CG in firms because it provides control tools to monitor the behavior and decisions of managers and check the performance of firms continuously. In this sense, our findings may provide additional evidence to support the agency costs of debt or the entrenchment hypothesis, which have been for a long time controversial in the literature on capital structure.
For future research, authors might consider the inclusion of the tenure structure given the prevalence of family firms in the Korean market, and introduce the existence of bonuses in the model to verify the degree and prevalence of the opportunistic behavior of managers. Moreover, researchers may provide more stable and robust evidence by enlarging the database by including international data or by expanding the period of data.

Author Contributions

All authors contributed extensively to the work presented in this paper. Writing—original draft, A.B.T.-P.; writing—review and editing, A.B.T.-P. and W.A.-F.; supervision, Y.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

We extend our gratitude and acknowledgment to the Universidad de Las Américas, which financially supported this research (EDN.ATP.23.13.01).

Data Availability Statement

The datasets used and analyzed in this study are available from the corresponding author on justified request.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest. The funders had no role in the design of the study; in the collection, analyses, or interpretation of data; in the writing of the manuscript; or in the decision to publish the results.

References

  1. Abdullah, Hariem, and Turgut Tursoy. 2021. Capital Structure and Firm Performance: Evidence of Germany under IFRS Adoption. Review of Managerial Science 15: 379–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Abor, Joshua. 2005. The Effect of Capital Structure on Profitability: An Empirical Analysis of Listed Firms in Ghana. Journal of Risk Finance 6: 16–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Aggarwal, Reena, Isil Erel, René Stulz, and Rohan Williamson. 2007. Governance Practices between U.S. and Foreign Firms: Measurement, Causes and Consequences. Oxford: Oxford University Press. NBER Working Paper Series 13288. [Google Scholar]
  4. Aldamen, Husam, Keith Duncan, Simone Kelly, and Ray McNamara. 2012. Audit Committee Characteristics and Firm Performance during the Global Financial Crisis. Accounting & Finance 52: 971–1000. [Google Scholar]
  5. Altieri, Michela. 2022. Agency Costs of Debt in Conglomerate Firms. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 57: 3048–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Arellano, Manuel, and Olympia Bover. 1995. Another Look at the Instrumental Variable Estimation of Error-Components Models. Journal of Econometrics 68: 29–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Arellano, Manuel, and Stephen Bond. 1991. Some Test of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations. Review of Economic Studies 58: 277–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Baihaqqi, Muhamad, Muhammad Widyanto, and Sri Kurniawati. 2023. How Financial Ratio, Good Corporate Governance, and Firm Size Affect Firm Value in Infraestructure Companies. East African Scholars Journal of Economic, Business and Management 6: 145–54. [Google Scholar]
  9. Black, Bernard, Hasung Jang, and Woochan Kim. 2006. Does Corporate Governance Predict Firm’s Market Values? Evidence from Korea. The Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 22: 366–413. [Google Scholar]
  10. Brown, Lawrence, and Marcus Caylor. 2006. Corporate Governance and Firm Valuation. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 25: 409–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Budiharjo, Roy. 2021. The Effect of Good Corporate Governance and Leverage toward Company Value with Profitability as a Moderating Variable. International Journal of Management Studies and Social Science Research 3: 220–34. [Google Scholar]
  12. Chan-Lau, Jorge. 2001. The Impact of Corporate Governance Structures on the Agency Cost of Debt. International Monetary Fund 1: 1–14. [Google Scholar]
  13. Chen, Jean. 2004. Determinants of Capital Structure of Chinese Listed Companies. Journal of Business Research 57: 1341–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Cheng, Yu-Shu, Yi-Pei Liu, and Chu-Yang Chien. 2010. Capital Structure and Firm Value in China Panel Threshold Regression Analysis. African Journal of Business Management 4: 2500–7. [Google Scholar]
  15. Detthamrong, Umawadee, Nongnit Chancharat, and Chaiporn Vithessonthi. 2017. Corporate Governance, Capital Structure and Firm Performance: Evidence from Thailand. Research in International Business and Finance 42: 689–709. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Durnev, Art, and Han Kim. 2005. To Steal or Not to Steal: Firm Attributes, Legal Environment, and Valuation. Journal of Finance 60: 1461–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Fama, Eugene, and Kenneth French. 1992. The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns. The Journal of Finance 47: 427. [Google Scholar]
  18. Fama, Eugene, and Kenneth French. 1998. Taxes, Financing Decision and Firm Value. The Journal of Finance 53: 819–43. Available online: https://www.jstor.org/stable/117379 (accessed on 10 August 2023). [CrossRef]
  19. Ferentinou, Aikaterini, and Searina Anagnostopoulou. 2016. Accrual-Based and Real Earnings Management before and after IFRS Adoption: The Case of Greece. Journal of Applied Accounting Research 17: 2–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Foerster, Stephen, Stephen Sapp, and Yaqui Shi. 2013. The Effect of Voluntary Disclosure on Firm Risk and Firm Value: Evidence from Management Earnings Forecasts. SSRN Electronic Journal, 1–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Geiger, Marshall, and David North. 2013. Do Strong Shareholder Rights Mitigate Earnings Management? Journal of Accounting, Ethics and Public Policy 14: 289–322. [Google Scholar]
  22. Gompers, Paul, Joy Ishii, and Andrew Metrick. 2003. Corporate Governance and Equity Prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118: 107–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. González, Víctor. 2013. Leverage and Corporate Performance: International Evidence. International Review of Economics and Finance 25: 169–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Gujarati, Damodar. 1988. Basic Econometrics, 2nd ed. New York: McGraw Hill. [Google Scholar]
  25. Harris, Milton, and Artur Raviv. 1991. The Theory of Capital Structure. The Journal of Finance 46: 296–355. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Ibhagui, Oyakhilome, and Felicia Olokoyo. 2018. Leverage and Firm Performance: New Evidence on the Role of Firm Size. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 45: 57–82. Available online: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1062940817302620 (accessed on 1 November 2023). [CrossRef]
  27. Jensen, Michael. 1986. Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. American Economic Review 76: 323–39. [Google Scholar]
  28. Jiraporn, Pornsit, Gary Miller, Soon Suk Yoon, and Young Kim. 2008. Is Earnings Management Opportunistic or Beneficial? An Agency Theory Perspective. International Review of Financial Analysis 17: 622–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Jiraporn, Pornsit, Jang-Chul Kim, Young Sang Kim, and Pattanaporn Kitsabunnarat. 2012. Capital Structure and Corporate Governance Quality: Evidence from the Institutional Shareholder Services (ISS). International Review of Economics and Finance 22: 208–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Kijkasiwat, Ploypailin, Anwar Hussain, and Amna Muntaz. 2022. Corporate Governance, Firm Performance and Financial Leverage across Developed and Emerging Economies. Risks 10: 185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Kim, Yangseon, Caixing Liu, and Stephen Rhee. 2003. The Relation of Earnings Management to Firm Size. Social Science Research Network 4: 81–88. [Google Scholar]
  32. Kis-Value Version 3.2. 2018.
  33. Klapper, Leora, and Inessa Love. 2004. Corporate Governance, Investor Protection and Performance in Emerging Markets. Journal of Corporate Finance 10: 703–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Klein, April. 2002. Audit Committee, Board of Director Characteristics and Earnings Management. Journal of Accounting and Economics 33: 375–400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. La Porta, Rafael, Florencio López-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. 2002. Investor Protection and Corporate Valuation. Journal of Finance 57: 1147–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Lee, Younghwan, Sun Kang, and Sang Min Cho. 2015. The Effect of Voluntary IFRS Adoption by Unlisted Firms on Earnings Quality and the Cost of Debt: Empirical Evidence from Korea. Journal of Business Economics and Management 16: 931–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Lin, Feng-Li, and Tsangyao Chang. 2011. Does Debt Affect Firm Value in Taiwan? A Panel Threshold Regression Analysis. Applied Economics 43: 117–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Liu, Chunyan, Konari Uchida, and Yufeng Yang. 2012. Corporate Governance and Firm Value during the Global Financial Crisis: Evidence from China. International Review of Financial Analysis 21: 70–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Lopes, Ana Paula. 2018. Audit Quality and Earnings Management: Evidence from Portugal. Athens Journal of Business and Economics 4: 179–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Marcoulides, Katerina, and Tenko Raykov. 2018. Evaluation of Variance Inflation Factors in Regression Models Using Latent Variable Modeling Methods. Educational and Psychological Measurement 79: 874–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Memon, Zulfiqar, Yan Chen, and Ayaz Samo. 2019. Corporate Governance, Firm Age, and Leverage: Empirical Evidence from China. Research Journal of Finance and Accounting 10: 19–31. [Google Scholar]
  42. Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller. 1958. The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment. American Economic Review 48: 261–97. [Google Scholar]
  43. Ngatno, Ngatno, Endang P. Apriatni, and Arief Youlianto. 2021. Moderating Effects of Corporate Governance Mechanism on the Relation between Capital Structure and Firm Performance. Cogent Business & Management 8: 1866822. [Google Scholar]
  44. Nwakuya, Moussa, and Marcus Ijomah. 2017. Fixed Effect versus Random Effects Modeling in a Panel Data Analysis: A Consideration of Economic and Political Indicators in Six African Countries. International Journal of Statistics and Applications 7: 275–79. [Google Scholar]
  45. Oke, Simon, and Brus Afolabi. 2011. Capital Structure and Industrial Performance in Nigeria. International Business and Management 2: 100–6. [Google Scholar]
  46. Onaolapo, Abdrahman, and Sunday Kajola. 2010. Capital Structure and Firm Performance: Evidence from Nigeria. European Journal of Economics, Finance, and Administrative Sciences 25: 70–82. [Google Scholar]
  47. Opler, Tim, and Sheridan Titman. 1994. Financial Distress and Corporate Performance. Journal of Finance 49: 1015–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Ozkan, Aydin. 2001. Determinants of Capital Structure and Adjustment to Long Run Target: Evidence from UK Company Panel Data. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 28: 175–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Persons, Obeua. 1995. Using Financial Statement Data to Identify Factors Associated with Fraudulent Financial Reporting. Journal of Applied Business Research 11: 38–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Pratomo, Wahyu, and Abdul Ismail. 2006. Islamic Bank Performance and Capital Structure. MPRA 6012. Available online: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/6012/ (accessed on 10 August 2023).
  51. Rajan, Raghuram G., and Luigi Zingales. 1995. What Do We Know about Capital Structure? Some Evidence from International Data. The Journal of Finance 50: 1421–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Ruland, William, and Ping Zhou. 2005. Debt Diversification and Valuation. Review of Quantitative Financial Accounting 25: 277–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Standard & Poor’s Governance Services. 2004. Criteria, Methodology and Definitions. In Standard & Poor’s Corporate Governance Scores and Evaluations. New York: McGraw-Hill Companies Inc., pp. 1–23. [Google Scholar]
  54. Titman, Sheridan, and Roberto Wessels. 1988. The Determinants of Capital Structure Choice. The Journal of Finance 43: 1–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Tulcanaza-Prieto, Ana Belén, and Younghwan Lee. 2022a. Real Earnings Management and Firm Value Using Quarterly Financial Data: Evidence from Korea. Global Business & Finance Review 27: 50–64. [Google Scholar]
  56. Tulcanaza-Prieto, Ana Belén, and Younghwan Lee. 2022b. Real Earnings Management, Firm Value, and Corporate Governance: Evidence from the Korean Market. International Journal of Financial Studies 10: 19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Tulcanaza-Prieto, Ana Belén, HoKyun Shin, Younghwan Lee, and Chang Won Lee. 2020a. Relationship among CSR Initiatives and Financial and Non-Financial Corporate Performance in the Ecuadorian Banking Environment. Sustainability 12: 1621. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Tulcanaza-Prieto, Ana Belén, Younghwan Lee, and Jeong-Ho Koo. 2020b. Leverage, Corporate Governance and Real Earnings Management: Evidence from Korean Market. Global Business & Finance Review 4: 51–72. [Google Scholar]
  59. Uchida, Konari. 2011. Does Corporate Board Downsize Increase Shareholder Value? Evidence from Japan. International Review of Economics and Finance 20: 562–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Wen, Yu, Kami Rwegasira, and Jan Bilderbeek. 2002. Corporate Governance and Capital Structure Decisions of the Chinese Listed Firms. International Review of Corporate Governance 10: 75–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Wruck, Karen. 1990. Financial Distress, Reorganization and Organizational Efficiency. Journal of Financial Economics 27: 419–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Yoon, Soon Suk, Gary Miller, and Pornsit Jiraporn. 2006. Earnings Management Vehicles for Korean Firms. Journal of International Financial Management & Accounting 17: 85–109. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Research model.
Figure 1. Research model.
Risks 12 00011 g001
Table 1. Sample selection and distribution per industry.
Table 1. Sample selection and distribution per industry.
DetailNo.
Initial number of firms265
(−) Firms with incomplete information for four years42
(−) Firms with extreme values and outliers8
=Final number of firms215
Number of firms per industryNo.
Communications26
Construction27
Electrical and electronic equipment27
Electricity and gas26
Food and beverages26
Non-metallic-mineral production29
Paper and wood28
Transport and storage26
Final number of firms per industry215
Table 2. Descriptive statistics.
Table 2. Descriptive statistics.
Variables MeanStd. Dev. MinLower Quartile (Q1)MedianUpper Quartile (Q3) Max
Dependent variables
Tobin’s Q0.0300.054−0.2020.0050.0300.0570.287
Price-to-book ratio0.5630.1810.0060.4250.5730.7110.900
Independent variables
Lev 0.4370.1810.0960.2890.4270.5760.935
CGS2.2110.1011.9022.1422.2102.2662.599
CG11.7260.0791.3471.6791.7361.7861.897
CG21.2000.1730.5741.0971.2111.2731.923
CG31.3320.1990.8541.1961.3011.4561.887
CG41.6330.1460.9031.5561.6231.7321.982
CG51.1370.6550.0001.0001.4771.6021.954
Control variables
Tang0.3230.1740.0050.1860.3020.4450.922
Size19.8771.48716.18518.84819.50720.48125.824
Liq1.7391.1410.2130.9741.4222.1377.782
NetIntPay−0.0070.012−0.097−0.013−0.0050.0010.023
Table 3. Pearson correlation matrix.
Table 3. Pearson correlation matrix.
Tobin’s QPrice-to-Book RatioLevCGSCG1CG2CG3CG4CG5TangSizeLiqNetIntPay
Tobin’s Q1
Price-to-book ratio0.538 ***1
Lev−0.442 ***−0.311 ***1
CGS0.193 ***0.196 ***−0.097 ***1
CG10.069 **0.049 **−0.127 ***0.439 ***1
CG20.125 ***0.110 ***0.096 ***0.571 ***0.0281
CG30.137 ***0.137 ***0.030 ***0.641 ***0.144 ***0.514 ***1
CG40.034 ***0.052 **0.094 ***0.598 ***0.086 **0.447 ***0.454 ***1
CG50.181 ***0.208 ***−0.220 ***0.586 ***0.161 ***0.071 **0.119 ***−0.010 ***1
Tang−0.172 ***−0.154 ***0.197 ***0.006−0.0010.030−0.0460.059−0.0651
Size0.097 ***0.086 **0.097 ***0.542 ***0.0380.614 ***0.616 ***0.572 ***0.068 **0.081 **1
Liq0.308 ***0.235 ***−0.715 ***0.084 **0.193 ***−0.118 ***−0.026−0.0600.178 ***−0.268 ***−0.091 ***1
NetIntPay0.456 ***0.390 ***−0.635 ***0.217 ***0.122 ***0.0360.173 ***−0.0020.253 ***−0.234 ***0.094 ***0.514 ***1
Note: *** and ** indicate statistical significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.
Table 4. Relationship between leverage and FV.
Table 4. Relationship between leverage and FV.
VariablesTobin’s QPrice-to-Book Ratio
Lev−0.080 *** −0.021 ***
(−5.428)
[3.075]
(−3.161)
[3.259]
StLev −0.037 ***
(−3.287)
[2.261]
−0.083 ***
LtLev (−4.248)
[1.760]
Tang−0.025 ***−0.029 ***−0.012 **−0.029 **
(−2.669)
[1.194]
(−2.940)
[1.281]
(−2.195)
[1.287]
(−2.492)
[1.203]
Size0.004 ***0.003 ***0.006 ***0.004 ***
(4.004)
[1.154]
(2.777)
[1.195]
(4.770)
[1.344]
(3.022)
[1.154]
Liq−0.002 *0.002 *0.004 **−0.001 **
(−1.900)
[2.192]
(1.852)
[2.202]
(2.425)
[1.482]
(−2.096)
[2.219]
NetIntPay0.206 ***0.604 ***1.431 ***0.437 ***
(6.517)
[1.973]
(9.502)
[1.597]
(8.229)
[1.721]
(5.903)
[2.111]
Intercept0.0060.005−0.056−0.009
(0.261)(0.186)(−1.332)(−0.310)
Year—fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Industry—fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Adj. R20.3090.2890.2990.212
F-Stat.26.549 ***24.251 ***25.466 ***12.535 ***
DW1.9631.8931.9091.949
Note: Beta corresponds to unstandardized coefficients. Numbers inside the parentheses are t-statistics. Numbers inside the brackets are the values of the variance inflation factor. ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Table 5. Relationship between CG and FV.
Table 5. Relationship between CG and FV.
VariablesTobin’s QPrice-to-Book Ratio
CGS0.045 ** 0.053 **
(2.378) (2.200)
[1.555] [1.568]
CG1 0.011 **
(2.538)
[1.102]
CG2 0.034 ***
(2.759)
[1.934]
CG3 0.019 *
(1.859)
[1.740]
CG4 0.006 **
(2.450)
[1.582]
CG5 0.006 ***
(2.621)
[1.111]
Tang−0.023 **−0.023 **−0.022 **−0.022 **−0.023 **−0.022 **−0.028 **
(−2.361)(−2.398)(−2.295)(−2.244)(−2.421)(−2.321)(−2.368)
[1.193][1.193][1.195][1.202][1.192][1.194][1.202]
Size0.0020.004 ***0.0010.0020.004 ***0.004 ***0.002
(1.602)(3.368)(1.001)(1.628)(2.986)(3.213)(1.320)
[1.575][1.142][1.799][1.732][1.714][1.142][1.572]
Liq0.004 **0.004 ***0.005 ***0.005 ***0.004 ***0.004 **0.001 ***
(2.501)(2.686)(2.815)(2.741)(2.640)(2.481)(2.618)
[1.482][1.514][1.483][1.482][1.478][1.483][1.509]
NetIntPay0.671 ***0.712 ***0.710 ***0.673 ***0.705 ***0.636 ***0.512 ***
(10.185)(10.523)(10.561)(10.223)(10.451)(9.943)(7.231)
[1.496][1.474][1.474][1.498][1.483][1.520][1.568]
Intercept−0.091 **−0.005−0.019−0.019−0.020−0.027−0.098 **
(−2.487)(−0.120)(−0.849)(−0.841)(−0.856)(−1.183)(−2.111)
Year—fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry—fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Adj. R20.2890.2850.2910.2870.2850.2900.216
F-Stat.24.291 ***23.782 ***24.476 ***24.083 ***23.774 ***24.406 ***12.836 ***
DW1.9912.0822.0861.9882.1832.0952.063
Note: Beta corresponds to unstandardized coefficients. Numbers inside the parentheses are t-statistics. Numbers inside the brackets are the values of the variance inflation factor. ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Table 6. The interaction effect of CG on the relationship between leverage and FV.
Table 6. The interaction effect of CG on the relationship between leverage and FV.
VariablesTobin’s QPrice-to-Book Ratio
Lev1.3792.5630.3880.6750.0150.6520.219
(0.827)(1.479)(0.707)(1.298)(0.016)(0.791)(0.901)
[3.227][3.086][3.589][3.610][3.886][5.691][3.851]
CGS0.771 *** 0.100 ***
(3.124) (2.866)
[7.895] [7.734]
CG1 0.546 ***
(3.147)
[8.395]
CG2 0.669 ***
(3.078)
[8.420]
CG3 0.620 ***
(3.410)
[7.762]
CG4 0.143 ***
(2.598)
[7.068]
CG5 0.053 ***
(2.943)
[8.093]
Lev × CGS0.927 ** 0.108 ***
(2.238) (1.966)
[3.454] [2.209]
Lev × CG1 1.091 **
(2.086)
[2.584]
Lev× CG2 0.868 **
(2.004)
[5.209]
Lev× CG3 1.002 **
(2.121)
[6.520]
Lev× CG4 0.418 **
(2.090)
[1.667]
Lev × CG5 0.013 **
(2.116)
[3.085]
Tang−0.216 ***−0.217 ***−0.205 **−0.213 ***−0.215 ***−0.211 **−0.029 **
(−2.649)(−2.654)(−2.515)(−2.610)(−2.630)(−2.577)(−2.434)
[1.196][1.195][1.197][1.206][1.196][1.205][1.205]
Size0.025 **0.037 ***0.020 ***0.026 **0.040 ***0.036 ***0.002 **
(2.300)(3.943)(2.662)(2.262)(3.464)(3.866)(2.491)
[1.603][1.161][1.823][1.753][1.748][1.159][1.596]
Liq−0.016−0.011−0.007−0.008−0.013−0.016−0.003
(−0.954)(−0.638)(−0.398)(−0.452)(−0.774)(−0.922)(−0.105)
[2.196][2.308][2.263][2.241][2.238][2.235][2.221]
NetIntPay0.033 ***0.325 ***0.243 ***0.842 ***0.303 ***0.950 ***0.371 ***
(6.308)(6.496)(6.482)(6.180)(6.474)(6.230)(5.605)
[1.991][1.975][1.976][2.008][1.979][2.003][2.146]
Intercept0.536 ***2.955 ***1.528 ***1.387 ***1.714 ***1.965 ***−0.197 *
(2.666)(3.484)(4.730)(4.408)(3.914)(9.474)(−1.668)
Year—fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry—fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Adj. R20.3120.3080.3160.3170.3070.3110.216
F-Stat.23.955 ***23.484 ***24.374 ***24.407 ***23.427 ***23.809 ***21.464 ***
DW1.9191.9181.9291.9331.9211.9122.063
Note: Beta corresponds to unstandardized coefficients. Numbers inside the parentheses are t-statistics. Numbers inside the brackets are the values of the variance inflation factor. ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Table 7. T-test for equality of means for firms with high and low levels of CG.
Table 7. T-test for equality of means for firms with high and low levels of CG.
VariableFirms with High Level of CGFirms with Low Level of CG Differencet-Value
Tobin’s Q0.0420.0180.0244.291 ***
Lev0.4290.476−0.047−2.780 ***
CGS2.3412.0870.25448.729 ***
CG11.7571.6720.08511.194 ***
CG21.3501.1360.21413.122 ***
CG31.5221.2150.30717.396 ***
CG41.7631.5370.22519.102 ***
CG51.5100.4561.05520.654 ***
Note: *** indicates statistical significance at the 1% level.
Table 8. Relationship between leverage and FV using firms with high and low levels of CG.
Table 8. Relationship between leverage and FV using firms with high and low levels of CG.
VariablesTobin’s Q
Firms with High Level of CGFirms with Low Level of CG
Lev−0.019 −0.109 ***
(−0.581) (−3.226)
[1.866] [3.804]
StLev −0.033 −0.102 ***
(−0.978) (−2.649)
[2.763] [2.572]
LtLev −0.126 −0.078 ***
(−1.468) (−2.620)
[1.478] [3.403]
Tang−0.053 **−0.045 **−0.031−0.044 *−0.054 **−0.031
(−2.523)(−2.041)(−1.407)(−1.828)(−2.145)(−1.223)
[1.255][1.392][1.453][1.482][1.574][1.530]
Size0.0040.0050.007 *0.0040.0020.005 **
(1.149)(1.316)(1.903)(1.687)(0.680)(2.044)
[1.124][1.172][1.260][1.444][1.601][1.722]
Liq0.0080.013 **0.010 **−0.005−0.0060.003
(1.361)(2.294)(2.260)(−1.147)(−1.117)(0.792)
[2.280][2.366][1.446][2.141][2.681][1.593]
NetIntPay1.827 ***2.060 ***1.797 ***1.278 **2.317 ***1.501 **
(4.872)(5.692)(5.378)(2.507)(5.536)(2.412)
[1.782][1.666][1.456][2.415][1.593][3.463]
Intercept−0.001−0.044−0.0660.0480.078−0.028
(−0.010)(−0.556)(−0.881)(1.000)(1.391)(−0.578)
Year—fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry—fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYes
Adj. R20.3700.3720.3870.3350.3200.309
F-Stat.9.962 ***10.037 ***10.658 ***8.177 ***7.725 ***7.380 ***
DW1.7231.7681.7452.0582.0862.025
Note: Beta corresponds to unstandardized coefficients. Numbers inside the parentheses are t-statistics. Numbers inside the brackets are the values of the variance inflation factor. ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Table 9. Relationship results of the 2SLS model.
Table 9. Relationship results of the 2SLS model.
First-Stage Regression Results
Variable CGS
Tobin’s Q0.583 ***
(3.017)
Intercept1.957 ***
(22.87)
Adj. R20.009
F-Stat.9.101 ***
Covariance Tobin’s Q0.094
Second-Stage Regression Results
Variable Tobin’s Q
Lev0.6801.379
(1.384)(0.827)
[3.077][3.227]
CGS0.368 **0.771 **
(2.285)(2.124)
[1.556][7.895]
Lev*CGS 0.927 **
(2.238)
[3.454]
Tang−0.213 ***−0.216 ***
(−2.612)(−2.649)
[1.195][1.196]
Size0.024 **0.025 **
(2.214)(2.300)
[1.594][1.603]
Liq−0.017−0.016
(−0.978)(−0.954)
[2.195][2.196]
NetIntPay0.610 ***0.533 ***
(6.291)(6.308)
[1.991][1.991]
Intercept1.454 ***0.536
(4.632)(0.666)
Quarter—fixed effectsYesYes
Industry—fixed effectsYesYes
Adj. R20.3120.312
F-Stat.25.340 ***23.955 ***
DW1.9131.919
Note: Beta corresponds to unstandardized coefficients. Numbers inside the parentheses are t-statistics. Numbers inside the brackets are the values of the variance inflation factor. *** and ** indicate statistical significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.
Table 10. Relationship results of the GMM regression.
Table 10. Relationship results of the GMM regression.
VariablesTobin’s Q
Levt−1−0.005 ** 0.038
(−2.385) (1.557)
CGSt−1 0.051 **0.062 ***
(2.473)(3.072)
Lev × CGS 0.048 ***
(5.553)
Tang−0.014 **−0.016 **−0.019 *
(−2.247)(−2.220)(−1.763)
Size0.003 **0.001 ***0.002 ***
(2.355)(2.897)(2.653)
Liq0.0030.004−0.003
(1.562)(1.632)(−1.368)
NetIntPay1.782 ***1.768 ***1.248 ***
(8.534)(9.015)(5.596)
Sargan test (p-value)0.9080.8980.874
Note: Numbers inside the parentheses are z-statistics. ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Tulcanaza-Prieto, A.B.; Lee, Y.; Anzules-Falcones, W. The Moderating Role of Corporate Governance in the Relationship between Leverage and Firm Value: Evidence from the Korean Market. Risks 2024, 12, 11. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks12010011

AMA Style

Tulcanaza-Prieto AB, Lee Y, Anzules-Falcones W. The Moderating Role of Corporate Governance in the Relationship between Leverage and Firm Value: Evidence from the Korean Market. Risks. 2024; 12(1):11. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks12010011

Chicago/Turabian Style

Tulcanaza-Prieto, Ana Belén, Younghwan Lee, and Wendy Anzules-Falcones. 2024. "The Moderating Role of Corporate Governance in the Relationship between Leverage and Firm Value: Evidence from the Korean Market" Risks 12, no. 1: 11. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks12010011

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop