Next Article in Journal
Determining Unintentional Island Threshold to Enhance the Reliability in an Electrical Distribution Grid
Next Article in Special Issue
On the Positive Decreasing Solutions of Half-Linear Delay Differential Equations of Even Order
Previous Article in Journal
Stability Analysis of a New Class of Series Type Additive Functional Equation in Banach Spaces: Direct and Fixed Point Techniques
Previous Article in Special Issue
Two Analytical Techniques for Fractional Differential Equations with Harmonic Terms via the Riemann–Liouville Definition
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Mean-Field and Anticipated BSDEs with Time-Delayed Generator

by
Pei Zhang
1,2,
Nur Anisah Mohamed
1,* and
Adriana Irawati Nur Ibrahim
1
1
Institute of Mathematical Sciences, Faculty of Science, Universiti Malaya, Kuala Lumpur 50603, Malaysia
2
School of Mathematics and Statistics, Suzhou University, Suzhou 234000, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Mathematics 2023, 11(4), 888; https://doi.org/10.3390/math11040888
Submission received: 12 December 2022 / Revised: 25 January 2023 / Accepted: 7 February 2023 / Published: 9 February 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Recent Advances in Differential Equations and Applications)

Abstract

:
In this paper, we discuss a new type of mean-field anticipated backward stochastic differential equation with a time-delayed generator (MF-DABSDEs) which extends the results of the anticipated backward stochastic differential equation to the case of mean-field limits, and in which the generator considers not only the present and future times but also the past time. By using the fixed point theorem, we shall demonstrate the existence and uniqueness of the solutions to these equations. Finally, we shall establish a comparison theorem for the solutions.

1. Introduction

Since Pardoux and Peng [1] first proposed a general form of non-linear backward stochastic differential equations (BSDEs) in 1990, the theoretical research of BSDEs has developed rapidly. In our research, we are looking at the case where there exists a pair of adapted processes ( Y · , Z · ) that satisfy the following type of BSDE
Y t = ξ + t T f ( s , Y s , Z s ) d s t T Z s d B s , 0 t T ,
where ξ is the terminal value, f is the generator related to the present time, and B s is a Brownian process. In the last three decades, research on BSDEs has seen significant advances in many fields: for example, various BSDE models and the uniqueness and existence of the solutions to these models (Bahlali et al. [2]; Al-Hussein [3]; Zhang et al. [4]), a new nonlinear expectation named g-expectation which is based on BSDEs (Peng [5]; Luo et al. [6]), the numerical solution of BSDEs (Ma et al. [7]; Gobet et al. [8]; Zhao et al. [9]; Han [10]), the relationship between BSDEs and partial differential equations (PDEs) (Ren and Xia [11]; Pardoux and Răşcanu [12]), and the numerous applications of BSDEs in various areas including optimal control, finance, biology, and physics (for examples, refer to [13,14,15,16,17]).
In numerous fields, including economics and finance, statistical mechanics, physics, and game theory, the use of mathematical mean-field approaches is crucial. Buckdahn et al. [18,19] introduced a new type of BSDE, called the mean-field BSDE, and then demonstrated the existence and uniqueness of the solution for that type of mean-field BSDE, which is given by
Y t = ξ + t T E f ( s , Y s , Z s , Y s , Z s ) d t t T Z s d B s , 0 t T .
Additionally, the authors also showed that in a Markovian setting, mean-field BSDEs generate the viscosity solution of a non-local PDE.
Meanwhile, Peng and Yang [20] initially discussed a fundamental class of BSDEs in 2009, namely, anticipated BSDEs, where
Y t = ξ T + t T f ( s , Y s , Z s , Y s + δ ( s ) , Z s + ζ ( s ) ) d t t T Z s d B s , 0 t T ; Y t = ξ t , T t T + K ; Z t = η t , T t T + K .
The two deterministic R + -valued continuous functions δ ( s ) , ζ ( s ) defined on [ 0 , T ] satisfy (i) t t + δ ( t ) T + K , t t + ζ ( t ) T + K , and (ii) t T f ( s + δ ( s ) ) d s L t T + K f ( s ) d s , t T f ( s + ζ ( s ) ) d s L t T + K f ( s ) d s ; the authors also demonstrated the existence and uniqueness of the solution to the above equations. Feng [21] investigated the uniqueness and existence of the solution of an anticipated BSDE with a reflecting boundary. Wang and Cui [22] also proposed a new type of differential equation called the anticipated backward doubly stochastic differential equation; the authors solved certain stochastic control problems by utilizing the duality between anticipated BSDEs and stochastic differential delay equations. Later, Wang and Yu [23] extended this theory to generalized anticipated backward doubly stochastical differential equations. Henceforth, the amount of study carried out on the combination of mean-field and anticipated BSDEs is progressively growing; for example, Douissi et al. [24] showed a new kind of mean-field anticipated BSDE driven by fractional Brownian motion. Furthermore, Liu and Da [25] focused on mean-field anticipated BSDEs driven by time-changed Lévy noises, while Hao [26] discussed anticipated mean-field BSDEs with jumps.
On the other hand, Delong and Imkeller [27] addressed BSDEs with time-delayed generators as follows:
Y t = ξ + t T f ( s , Y s u ( s ) , Z s v ( s ) ) d t t T Z s d B s , 0 t T ,
where f is a generator that depends on the past value of a solution and 0 u ( s ) T , 0 v ( s ) T .
As a generalisation of Delong and Imkeller [27] or Peng and Yang [20], He et al. [28] investigated a type of delay and anticipated BSDEs. Ma and Liu [29] provided results for the existence and uniqueness of the solution for a mean-field BSDE with an average delay and applied the theoretical results to the study of the infinite-horizon linear-quadratic control issue. Under partial information, Zhuang [30] studied non-zero and differential games for the anticipated forward-backward stochastic differential delay equation, which can be used to resolve a problem involving the management of time-delayed pension funds with non-linear expectations.
However, under the condition of mean-field, the case where the generator considers not only the current time and the future time but also the past time has not been studied yet. Therefore, our study will focus on studying the BSDEs of this case to enrich the theory of BSDEs. This study might then encourage researchers to investigate stochastic optimal control problems more realistically; furthermore, the theory will be useful to connect mean-field BSDEs of this type with non-local PDE.
Based on the motivations discussed above, an essential and meaningful question is that if we construct the mean-field and anticipated BSDEs with a time-delayed generator, how can we prove the existence and uniqueness of its solution? In addition, what about the relative comparison theorem? Firstly, the BSDE model considered in our study is given by
d Y t = E [ f ( t , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t , Z t , Y t , Z t , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ) ] d t Z t d B t , 0 t T ; Y t = ξ t , T t T + K ; Z t = η t , T t T + K .
The rest of the framework for this study is organised as follows. Section 2 introduces some basic information on the new BSDE model that we are proposing, which is the mean-field anticipated backward stochastic differential equation with a time-delayed generator (MF-DABSDE for short). In Section 3, by using the fixed point theorem, we demonstrate the existence and uniqueness of the solutions for this type of BSDE. Section 4 focuses on studying the comparison theorem of the solutions for this kind of model.

2. Preliminaries

We assume a complete probability space ( Ω , F , P ) with natural filtration F t = σ W s , s t N P , t [ 0 , T ] , which is generated by a d-dimensional standard Brownian motion { B t } t 0 , where T > 0 is a fixed real-time horizon and N P denotes the set of all P-null subsets and a real-time horizon. We denote the norm in R m by | · | . To simplify the presentation, we only discuss the one-dimensional case in this study. Consider the following sets:
L 2 ( F t ; R m ) : = φ : Ω R m | φ is F t measurable , E [ | φ | 2 ] < ;
L F 2 ( 0 , T ; R m ) : = { φ : [ 0 , T ] × Ω R m | φ is progressively measurable process ,
E 0 T | φ ( t ) | 2 ] d t < } ;
S F 2 ( 0 , T ; R m ) : = { ϕ : [ 0 , T ] × Ω R m | φ is continuous adapted process ,
E sup 0 t T | φ ( t ) | 2 < } .
If m = 1 , we denote the above spaces, respectively, by L 2 ( F t ) , L F 2 ( 0 , T ) and S F 2 ( 0 , T ) .
In addition, we introduce assumptions about d i . Let d i ( · ) , i = 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 represent four R + -valued continuous functions defined on [ 0 , T ] , and consider the following assumptions:
(D1)
There exists a constant K 0 , such that for all t [ 0 , T ] , 0 t d 1 ( t ) t , 0 t d 2 ( t ) t , t t + d 3 ( t ) T + K , t t + d 4 ( t ) T + K ;
(D2)
There exists a constant L 0 , such that for all non-negative and integrable f ( · ) ,
t T f ( s d 1 ( s ) ) d s L t T + K f ( s ) d s , t T f ( s d 2 ( s ) ) d s L t T + K f ( s ) d s ,
t T f ( s + d 3 ( s ) ) d s L t T + K f ( s ) d s , t T f ( s + d 4 ( s ) ) d s L t T + K f ( s ) d s .
Then, we introduce the space required by mean-field limits and the assumptions; we first let ( Ω ¯ , F ¯ , P ¯ ) = ( Ω × Ω , F F , P P ) be the (non-completed) product of ( Ω , F , P ) with itself, and the product space has been filtered by F ¯ = F t ¯ = F F t , 0 t T . As a random variable originally defined on Ω , ξ L 0 ( Ω , F , P ; R m ) is canonically extended to Ω ¯ : ξ ( ω , ω ) = ξ ( ω ) , ( ω , ω ) Ω ¯ = Ω × Ω . For any φ L 1 ( Ω ¯ , F ¯ , P ¯ ) , φ ( . , ω ) : Ω R belongs to L 1 ( Ω , F , P ) , P ( d ω ) -a.s.; and then we denote the expectation of φ ( . , ω ) by
E [ φ ( . , ω ) ] = Ω φ ( ω , ω ) P ( d ω ) .
Note that E [ φ ] = E [ φ ( . , ω ) ] L 1 ( Ω , F , P ) , and
E ¯ [ φ ] = Ω φ d P ¯ = Ω E [ ( . , Ω ) ] P ( d ω ) = E [ E [ φ ] ] .
Now we observe that the generator of model (1) is E [ f ( t , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t , Z t , Y t , Z t , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ) ] , which includes not only the present and the past, but also the future solutions. Because of the preceding notation, we consider the following derivation:
E f ( t , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t , Z t , Y t , Z t , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ) ( ω ) = E [ f ( t , Y t d 1 ( t ) ( ω ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) ( ω ) , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t ( ω ) , Z t ( ω ) , Y t , Z t , Y t + d 3 ( t ) ( ω ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ( ω ) , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ) ] = Ω f ( t , Y t d 1 ( t ) ( ω ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) ( ω ) , Y t d 1 ( t ) ( ω ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) ( ω ) , Y t ( ω ) , Z t ( ω ) , Y t ( ω ) , Z t ( ω ) , Y t + d 3 ( t ) ( ω ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ( ω ) , Y t + d 3 ( t ) ( ω ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ( ω ) ) P ( d ω ) .
Indeed, based on the definition of expectation given above, we can derive the following two special cases:
E E f ( t , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t , Z t , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ) = E E f ( t , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t , Z t , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ) = E f ( t , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t , Z t , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ) ; E E f ( t , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t , Z t , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ) = E E f ( t , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t , Z t , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ) = E f ( t , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t , Z t , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ) .
Next, we present assumptions about the generator f. Let the mapping f ( t , ω , u , v , u , v ,
y , z , y , z , ϕ , ψ , ϕ , ψ ) : [ 0 , T ] × Ω × L 2 ( F r , R m ) × L 2 ( F r , R m ) × L 2 ( F r , R m ) × L 2 ( F r , R m ) ×
L 2 ( F r , R m ) × L 2 ( F r , R m ) L 2 ( F t , R m ) , s r , r T + K , satisfy the following two assumptions:
(H1)
There exists a constant C > 0 , such that for every t [ 0 , T ] , we have
f ( t , u , v , u , v , y , z , y , z , ϕ , ψ , ϕ , ψ ) f ( t , u ¯ , v ¯ , u ¯ , v ¯ , y ¯ , z ¯ , y ¯ , z ¯ , ϕ ¯ , ψ ¯ , ϕ ¯ , ψ ¯ ) C ( u u ¯ + | v v ¯ | + | u u ¯ | + | v v ¯ | + | y y ¯ | + | z z ¯ | + | y y ¯ | + | z z ¯ | + E | ϕ ϕ ¯ | + | ψ ψ ¯ | | F t + E | ϕ ϕ ¯ | + | ψ ψ ¯ | | F t ) ,
where u , u , u ¯ , u ¯ L F 2 ( 0 , t ; R m ) ; v , v , v ¯ , v ¯ L F 2 ( 0 , t ; R m × d ) ; y , y , y ¯ , y ¯ R m ; z , z , z ¯ , z ¯ R m × d ; ϕ , ϕ , ϕ ¯ , ϕ ¯ L F 2 ( t , T + K ; R m ) ; and ψ , ψ , ψ ¯ , ψ ¯ L F 2 ( t , T + K ; R m × d ) ;
(H2)
E 0 T f ( t , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 ) 2 d t < , and f ( t , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 ) L F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m ) .
We shall now review some basic results of propositions that will be used throughout the paper: Itô’s formula, the Burkeholder–Davis–Gundy inequality, and the fixed point theorem. Firstly, as we know, Itô’s formula is the most famous formula in stochastic calculus; it was proposed by Kiyosi Itô [31] in 1951 and is frequently used in the field of stochastic differential equations. This formula points out the rules for differentiating the functions of a stochastic process, and it is given below.
Proposition 1 
(Øksendal [32], Theorem 4.1.2). Let X t be an Itô process given by d X t = u d t + v d B t , where B t is a Brownian process and the functions u , v are deterministic functions of time. For any twice differentiable scalar function g ( t , x ) of two real variables t and x, we have
d g ( t , X t ) = g t ( t , X t ) d t + g x ( t , X t ) d X t + 1 2 2 g x 2 ( t , X t ) · ( d X t ) 2 .
Next, the Burkholder-Davis-Gundy inequality is given as follows:
Proposition 2 
(Burkholder et al. [33], Theorem 2.3). For any 1 p < , there exist positive constants c p and C p such that, for all local martingales X with X 0 = 0 and stopping times τ, the following inequality holds:
c p E [ X ] τ p / 2 E ( sup 0 t τ X t ) p C p E [ X ] τ p / 2 .
This paper will use the special case of p = 2 for the Burkholder-Davis-Gundy inequality.
Lastly, the fixed point theorem is an important principle in mathematics, and there have been several theorems that fall under it, for example, the contraction mapping theorem or Banach theorem, the Brouwer fixed point theorem, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem, Tarski’s theorem, and so on. These fixed point theorems often play a key role in proving the existence and uniqueness of fixed points for a self-mapping on complete metric spaces. Interested readers can refer to Granas and Dugundji [34] and Zhou et al. [35]. The contraction mapping theorem, which will be used in this paper, is briefly introduced below.
Proposition 3 
(Granas and Dugundji [34], Theorem 1.1). Let ( Y , d ) be a complete metric space and F : Y Y be contractive. Then F has a unique fixed point u, and F n ( y ) u for each y Y .

3. An Existence and Uniqueness Result for MF-DABSDEs

In this section, our aim is to seek out a pair of processes ( Y t , Z t ) S F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m × L F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m × d ) satisfying the mean-field BSDEs of model (1). Lemma 3.1 of Peng [5] can be extended to MF-DABSDEs by the following simple deduction.
Lemma 1. 
Given a terminal condition ξ L 2 ( F T ; R m ) , i.e., ξ is a R m -value F T -measurable random variable that satisfies E | ξ | 2 < , and f 0 ( t ) is an F t -adapted process that satisfies E 0 T | f 0 ( t ) | 2 d t < . Therefore, ( y t , z t ) L F 2 ( 0 , T ; R m × R m × d ) is a pair of processes that satisfy the following type of BSDEs:
y t = ξ + t T E f 0 ( s ) d s t T z s d B t , t [ 0 , T ] .
If f 0 ( t ) L F 2 ( 0 , T ; R m ) , then ( y t , z t ) S F 2 ( 0 , T ; R m ) × L F 2 ( 0 , T ; R m × d ) . Hence, for β > 0 , which is an argitrary constant, the following estimate can be obtained:
| y 0 | 2 + E 0 T e β s β 2 | y s | 2 + | z s | 2 d s E e β T | ξ | 2 + 2 β E 0 T e β s E [ f 0 ( s ) ] 2 d s .
We also have
E sup 0 t T | y t | 2 C E | ξ | 2 + 0 T E [ f 0 ( s ) ] 2 d s < .
Proof. 
Applying Itô’s formula for e β s | Y s | 2 for s [ t , T ] , one has
e β t | y t | 2 + t T e β s ( β | y s | 2 + | z s | 2 ) d s = e β T | ξ | 2 + 2 t T e β s | y s | E f 0 ( s ) d s 2 t T e β s | y s | | z s | d s .
Taking conditional expectation under F t and multiplying e β t on both sides of the above equation,
| y t | 2 + E t T e β ( s t ) ( β | y s | 2 + | z s | 2 ) d s | F t = E e β ( T t ) | ξ | 2 | F t + 2 E t T e β ( s t ) | y s | E f 0 ( s ) d s | F t E e β ( T t ) | ξ | 2 | F t + E t T e β ( s t ) β 2 | y s | 2 + 2 β E f 0 ( s ) 2 d s | F t .
Thus,
| y t | 2 + E t T e β ( s t ) β 2 | y s | 2 + | z s | 2 d s | F t E e β ( T t ) | ξ | 2 | F t + 2 β E t T e β ( s t ) E f 0 ( s ) 2 d s | F t .
When t = 0 , we have
| y 0 | 2 + E 0 T e β s β 2 | y s | 2 + | z s | 2 d s E e β T | ξ | 2 + 2 β E 0 T e β s E f 0 ( s ) 2 d s .
By using Burkholder–Davis–Gundy inequality, we have
E sup 0 t T | y t | 2 C E | ξ | 2 + 0 T E [ f 0 ( s ) ] 2 d s < ,
where C is a constant that varies with T. Therefore, y t S F 2 ( 0 , T ; R m ) . □
Lemma 2. 
Suppose f ( s , · ) satisfies (H1) and (H2) for s [ 0 , T ] . Further, let y s d 1 ( s ) , y s d 1 ( s ) , y ¯ s d 1 ( s ) , y ¯ s d 1 ( s ) L F 2 ( 0 , t ; R m ) ; z s d 2 ( s ) , z s d 2 ( s ) , z ¯ s d 2 ( s ) , z ¯ s d 2 ( s ) L F 2 ( 0 , t ; R m × d ) ; y s , y s , y ¯ s , y ¯ s R m ; z s , z s , z ¯ s , z ¯ s R m × d ; y s + d 3 ( s ) , y s + d 3 ( s ) , y ¯ s + d 3 ( s ) , y ¯ s + d 3 ( s ) L F 2 ( t , T + K ; R m ) ; z s + d 4 ( s ) , z s + d 4 ( s ) , z ¯ s + d 4 ( s ) , z ¯ s + d 4 ( s ) L F 2 ( t , T + K ; R m × d ) for t [ 0 , T ] ; and let d i ( t ) , i = 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 , satisfy (D1) and (D2). Hence,
E [ t T e β s | E f ( s , y s d 1 ( s ) , z s d 2 ( s ) , y s d 1 ( s ) , z s d 2 ( s ) , y s , z s , y s , z s , y s + d 3 ( s ) , z s + d 4 ( s ) , y s + d 3 ( s ) , z s + d 4 ( s ) ) E f ( s , y ¯ s d 1 ( s ) , z ¯ s d 2 ( s ) , y ¯ s d 1 ( s ) , z ¯ s d 2 ( s ) , y ¯ s , z ¯ s , y ¯ s , z ¯ s , y ¯ s + d 3 ( s ) , z ¯ s + d 4 ( s ) , y ¯ s + d 3 ( s ) , z ¯ s + d 4 ( s ) ) | 2 d s ] 24 C 2 ( 2 L + 1 ) E t T + K e β s | y ^ s d 1 ( s ) | 2 + | z ^ s d 2 ( s ) | 2 + | y ^ s , z ^ s | 2 + | y ^ s + d 3 ( s ) | 2 + | z ^ s + d 4 ( s ) | 2 d s ,
where we denote the differences by y ^ s d 1 ( s ) = y s d 1 ( s ) y ¯ s d 1 ( s ) , z ^ s d 2 ( s ) = z s d 2 ( s ) z ¯ s d 2 ( s ) , y ^ s = y s y ¯ s , z ^ s = z s b a r z s , y ^ s + d 3 ( s ) = y s + d 3 ( s ) y ¯ s + d 3 ( s ) , z ^ s + d 4 ( s ) = z s + d 4 ( s ) z ¯ s + d 4 ( s ) .
Proof. 
From assumptions (H1), (D1), and (D2), Equation (2), and Jensen’s inequality, we have
E [ t T e β s | E f ( s , y s d 1 ( s ) , z s d 2 ( s ) , y s d 1 ( s ) , z s d 2 ( s ) , y s , z s , y s , z s , y s + d 3 ( s ) , z s + d 4 ( s ) , y s + d 3 ( s ) , z s + d 4 ( s ) ) E f ( s , y ¯ s d 1 ( s ) , z ¯ s d 2 ( s ) , y ¯ s d 1 ( s ) , z ¯ s d 2 ( s ) , y ¯ s , z ¯ s , y ¯ s , z ¯ s , y ¯ s + d 3 ( s ) , z ¯ s + d 4 ( s ) , y ¯ s + d 3 ( s ) , z ¯ s + d 4 ( s ) ) | 2 d s ] E [ t T e β s E [ | f ( s , y s d 1 ( s ) , z s d 2 ( s ) , y s d 1 ( s ) , z s d 2 ( s ) , y s , z s , y s , z s , y s + d 3 ( s ) , z s + d 4 ( s ) , y s + d 3 ( s ) , z s + d 4 ( s ) ) f ( s , y ¯ s d 1 ( s ) , z ¯ s d 2 ( s ) , y ¯ s d 1 ( s ) , z ¯ s d 2 ( s ) , y ¯ s , z ¯ s , y ¯ s , z ¯ s , y ¯ s + d 3 ( s ) , z ¯ s + d 4 ( s ) , y ¯ s + d 3 ( s ) , z ¯ s + d 4 ( s ) ) | 2 ] d s ] 24 C 2 E t T e β s | y ^ s d 1 ( s ) | 2 + | z ^ s d 2 ( s ) | 2 + | y ^ s | 2 + | z ^ s | 2 + | y ^ s + d 3 ( s ) | 2 + | z ^ s + d 4 ( s ) | 2 d s 24 C 2 ( 2 L + 1 ) E t T + K e β s | y ^ s | 2 + | z ^ s | 2 d s .
Theorem 1. 
Suppose that ξ ( t ) S F 2 ( T , T + K ; R m and η ( t ) L F 2 ( T , T + K ; R m × d ) satisfy the conditions (H1) and (H2), and d i ( t ) , i = 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 , satisfy (D1) and (D2), then there will exist a unique solution ( Y t , Z t ) t [ 0 , T + K ] S F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m × L F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m × d ) for the MF-DABSDEs.
Proof. 
Firstly, we define a norm on L F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m × d ) which is equivalent to the following norm
φ ( · ) β = E 0 T + K e β t | φ t | 2 d t 2 .
We rewrite the MF-DABSDE given in Equation (1) as
Y t = ξ T + t T E [ f ( t , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t d 1 ( t ) , Z t d 2 ( t ) , Y t , Z t , Y t , Z t , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) , Y t + d 3 ( t ) , Z t + d 4 ( t ) ) ] d t t T Z t d B t , 0 t T ; Y t = ξ t , T t T + K ; Z t = η t , T t T + K .
Then we define the mapping I: L F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m × R m × d ) L F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m × R m × d ) such that ( Y · , Z · ) = I ( y · , z · ) . For an arbitrary pair ( y · , z · ) , ( y ¯ · , z ¯ · ) L F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m × R m × d ) , let ( Y · , Z · ) = I ( y · , z · ) , ( Y ¯ · , Z ¯ · ) = I ( y ¯ · , z ¯ · ) , and we put the differences as follows:
( Y ^ · , Z ^ · ) = ( Y · Y ¯ · , Z · Z ¯ · ) , ( y ^ · , z ^ · ) = ( y · y ¯ · , z · z ¯ · ) .
Now we will prove that the pair ( Y t ) S F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m ) , ( Z t ) L F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m × d ) can solve Equation (3) if and only if it is a fixed point of I.
Applying Itô’s formula for e β t | Y ^ t | 2 we have
d e β t | Y ^ t | 2 = β e β t | Y ^ t | 2 + 2 e β t | Y ^ t | d | Y ^ t | + e β t d | Y ^ t | 2 .
Combining Equation (1) and the properties of the Itô’s integral, and then taking the integral on [ 0 , T ] , we have
e β T | Y ^ T | 2 | Y ^ 0 | 2 = 0 T e β t β | Y ^ t | 2 + | Z ^ t | 2 d t 2 0 T e β t | Y ^ t | { E [ f ( t , y t d 1 ( t ) , z t d 2 ( t ) , y t d 1 ( t ) , z t d 2 ( t ) , y t , z t , y t , z t , y t + d 3 ( t ) , z t + d 4 ( t ) , y t + d 3 ( t ) , z t + d 4 ( t ) ) ] E [ f ( t , y ¯ t d 1 ( t ) , z ¯ t d 2 ( t ) , y ¯ t d 1 ( t ) , z ¯ t d 2 ( t ) , y ¯ t , z ¯ t , y ¯ t , z ¯ t , y ¯ t + d 3 ( t ) , z ¯ t + d 4 ( t ) , y ¯ t + d 3 ( t ) , z ¯ t + d 4 ( t ) ) ] } d t + 2 0 T e β t | Y ^ t | | Z ^ t | d B t .
Rearranging the terms and taking expectations on both sides, we obtain
| Y ^ 0 | 2 + β E 0 T e β t | Y ^ t | 2 d t + E 0 T e β t | Z ^ t | 2 d t = 2 E [ 0 T e β t | Y ^ t | { E [ f ( t , y t d 1 ( t ) , z t d 2 ( t ) , y t d 1 ( t ) , z t d 2 ( t ) , y t , z t , y t , z t , y t + d 3 ( t ) , z t + d 4 ( t ) , y t + d 3 ( t ) , z t + d 4 ( t ) ) ] E [ f ( t , y ¯ t d 1 ( t ) , z ¯ t d 2 ( t ) , y ¯ t d 1 ( t ) , z ¯ t d 2 ( t ) , y ¯ t , z ¯ t , y ¯ t , z ¯ t , y ¯ t + d 3 ( t ) , z ¯ t + d 4 ( t ) , y ¯ t + d 3 ( t ) , z ¯ t + d 4 ( t ) ) ] } d t ] β 2 E 0 T e β t | Y ^ t | 2 d t + 2 β E [ 0 T e β t { E [ f ( t , y t d 1 ( t ) , z t d 2 ( t ) , y t d 1 ( t ) , z t d 2 ( t ) , y t , z t , y t , z t , y t + d 3 ( t ) , z t + d 4 ( t ) , y t + d 3 ( t ) , z t + d 4 ( t ) ) ] E [ f ( t , y ¯ t d 1 ( t ) , z ¯ t d 2 ( t ) , y ¯ t d 1 ( t ) , z ¯ t d 2 ( t ) , y ¯ t , z ¯ t , y ¯ t , z ¯ t , y ¯ t + d 3 ( t ) , z ¯ t + d 4 ( t ) , y ¯ t + d 3 ( t ) , z ¯ t + d 4 ( t ) ) ] } 2 d t ] .
Rearranging the terms again and applying Lemma 2, we obtain the following estimate:
E 0 T e β t β 2 | Y ^ t | 2 + | Z ^ t | 2 d t 2 β E [ 0 T e β t { E f ( t , y t d 1 ( t ) , z t d 2 ( t ) , y t d 1 ( t ) , z t d 2 ( t ) , y t , z t , y t , z t , y t + d 3 ( t ) , z t + d 4 ( t ) , y t + d 3 ( t ) , z t + d 4 ( t ) ) E f ( t , y ¯ t d 1 ( t ) , z ¯ t d 2 ( t ) , y ¯ t d 1 ( t ) , z ¯ t d 2 ( t ) , y ¯ t , z ¯ t , y ¯ t , z ¯ t , y ¯ t + d 3 ( t ) , z ¯ t + d 4 ( t ) , y ¯ t + d 3 ( t ) , z ¯ t + d 4 ( t ) ) } 2 d t ] 48 C 2 ( 2 L + 1 ) β E 0 T + K e β s | y ^ s | 2 + | z ^ s | 2 d s .
Finally, by taking β = 96 C 2 ( 2 L + 1 ) + 2 , we obtain
E 0 T + K e β t | Y ^ t | 2 + | Z ^ t | 2 d t 1 2 E 0 T + K e β t | y ^ t | 2 + | z ^ t | 2 d t .
That is,
( Y ^ · , Z ^ · ) β 1 2 ( y ^ · , z ^ · ) β .
Thus, this mapping I is a contraction mapping on L F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m × R m × d ) that allows us to apply the fixed point theorem; the mapping I has a unique fixed point. That means Equation (3) has a unique solution ( Y t , Z t ) L F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m × R m × d ) on [ 0 , T + K ] such that I ( y t , z t ) = ( Y t , Z t ) . On the other hand, as f satisfies the assumptions (H1) and (H2), and d i ( t ) , i = 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 , satisfy (D1) and (D2), we have f ( t , y t d 1 ( t ) , z t d 2 ( t ) , y t d 1 ( t ) , z t d 2 ( t ) , y t , z t , y t , z t , y t + d 3 ( t ) , z t + d 4 ( t ) , y t + d 3 ( t ) , z t + d 4 ( t ) ) L F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m ) . Then, by applying Lemma 1, we obtain Y t S F 2 ( 0 , T + K ; R m ) . □

4. Comparison Theorem

In this section, we investigate a comparison theorem of MF-DABSDEs of the one-dimensional kind shown below:
Y t = ξ T + t T E f ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) , Y s , Z s , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ) d s t T Z s d B s , 0 t T ; Y t = ξ t , T t T + K ; Z t = η t , T t T + K .
Firstly, we introduce the classical case of the comparison theorem of BSDEs; Lemma 3 refers to Lemma 3.4 of Peng and Yang [20].
Lemma 3. 
Let ( Y · ( 1 ) , Z · ( 1 ) ) , ( Y · ( 2 ) , Z · ( 2 ) ) be the solutions of the following classical type of BSDE:
Y t ( j ) = ξ T ( j ) + t T f j ( s , Y s ( j ) , Z s ( j ) ) d s t T Z s ( j ) d B s , 0 t T .
Here j = 1 , 2 , and for ( y , z ) , f j ( t , y , z ) : Ω × [ 0 , T ] × R m × R m × d R m satisfies the Lipschitz condition, meaning that for any y , y ¯ R m and z , z ¯ R m × d , there exists C > 0 such that | f j ( t , y , z ) f j ( t , y ¯ , z ¯ ) | C ( | y y ¯ | + | z z ¯ | ) and f j ( · , 0 , 0 ) L F 2 ( 0 , T ; R m ) . If ξ ( 1 ) ξ ( 2 ) , f 1 ( t , y , z ) f 2 ( t , y , z ) , t [ 0 , T ] , y R m , z R m × d , then
Y t ( 1 ) Y t ( 2 ) , a . e . , a . s .
Next, let ( Y · ( 1 ) , Z · ( 1 ) ) , ( Y · ( 2 ) , Z · ( 2 ) ) be the solutions of the two one-dimensional MF-DABSDEs shown below,
Y t ( j ) = ξ T ( j ) + t T E f j ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) ( j ) , Y s ( j ) , Z s ( j ) , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ( j ) ) d s t T Z s ( j ) d B s , 0 t T ; Y t ( j ) = ξ t ( j ) , T t T + K ; Z t ( j ) = η t ( j ) , T t T + K ,
where j = 1 , 2 . The end outcome is as follows.
Theorem 2. 
Suppose f j ( t , · ) , j = 1 , 2 satisfy the assumptions (H1) and (H2), ξ t ( j ) S F 2 ( T , T + K ; R m ) , and d i ( t ) , i = 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 satisfy (D1) and (D2). Moreover, assume that
(i) 
f 1 ( t , u , y , z , ϕ ) is increasing in u and ϕ ;
(ii) 
ξ t ( 1 ) ξ t ( 2 ) ;
(iii) 
f 1 ( t , y t d 1 ( t ) , y t , z t , y t + d 3 ( t ) ) f 2 ( t , y t d 1 ( t ) , y t , z t , y t + d 3 ( t ) ) , y t d 1 ( t ) L F 2 ( 0 , t ) , y t + d 3 ( t ) L F 2 ( t , T + K ) .
It is then true that Y t ( 1 ) Y t ( 2 ) almost surely.
Proof.  
Since ( Y · ( 1 ) , Z · ( 1 ) ) is the solution of the one-dimensional MF-DABSDE given in Equation (5), we have
Y t ( 1 ) = ξ T ( 1 ) + t T E f 1 ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) ( 1 ) , Y s ( 1 ) , Z s ( 1 ) , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ( 1 ) ) d s t T Z s ( 1 ) d B s , 0 t T ; Y t ( 1 ) = ξ t ( 1 ) , T t T + K .
Next, we consider the following BSDEs:
Y t ( 3 ) = ξ T ( 2 ) + t T E f 2 ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) ( 1 ) , Y s ( 3 ) , Z s ( 3 ) , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ( 1 ) ) d s t T Z s ( 3 ) d B s , 0 t T ; Y t ( 3 ) = ξ t ( 2 ) , T t T + K .
From the classical existence and uniqueness theorem of classical BSDEs (Peng 2004, Theorem 3.2), we know there exists a unique solution ( Y t ( 3 ) , Z t ( 3 ) ) S F 2 ( 0 , T ) × L F 2 ( 0 , T ) . Considering Equations (6) and (7), as ξ t ( 1 ) ξ t ( 2 ) , f 1 ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) ( 1 ) , Y s ( 1 ) , Z s ( 1 ) , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ( 1 ) ) f 2 ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) ( 1 ) , Y s ( 3 ) ,   Z s ( 3 ) , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ( 1 ) ) , by Lemma 3, we have
Y t ( 1 ) Y t ( 3 ) a . e . , a . s .
Set
Y t ( 4 ) = ξ T ( 2 ) + t T E f 2 ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) ( 3 ) , Y s ( 4 ) , Z s ( 4 ) , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ( 3 ) ) d s t T Z s ( 4 ) d B s , 0 t T ; Y t ( 4 ) = ξ t ( 2 ) , T t T + K .
Consider Equations (7) and (8); f 1 ( t , u , y , z , ϕ ) is increasing in u and ϕ , and Y t ( 1 ) Y t ( 3 ) , which imply f 2 ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) ( 1 ) , Y s ( 3 ) , Z s ( 3 ) , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ( 1 ) ) f 2 ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) ( 3 ) , Y s ( 4 ) , Z s ( 4 ) , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ( 3 ) ) . Similar to the above, we have
Y t ( 3 ) Y t ( 4 ) a . e . , a . s .
For n = 5 , 6 , , we consider the following BSDEs:
Y t ( n ) = ξ T ( 2 ) + t T E f 2 ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) ( n 1 ) , Y s ( n ) , Z s ( n ) , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ( n 1 ) ) d s t T Z s ( n ) d B s , 0 t T ; Y t ( n ) = ξ t ( 2 ) , T t T + K .
Similarly, we obtain
Y t ( 4 ) Y t ( 5 ) Y t ( n 1 ) Y t ( n ) , a . s .
Next, we will show that n 4 , Y t ( n ) and Z t ( n ) are, respectively, Cauchy sequences. Denote Y ^ t ( n ) : = Y t ( n ) Y t ( n 1 ) , Z ^ t ( n ) : = Z t ( n ) Z t ( n 1 ) , n 4 , then from estimate (4), we obtain
E 0 T e β t β 2 | Y ^ t ( n ) | 2 + | Z ^ t ( n ) | 2 d t 2 β E [ 0 T e β t { E [ f 2 ( t , Y s d 1 ( s ) ( n 1 ) , Y t ( n ) , Z t ( n ) , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ( n 1 ) ) f 2 ( t , Y s d 1 ( s ) ( n 2 ) , Y t ( n 1 ) , Z t ( n 1 ) , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ( n 2 ) ) ] } 2 d t ] .
When we apply Jensen’s inequality, assumptions (H1), (D1) and (D2), and the fact that ( a + b + c + d ) 2 4 ( a 2 + b 2 + c 2 + d 2 ) , one has
E 0 T e β t β 2 | Y ^ t ( n ) | 2 + | Z ^ t ( n ) | 2 d t 8 C 2 ( 2 L + 1 ) β E [ 0 T e β t | Y ^ t ( n 1 ) | 2 + Y ^ t ( n ) | 2 + Z ^ t ( n ) | 2 + Y ^ t ( n 1 ) | 2 d t .
Let β = 32 C 2 ( 2 L + 1 ) + 2 , then we obtain
E 0 T e β t | Y ^ t ( n ) | 2 + | Z ^ t ( n ) | 2 d t 1 4 E 0 T e β t | Y ^ t ( n ) | 2 + Z ^ t ( n ) | 2 d t + 1 2 E 0 T e β t | Y ^ t ( n 1 ) | 2 d t .
Hence,
E 0 T e β t | Y ^ t ( n ) | 2 + | Z ^ t ( n ) | 2 d t 2 3 E 0 T e β t | Y ^ t ( n 1 ) | 2 d t 2 3 E 0 T e β t | Y ^ t ( n 1 ) | 2 + | Z ^ t ( n 1 ) | 2 d t .
Therefore,
E 0 T e β t | Y ^ t ( n ) | 2 + | Z ^ t ( n ) | 2 d t 2 3 n 4 E 0 T e β t | Y ^ t ( 4 ) | 2 + | Z ^ t ( 4 ) | 2 d t .
This means ( Y ^ t ( n ) , Z ^ t ( n ) ) n 4 is Cauchy sequence in L F 2 ( 0 , T + K ) × L F 2 ( 0 , T ) . Let the limit of ( Y ^ t ( n ) , Z ^ t ( n ) ) be ( Y · , Z · ) for all 0 t T , when n , hence
E t T e β s E f 2 ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) ( n 1 ) , Y s ( n ) , Z s ( n ) , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ( n 1 ) ) E f 2 ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) , Y s , Z s , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ) d s 4 C 2 E t T e β s | Y s ( n ) Y s | 2 + | Z s ( n ) Z s | 2 + 2 L | Y s ( n 1 ) Y s | 2 0 .
Thus, ( Y t , Z t ) is a solution of the following MF-DABSDEs:
Y t = ξ T ( 2 ) + t T E f 2 ( s , Y s d 1 ( s ) , Y s , Z s , Y s + d 3 ( s ) ) d s t T Z s d B s , 0 t T ; Y t = ξ t ( 2 ) , T t T + K .
Then, by Theorem 1 on the uniqueness of the solution, we know that
Y t = Y t ( 2 ) , a . s .
Since
Y t ( 1 ) Y t ( 3 ) Y t ( 4 ) Y t ,
then we obtain the desired result Y t ( 1 ) Y t ( 2 ) , a . s .

5. Conclusions

Our study contributes to the introduction of a new type of BSDE, the mean-field anticipated BSDE with a time-delayed generator, and uses the fixed point theorem, which is more convenient than another method (Picard’s iterative method), to prove the existence and uniqueness of the solution to this class of equations. Moreover, a comparison theorem is also obtained. A potential limitation of this study, when compared with the core work of Peng and Yang [20], stems from the fact that it involves mean-field limits and a more general generator f, which necessitates more elaborate steps. Also, this paper is slightly more demanding in terms of assumptions because of the simpler fixed point theorem method. Therefore, as a follow-up study and as the application of this paper, we aim to establish the relationship between the MF-DABSDEs and a nonlocal partial differential equation. In addition, it should be pointed out that, similar to the study of mean-field anticipated BSDEs driven by fractional Brownian motion, theoretically, our equation can also be applied to stochastic optimal control problems. In the future, further research may be conducted on this topic utilising broader assumptions and simpler approaches..

Author Contributions

Writing—original draft and writing—review and editing, P.Z., N.A.M. and A.I.N.I. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

The research was funded by Anhui Philosophy and Social Science Planning Project (AHSKQ2021D98), Natural Science Fund of Universities in Anhui Province (KJ2021A1101), Scientific research projects of colleges and universities in Anhui Province(2022AH051370), and Universiti Malaya research project (GPF031B-2018).

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

The authors appreciate the reviewers’ thorough reading and insightful feedback. Additionally, the authors would like to express their gratitude to the participating editors.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Pardoux, E.; Peng, S. Adapted solution of a backward stochastic differential equation. Syst. Control Lett. 1990, 14, 55–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Bahlali, K.; Essaky, E.H.; Oukine, Y. Reflected backward stochastic differential equation with jumps and locally Lipschitz coefficient. Random Oper. Stoch. Equ. 2002, 10, 481–486. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Al-Hussein, A. Backward stochastic partial differential equations driven by infinite-dimensional martingales and applications. Stochastics 2009, 81, 601–626. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Zhang, P.; Ibrahim, A.I.N.; Mohamed, N.A. Backward Stochastic Differential Equations (BSDEs) Using Infinite-Dimensional Martingales with Subdifferential Operator. Axioms 2022, 11, 536. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Peng, S. Nonlinear Expectations, Nonlinear Evaluations and Risk Measures. In Stochastic Methods in Finance; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 2004; pp. 165–253. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Luo, M.; Fečkan, M.; Wang, J.R.; O’Regan, D. g-Expectation for Conformable Backward Stochastic Differential Equations. Axioms 2022, 11, 75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Ma, J.; Protter, P.; Martín, J.S.; Torres, S. Numberical Method for Backward Stochastic Differential Equations. Ann. Appl. Probab. 2002, 12, 302–316. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Gobet, E.; Lemor, J.P.; Warin, X. A regression-based Monte Carlo method to solve backward stochastic differential equations. Ann. Appl. Probab. 2005, 15, 2172–2202. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Zhao, W.; Zhang, W.; Ju, L. A Numerical Method and its Error Estimates for the Decoupled Forward-Backward Stochastic Differential Equations. Commun. Comput. Phys. 2014, 15, 618–646. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Han, Q. Variable Step Size Adams Methods for BSDEs. J. Math. 2021, 2021, 9799627. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Ren, Y.; Xia, N. Generalized Reflected BSDE and an Obstacle Problem for PDEs with a Nonlinear Neumann Boundary Condition. Stoch. Anal. Appl. 2006, 24, 1013–1033. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Pardoux, E.; Răşcanu, A. Backward Stochastic Differential Equations. In Stochastic Differential Equations, Backward SDEs, Partial Differential Equations; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2014; pp. 353–515. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Karoui, N.E.; Peng, S.; Quenez, M.C. Backward stochastic differential equations in finance. Math. Financ. 1997, 7, 1–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Peng, S.; Wu, Z. Fully Coupled Forward-Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Applications to Optimal Control. SIAM J. Control Optim. 1999, 37, 825–843. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. El Asri, B.; Hamadene, S.; Oufdil, K. On the stochastic control-stopping problem. J. Differ. Equ. 2022, 336, 387–426. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Perninge, M. Sequential Systems of Reflected Backward Stochastic Differential Equations with Application to Impulse Control. Appl. Math. Optim. 2022, 86, 19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Li, J.; Peng, S. Stochastic optimization theory of backward stochastic differential equations with jumps and viscosity solutions of Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman equations. Nonlinear Anal. 2009, 70, 1776–1796. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Buckdahn, R.; Djehiche, B.; Li, J.; Peng, S. Mean-field backward stochastic differential equations: A limit approach. Ann. Appl. Probab. 2009, 37, 1524–1565. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Buckdahn, R.; Li, J.; Peng, S. Mean-field backward stochastic differential equations and related partial differential equations. Stoch. Process. Appl. 2009, 119, 3133–3154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Peng, S.; Yang, Z. Anticipated backward stochastic differential equations. Ann. Appl. Probab. 2009, 37, 877–902. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Feng, X. Anticipated Backward Stochastic Differential Equation with Reflection. Commun. Stat.-Simul. Comput. 2016, 45, 1676–1688. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Wang, T.; Cui, S. Anticipated Backward Doubly Stochastic Differential Equations with Non-Lipschitz Coefficients. Mathematics 2022, 10, 396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Wang, T.; Yu, J. Anticipated Generalized Backward Doubly Stochastic Differential Equations. Symmetry 2022, 14, 114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Douissi, S.; Wen, J.; Shi, Y. Mean-field anticipated BSDEs driven by fractional Brownian motion and related stochastic control problem. Appl. Math. Comput. 2019, 355, 282–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Liu, Y.; Dai, Y. Mean-field anticipated BSDEs driven by time-changed Lévy noises. Adv. Differ. Equ. 2020, 2020, 621. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Hao, T. Anticipated mean-field backward stochastic differential equations with jumps. Lith. Math. J. 2020, 60, 359–375. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Delong, Ł.; Imkeller, P. Backward stochastic differential equations with time delayed generators—Results and counterexamples. Ann. Appl. Probab. 2010, 20, 1512–1536. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. He, P.; Ren, Y.; Zhang, D. A Study on a New Class of Backward Stochastic Differential Equation. Math. Probl. Eng. 2020, 2020, 1518723. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Ma, H.; Liu, B. Infinite horizon optimal control problem of mean-field backward stochastic delay differential equation under partial information. Eur. J. Control 2017, 36, 43–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Zhuang, Y. Non-zero sum differential games of anticipated forward-backward stochastic differential delayed equations under partial information and application. Adv. Differ. Equ. 2017, 2017, 383. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Itô, K. On stochastic differential equations. Mem. Am. Math. Soc. 1951, 4, 1–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Øksendal, B. Stochastic Differential Equations: An Introduction with Applications, 6th ed.; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2003; ISBN 978-3-642-14394-6. [Google Scholar]
  33. Burkholder, D.L.; Davis, B.J.; Gundy, R.F. Integral inequalities for convex functions of operators on martingales. Proc. Sixth Berkeley Symp. Math. Stat. Prob. 1972, 2, 223–240. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Granas, A.; Dugundji, J. Fixed Point Theory, 2003rd ed.; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2003; ISBN 978-0387001739. [Google Scholar]
  35. Zhou, Z.; Bambos, N.; Glynn, P. Deterministic and Stochastic Wireless Network Games: Equilibrium, Dynamics, and Price of Anarchy. Oper. Res. 2018, 66, 1498–1516. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zhang, P.; Mohamed, N.A.; Ibrahim, A.I.N. Mean-Field and Anticipated BSDEs with Time-Delayed Generator. Mathematics 2023, 11, 888. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11040888

AMA Style

Zhang P, Mohamed NA, Ibrahim AIN. Mean-Field and Anticipated BSDEs with Time-Delayed Generator. Mathematics. 2023; 11(4):888. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11040888

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zhang, Pei, Nur Anisah Mohamed, and Adriana Irawati Nur Ibrahim. 2023. "Mean-Field and Anticipated BSDEs with Time-Delayed Generator" Mathematics 11, no. 4: 888. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11040888

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop