Next Article in Journal
The Impact of Recent Economic Crises on Income Inequality and the Risk of Poverty in Greece
Previous Article in Journal
FDI and Firm Productivity: A Comprehensive Review of Macroeconomic and Microeconomic Models
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Road to Hell Is Paved with Good Intentions: Modeling Grant Competition between Universities
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Human Capital, Networks and Segmentation in the Market for Academic Economists

by
João Ricardo Faria
1,
Franklin G. Mixon, Jr.
2,* and
William C. Sawyer
3
1
Department of Economics, Florida Atlantic University, Boca Raton, FL 33431, USA
2
Center for Economic Education, Columbus State University, Columbus, GA 31907, USA
3
Department of Economics, Texas Christian University, Fort Worth, TX 76109, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2023, 11(6), 165; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11060165
Submission received: 19 April 2023 / Revised: 31 May 2023 / Accepted: 8 June 2023 / Published: 12 June 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Sociology of Economics)

Abstract

:
Academic labor markets often exhibit steep hierarchies, with institutions at the top attempting to attract newly minted doctorates from similarly situated institutions in an effort to maintain or improve their reputations. Yet, despite recent research on labor market segmentation in academe, the literature has heretofore been under-theorized. This paper provides a straightforward formal model that generates a three-tiered hierarchy of academic institutions, wherein academic departments affiliated with top-tier universities endeavor to hire only from within the group, while those in the bottom tier are unable to employ faculty with degrees from top departments. The results from statistical tests applied to data from economics departments in the U.S. indicate that top-tier departments employ 3.5 to 3.8 (2.5 to 2.9) more assistant professors from top-tier institutions, ceteris paribus, than bottom (middle) tier departments.

1. Introduction

The academic labor market is noticeably segmented. Top academic departments often hire faculty with in-house doctoral degrees, while also attempting to attract newly minted doctorates from similarly situated institutions, all in an effort to improve their reputations through publications in leading journals and larger citation counts (see Faria et al. 2016, 2017). This practice follows from the idea that faculty candidates with doctorates from top academic departments are thought, a priori, to be future stars (see Mixon and Upadhyaya 2011, 2012, 2014; Faria et al. 2016, 2017). Moreover, it is well known that the most prestigious academic journals are edited (i.e., managed) by faculty members who are affiliated with these same top academic departments. A recent study by Colussi (2018) found that about 43 percent of the articles published in the top general-interest economics journals are authored by scholars who were connected to an editor at the time of the publication, and that being a doctoral student or departmental colleague of a journal’s editor improves one’s publication outcomes.1
Despite the recent interest in the academic labor market segmentation phenomenon highlighted above, the literature examining this phenomenon has heretofore been under-theorized. This study contributes to filling that gap in the literature. It provides a straightforward formal model that generates a three-tiered hierarchy of academic institutions. In equilibrium, we show that academic departments affiliated with top-tier universities endeavor to hire only within-tier job market candidates. In contrast, departments comprising the second tier hire a mix of faculty with degrees from both the top departments and from lesser-ranked institutions, while those at the bottom (i.e., the third tier) are unable to employ faculty with degrees from top departments, and, as a consequence, only hire candidates from institutions ranked near the median. The specifics of our model are supported by various statistical tests based on data from economics departments at colleges and universities in the U.S. Before turning to the formal model and the empirical explorations, we first provide a brief discussion of the background literature related to our work.

2. The Background Literature: A Brief Review

The noteworthy segmentation of the academic labor market is the subject of prior research. Just recently, for example, Yuret’s (2018) analysis of the educational backgrounds of 14,310 full professors from 48 top universities in the United States reveals that 72 percent of the professors obtained their doctorate degrees from only 20 universities.2 This type of market segmentation is quite profound in the field of law. Segall and Feldman (2019) report that of the 152 tenured or tenure-track law school faculties at Harvard University and Yale University holding domestic academic credentials, 149 hold degrees from among the top 10 institutions as ranked by the U.S. News & World Report. Similar results hold for Stanford University, the University of Chicago, the University of Michigan and the University of Pennsylvania.
The economics discipline is, as noted in the introduction above, especially prone to labor market segmentation. For example, both Han (2003) and Wu (2005) report that although the tendency of academic departments to hire from institutions ranked at or above their level is prevalent throughout academe, the top economics departments are more likely to engage in the practice than are top departments in other social sciences (e.g., sociology, political science, psychology), English, history and mathematics. A study by Klein (2005) that utilizes the international departmental rankings from Coupé (2003) reports that between 80 and 90 percent of economics faculty at the top economics departments earned their doctorates at one of the top 35 economics departments. Additionally, the data indicate that these same top 35 economics departments draw 76 percent of their combined faculty from within the group (Klein 2005).3 Klein supplements these results by reiterating the earlier finding in Kocher and Sutter (2001) that the top 10 institutions conferred the doctorates of about 55 percent of the authors in 15 top economics journals.4 Relatedly, more recent work by Colussi (2018) reports that between 2000 and 2006, 25 percent of the authors in the top four economics journals were employed at only six universities, while 47 percent earned their doctorates from the same universities. In an update, Heckman and Moktan (2020) found that between 2000 and 2016, about 12 percent of the papers in the American Economic Review and about 25 percent of the papers in the Quarterly Journal of Economics had at least one author affiliated with Harvard University.5 Lastly, Wright (2023) discusses the research indicating that the alma mater rankings are statistically significant predictors of the likelihood of publishing in the top five journals.
The phenomenon described by Klein (2005) was also found in a study by Combes et al. (2008) that analyzes the determinants of success in the concours d’agrégation en sciences économiques, which is a centralized hiring procedure through which professors of economics are selected in France. Using data from 1984 to 2003, these researchers focus in part on the role that candidates’ networks, defined as professional links between candidates and the hiring committee members who make the recruitment decisions, play in securing academic employment (Combes et al. 2008). They report that professional connections to hiring committee members are significantly related to the probability of securing employment. In fact, the effect of network connections is sufficiently strong that a substantial improvement in a candidate’s publication record is required to compensate for not being linked to the hiring committee (Combes et al. 2008).
Interestingly, there is some evidence that such hiring practices do not necessarily produce the desired outcome. In a study of the research productivity of new graduates from North American doctoral programs in economics from 1986 to 2000, Conley and Önder (2014) found that the rank of the graduate departments themselves provides a surprisingly poor prediction of future research success. For example, at the top 10 departments as a group, the median graduate has fewer than 0.03 American Economic Review-equivalent publications six years after graduation, which is a record they characterize as un-tenurable at a top department. They also report that doctoral program graduates of equal percentile rank from certain lower-ranked departments have stronger publication records than their counterparts at higher-ranked departments (Conley and Önder 2014). These results are consistent with an earlier work by Kim et al. (2009) and arguments made in a new study by Wright (2023). They assert that most of the productivity gains that elite universities historically provided have dissipated due to changes in communications technology (Kim et al. 2009; Wright 2023).
An earlier study by Pjesky and Sutter (2011) perhaps explains the disconnect between hiring practices at elite institutions and the same institutions’ desire to employ candidates with the greatest potential for future success. The disconnect results from the lack of a profit motive in academia, which, in other settings, was shown to curb forms of prejudice in hiring. Pjesky and Sutter (2011) explored the role of the profit motive in the performance of academic markets by comparing the pedigree of employees of top law schools to those at top law firms. In doing so, they found that top law schools are much more likely to employ graduates of top-ranked law schools than are elite law firms, and the difference exists at both the junior and senior levels. They also fail to report evidence suggesting that, in their roles as professors, the graduates of top law schools outperform those of less prestigious schools in terms publications or citations.6 When viewed together, these results support the notion that in the absence of a profit motive, hiring in the academy appears more likely to indulge a preference for pedigree.

3. Network Effects in Academic Labor Markets

As a result of the academic labor market practices described in the academic literature reviewed above, the establishment of networks consisting of faculty who are affiliated with higher echelon institutions has a high payoff. However, only a handful of academic departments housed in colleges and universities ranked near the median are able to attract and hire faculty with highly valued doctoral degrees. The lowest-ranking, typically smaller academic departments are generally unable to hire faculty with degrees from the top academic departments. In the relatively rare cases where they are successful, they generally find that the retention of these faculty is very difficult (Wapman et al. 2022). These problems mean that smaller and lesser-known academic departments typically fill faculty vacancies with candidates holding doctoral degrees from universities ranked near the median. Given the labor market and other networks fostered by academic departments at prominent universities (Heckman and Moktan 2020; Wright 2023), and the difficulties in hiring faculty from top-tier institutions faced by academic departments at universities ranked near the median (Yuret 2018; Segall and Feldman 2019), there is typically little change in the various rankings of academic departments. This type of stability is often supported by relatively large and significant correlation coefficients produced in studies that compare various rankings of departments (e.g., see Faria et al. 2016; Qian et al. 2016; Mixon and Upadhyaya 2022a).
Our formal model presents academic departments consisting of two types of faculties, one with degrees from top universities with human capital N , and another with degrees from all other universities with human capital H .7 It is generally assumed, a priori, that N H . A representative academic department benefits from human capital by hiring faculty who are productive in both teaching and research. The academic department also benefits from reputational effects, R , that emanate from the research endeavors of its faculty, which are captured by publications, P , and citations to those publications, C . Both P and C are positively related to R , and the representative academic department’s utility function is defined by
U = u H + v N + R ( P , C )
It is worth stressing, as discussed above, that the most prominent academic journals are usually edited (i.e., managed) by faculty who are affiliated with the top academic departments (Colussi 2018; Wright 2023). This generally benefits graduates from these departments, and these network effects facilitate the hiring of these newly minted PhDs by top academic departments (Heckman and Moktan 2020; Wright 2023). The network effects are captured in the model by assuming that publications and citations are increasing functions of N .8 Therefore, the reputational effects are a function of N as follows:
R P , C = R P N , C N = R ( N )
With the other factors constant, the representative academic department always prefers N to H in the academic labor market. Therefore, the academic department’s demand for H is derived from its demand for N . Given that the academic department hires several faculties with N , the remaining positions are filled by H and, as a consequence, H = H N , H N > 0 . In sum, the working hypotheses of our model are that (1) departments choose to hire faculty based on pedigree (whether they hold a doctorate from the top- or lower-ranked departments) (Kocher and Sutter 2001; Han 2003; Klein 2005; Wu 2005; Bryan 2019; Wapman et al. 2022; Wright 2023), and (2) job market candidates from top departments have an advantage because their professors dominate the main journals of the area (Colussi 2018; Heckman and Moktan 2020; Wright 2023). This network effect translates into more publications, thus increasing their value in the job market (Oyer 2006; Heckman and Moktan 2020; Wright 2023).
In order to simplify the algebra, we assume this process to be explicit in the following form:
H = W π N + a N N 2
where W π are the net costs to the academic department of hiring N , and a N N 2 are the adjustment costs to the academic department of hiring a level of N that differs from its optimal level, N .
The number of faculty candidates in the academic labor market who hold degrees from top academic departments is limited because top departments not only hire from other top departments (Wapman et al. 2022; Wright 2023), but they also hire the top candidates from within their own and other top departments (Faria et al. 2016; Bryan 2019). Because of this excess supply, the average department will hire doctoral candidates from a higher-ranked institution so that a rationing process for top candidates occurs, such that
N N
Substituting (2) into (1) and maximizing it with respect to H and N , considering (3) and (4) as constraints, yields the following Lagrangian function,
L = u H + v N + R N + δ W π N + a N N 2 H + μ N N
where δ can be interpreted as the marginal utility of the derived demand for H , and μ is the marginal utility of relaxing the constraint in (4). The first-order conditions are,
L H = 0 u ( H ) δ = 0
L N 0 v ( N ) + R ( N ) + δ W π + 2 a ( N N ) μ 0 ; N 0 ;   N L N = 0
and
N N 0 ;   μ 0 ;   μ N N = 0
where (7) and (8) are the Kuhn–Tucker conditions.
Substituting (6) into (7) yields an expression for H as a function of N as follows:
u H μ v N R N W π + 2 a ( N N )
In order to obtain clear solutions, we assume the following explicit functions:
u H = u   l n H ; v N = v N 0.5 N 2 ; R N = R N
Substituting (10) into (9) yields
u H μ + N v R W π + 2 a N N H W π + 2 a N N u μ + N v R
In solving the model, the above optimality conditions yield three equilibria. Each equilibrium allows us to classify academic departments on a hierarchical basis according to the type of human capital they hire. These are,
Tier 1 Academic Department
L N = 0   and   N 1 = N = N + W π 2 a N > 0 ,   and   H 1 = 0
Tier 2 Academic Department
L N = 0   and   0 < N 2 = N < N   and   H 2 = W π u N v R
and
Tier 3 Academic Department
L N 0 ; N 3 = 0   and   H 3 π W + 2 a N u v + R .
Based on the hypothesis that faculty possessing doctoral degrees from top academic departments are paid more than the return they generate to their respective academic departments, given that the net costs are positive (i.e., W > π ), the comparison of the academic departments, according to the conditions in (12) through (14), yields the main result of the model. Namely, a ranking of academic departments in terms of human capital accumulated
N 1 N 2 N 3 ,
and
H 1 H 2 H 3 .
According to (15) and (16), top academic departments are of the Tier 1 type, given that they are able fill all of their faculty vacancies with candidates who hold doctoral degrees from top academic departments. In some cases, they may even hire more of these candidates than is optimal (i.e., N 1 = N = N + W π 2 a N ). Additionally, they do not hire candidates who do not possess a doctoral degree from a top institution (i.e., H 1 = 0 ). Next, Tier 2 characterizes the median academic departments, which satisfy their optimal levels of human capital through candidates from top academic departments, N 2 = N , and then fill the rest of their vacancies with candidates who hold doctoral degrees from academic departments other than those at the top of the academic hierarchy. Lastly, the academic departments occupying the lowest rung(s) of the academic hierarchy are classified as Tier 3 organizations. These academic departments are unable to hire any candidates who possess a doctoral degree from a top academic department (i.e., N 3 = 0 ). Thus, all of their faculty vacancies are filled by candidates who hold doctoral degrees from other academic departments.

4. Empirical Evidence

To explore the main implication of the economic model presented in the previous section, we begin with a straightforward econometric test of the human capital ranking described in (15). More specifically, we regress the number of assistant professors employed by an economics department, i, who hold an academic credential from a top-tier economics department (i.e., Ni) on the size of the department, as captured by the total number of assistant professors employed, TotFaculty, and HigherTier, which is a dummy variable equal to one for higher-tier (i.e., higher-ranking) economics departments, and zero otherwise.9 In all cases, TotFaculty and HigherTier are expected to be positively related to the number of assistant professors employed by an economics department, i, who hold an academic credential from a top-tier economics department (i.e., Ni).
The ranking information on economics departments is collected from two sources, RePEc and U.S. News & World Report. The first of these, RePEc, is a widely used source of institutional quality (rankings) by academic economists (e.g., see Bornmann et al. 2018; Gnewuch and Wohlrabe 2018; Wallace and Perri 2018; Baumann and Wohlrabe 2020; García-Suaza et al. 2020; Doleac et al. 2021; Rybacki and Serwa 2021; Zacchia 2021; Chang and Li 2022), while U.S. News & World Report is the gold standard for institutional quality (rankings) among American media and the general public. As a consequence, the latter is also widely used in the economics literature (e.g., see Boustan and Langan 2019; Bryan 2019; Lundberg and Stearns 2019; Mixon 2019; Ghosh and Liu 2020; Heckman and Moktan 2020; Bedard et al. 2021; Naven and Whalen 2022). The human capital (i.e., academic credentials) data for each assistant professor are collected from departmental websites. In the case of the RePEc ranking, we selected the top 10, middle 10 and bottom 10 economics departments as representatives of the three academic tiers described in the previous section.10 In terms of the U.S. News & World Report ranking, we selected the top 10 and middle 10 academic institutions. Given that this source ranks the bottom 40 academic institutions in the same position, we randomly selected 20 academic institutions from this set to constitute the bottom 10 academic institutions from this source.
The results from the ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions (using SAS) based on three comparisons—N1 vs. N2, N1 vs. N3 and N2 vs. N3—using each data source are presented in Table 1. Beginning with the RePEc ranking, TotFaculty is, as expected, both positively signed and significantly related to N across all three comparisons. According to the estimates, each additional assistant professor employed raises the number of assistant professors holding human capital N from 0.53 to 0.73, ceteris paribus. As predicted by the tier effect variable in our economic model, the top-tier economics departments employ an average of 2.5 additional assistant professors with human capital N than do their middle-tier counterparts. Compared to the bottom-tier economics departments, the top-tier departments employ 3.5 additional assistant professors with human capital N. Lastly, the middle-tier economics departments employ, on average, about one additional assistant professor with human capital N than do their bottom-tier counterparts. In all three cases, the reported difference between the economics departments, according to the academic tier, is significant.
Moving to the U.S. News & World Report data, TotFaculty is again positively related to N in each case. With the exception of the third comparison (i.e., N2 vs. N3), the coefficient estimate attached to TotFaculty is statistically significant. In the two statistically significant cases, the estimate suggests that the employment of each assistant professor raises the number of assistant professors with human capital N from 0.68 to 0.79, ceteris paribus. As predicted by the tier effect variable in our economic model, the top-tier academic institutions employ an average of 2.9 additional assistant professors with human capital N than do their middle-tier counterparts. Compared to the bottom-tier academic institutions, the top-tier institutions employ 3.8 additional assistant professors with human capital N. Lastly, the middle-tier academic institutions employ, on average, about 1.3 additional assistant professors with human capital N than their bottom-tier counterparts. In all three cases, the reported difference between the institutions, according to the academic tier, is significant.
Next, we explore some of the individual characteristics of the economic model that are discussed after the introduction of (15) and (16) in the prior section. Table 2 provides the details of the individual economics departments ranked by RePEc that are used to perform the first three OLS regressions in Table 1. In this case, each economics department provides a test of some of the strict characteristics of our model discussed above. For example, the first set of tests presented in Table 2 are goodness-of-fit tests that compare the distribution of assistant professors described by our model to each economics department’s actual distribution. For the top-tier departments, the former is that H1 = 0 (i.e., N1 is equal to the total number of assistant professors). As indicated by the goodness-of-fit test statistics shown in the top one-third of Table 2, the actual distribution of human capital for the top-tier economics departments does not significantly differ from that predicted by our model in nine of the ten cases. In this instance, unexpected results are obtained for the economics department at New York University.
The bottom portion of Table 2 presents results from the goodness-of-fit tests for the bottom-tier economics departments. For the bottom-tier departments, our model asserts that H3 is equal to the total number of assistant professors (i.e., N3 = 0). As indicated in Table 2, the actual distribution of human capital for the bottom-tier economics departments does not significantly differ from that predicted by our model in eight of the ten cases. Here, unexpected results are obtained for the economics departments at CUNY—Hunter College and Wesleyan University.11 The latter of these two unexpected cases raises the issue of including liberal arts institutions in the sample. Institutions that are more teaching oriented, such as Hamilton College, Amherst College and Wesleyan University, may have different utility functions and, therefore, should be excluded from the analysis. Doing so, in this case, would yield a concordant percent of 85.7, which more strongly supports our formal model. The research by Hartley and Robinson (1997), Bodenhorn (1997, 2003), Qian et al. (2016) and Mixon and Upadhyaya (forthcoming) indicates, however, that top-tier liberal arts colleges in the U.S. have, since the mid-1980s, developed a rather robust research ethos that is in many ways similar to that at research-oriented universities. This literature would support the inclusion of the aforementioned liberal arts institutions in Table 2.
The characteristic of the formal model that relates to the mid-tier economics departments is simply that N2 and H2 are each greater than zero. In this case, the goodness-of-fit tests compare each economics department’s actual distribution of assistant professors to one where N2 and H2 are equally represented. These results are displayed in the middle portion of Table 2. In eight of the ten tests, there is no significant difference between these two distributions, which is a result that is consistent with our model. The two unexpected results are obtained for the University of Illinois and Florida State University. The former employs a relatively large number of assistant professors with human capital N, and the latter employs a relatively large number of assistant professors with human capital H.
The type of analysis referred to above is replicated using the ranking information provided by the U.S. News & World Report. The results from this analysis are presented in Table 3. As indicated by the goodness-of-fit statistics displayed in the top one-third of Table 3, the actual distribution of human capital for the top-tier academic institutions does not significantly differ from that predicted by our model in eight of the ten cases. Here, unexpected results are obtained for the economics departments at Columbia University and the University of Pennsylvania.
The bottom portion of Table 3 contains results from the goodness-of-fit tests for the bottom-tier academic institutions using the ranking information from the U.S. News & World Report. As indicated in Table 3, the actual distribution of human capital for the bottom-tier academic institutions does not significantly differ from that predicted by our model in 19 of the 20 cases, resulting in a concordant score of 95 percent, which is up from the 80 percent concordant score for the bottom tier using the RePEc ranking. In this case, the only unexpected result is obtained for the economics department at Fordham University.12
Lastly, the results for the mid-tier academic institutions are displayed in the middle portion of Table 3. In eight of the ten tests, there is no significant difference between the two distributions that are compared, which again, is a result that is consistent with our model. It also represents a notable improvement over the 70 percent concordance recorded for a similar test using the RePEc ranking data. In this case, the two unexpected results are obtained for the University of Kentucky and Tulane University. Each of these universities employs a relatively large number of assistant professors of economics with human capital H.

5. Additional Discussion, Implications and Ideas for Future Research

The main result generated by our formal model presented above is a ranking of the academic departments in terms of human capital accumulation. The top academic departments, therein, are able fill all of their faculty vacancies with candidates who hold doctoral degrees from top academic departments, while, conversely, the academic departments occupying the lowest tier are unable to attract job market candidates from the top academic departments. Lastly, the academic departments occupying the middle of the distribution employ some faculty from top departments, and others from departments lower in the hierarchy. Using the RePEc data, an analysis of the employment patterns exhibited by U.S. economics departments suggests that the actual employment patterns differ, taking a statistical point of view, from the main result of our formal model in only 10 to 20 percent of cases. When the data from the U.S. News & World Report are used instead, the discordance occurs in only 5 to 20 percent of cases. These results support both the prior literature (e.g., Han 2003; Klein 2005; Wu 2005; Bryan 2019; Wapman et al. 2022; Wright 2023) and our formal model.
As indicated above, the actual numbers found in Table 2 and Table 3 are also applied to regression-based testing. Based on the OLS models, using the RePEc data (see Table 1) for eight-member departments occupying the top two tiers, a top-tier department is predicted to employ 6.46 faculty with human capital N, and 1.54 faculty with human capital H, while a second-tier department is predicted to employ 3.98 faculty with human capital N, and 4.02 faculty with human capital H. According to the data in Table 2, Stanford University employs eight assistant professors of economics, comprising six with human capital N and two with human capital H. These are quite close to the predicted values for the top-tier departments. Table 2 also indicates that the University of California—Riverside employs eight assistant professors of economics, with three having human capital N and five having human capital H. These are consistent with the predictions for the second-tier departments noted above, and, combined with the comparisons for the top tier, support both the prior work (e.g., Han 2003; Klein 2005; Wu 2005; Bryan 2019; Wapman et al. 2022; Wright 2023) and our formal model.
Much like that in the study by Wapman et al. (2022), the main implication of the formal model and empirical analyses presented in this study relates to the hiring and retention of university faculty, both of which rely upon efforts to improve the organization, composition and scholarship of the academic workforce (Wapman et al. 2022). As Lan et al. (forthcoming) point out, the employment outcomes and career prospects of employment in higher education are increasing in importance to job market prospects and to the general public, which consumes and funds higher education. In most cases, the advancement from assistant professor to professor requires experience in teaching and a substantial publication record (Lan et al., forthcoming). These accomplishments take considerable time, perhaps 10 or more years. Both our formal model and the empirical analyses concern the prestige factor involved in matching job market prospects and higher education institutions. For those who do not matriculate into the professorate from top departments, the prestige factor in hiring is compounded by Oyer’s (2006) finding that job market prospects who initially place into tenure-track jobs are 55 percent more likely to secure tenure in a later year, and that candidates who are initially employed by a top 50 department are 60 percent more likely to be at a top 50 department later in their careers. These results hold, as Oyer (2006) shows, because a better initial job market placement increases one’s research productivity, which helps to offset some of the uncontrollable risks that one may face during promotion and merit raise processes, and future job searches (see also Mixon and Upadhyaya, forthcoming).
Going beyond Oyer’s (2006) analysis, other prior research indicate that economists affiliated with top-ranked institutions benefit from their institutional affiliation with regard to the receipt of research grants (Murray et al. 2016), membership in the National Bureau of Economic Research (Kleemans and Thornton 2021), invitations to give professional presentations (Doleac et al. 2021), invitations to collaborate on research projects (Jones et al. 2008) and, most importantly, favorable judgments by journal editors (Blank 1991; Oyer 2006; Fourcade et al. 2015; Ersoy and Pate, forthcoming). Additionally, the research by Hoover and Svorenčík (2023) indicates that economists holding doctorates from, or employed by, one of only six universities have dominated the ‘electoral pool’ of the American Economic Association (AEA) since its inception.13 This organization is not only influential in its own right, but it also sponsors some of the most influential journals in economics, including, but not limited to, the American Economic Review, the Journal of Economic Literature and the Journal of Economic Perspectives (see Mixon and Upadhyaya 2022b). The first of these journals, according to Card and DellaVigna (2013) and Card and DellaVigna (2018), is responsible for publishing between 35 and 41 percent of the top five papers in economics each year. Lastly, the AEA also sponsors the John Bates Clark Medal, which is arguably the second-most prestigious award in economics (Mixon and Upadhyaya 2014; Chan et al. 2018; Cherrier and Svorenčík 2020).
Although empirical tests generally support the facets of our formal model, our study is not without limitations. The quality of the predictions discussed above and the size of the accompanying R2 statistics notwithstanding, the models examined in Table 1 are rather parsimonious. Thus, any future attempt to explore the impacts of additional regressors on academic departments’ hiring patterns would represent a useful extension of the literature on networks and labor market segmentation in academe. A further extension of our empirical work might also go beyond the studies by Hartley and Robinson (1997), Bodenhorn (1997, 2003), Qian et al. (2016) and Mixon and Upadhyaya (forthcoming), and conduct tests to explore the possibility that research universities and liberal arts colleges have different utility functions. This could be performed by replicating our analyses using separate samples for research universities and liberal arts colleges. The counterfactual approach in Mixon and Upadhyaya (forthcoming) perhaps provides a template for such analysis.
There are also other avenues for extending the formal model in this study. For example, our effort to show in (15) and (16) that N 1 N 2 N 3 and H 1 H 2 H 3 , respectively, could be accomplished without most of the assumptions made regarding the functional forms. Instead, our main result could be derived from several monotonic conditions. This would provide a more technical approach to the formal analysis. Additionally, our formal model tends to show a one-way selection process that focuses on academic departments’ preferences. Future research could model the choices and behavior of PhD candidates applying for, and accepting, offers from academic departments. Although our formal model is general enough to be applied to all categories of academic departments, one obvious avenue for future research would be to extend the formal model, and the empirical tests supporting it, to other disciplines. Perhaps law, which is discussed above, would be a useful place to start. Following Conley and Önder (2014), more sophisticated analyses might also integrate class rank into the hiring process. Such an undertaking would, of course, be relatively costly to subject to empirical verification. Additionally, extending a model like the one presented here to various outcome measures of the sort examined by Conley and Önder (2014) and described in Klein (2005) would be less costly, yet perhaps still generate useful insights into the inner workings of academic labor markets across disciplines. Lastly, this study does not deal with the important topic of academic inbreeding, which is detrimental to research aspirations, innovativeness, risk-taking and the multi-disciplinary nature of the engagement of academics’ research agendas (Horta et al. 2022; Loewenstein et al. 2001; Weber et al. 2002; Conley and Önder 2014; Akerlof 2020; Heckman and Moktan 2020; Wright 2023). Thus, the bias that academic inbreeding introduces in hiring is an additional element of inefficiency in the academic labor market that could be integrated into the formal model.

6. Conclusions

The segmentation of the academic labor market on the basis of elite pedigree is a subject of much study and debate. Despite this interest, however, the academic literature examining the phenomenon has heretofore been under-theorized. The straightforward formal model presented above, wherein a three-tiered hierarchy of academic institutions exists, addresses this void. More specifically, the model indicates that academic departments affiliated with top-tier universities endeavor to hire only within-tier job market candidates, while those in the bottom tier are unable to employ faculty with degrees from top departments. The remaining middle tier is, unlike the departments populating the third tier, able to employ some faculty with degrees from the highest-ranking institutions in the field, although the degree to which this occurs falls far short of that exhibited among the top departments.
The statistical tests based on the ranking information on economics departments or institutions that are collected from the RePEc and U.S. News & World Report support the main element of our formal model. For example, the results from the OLS regressions based on three comparisons—top-tier economics departments and second-tier economics departments, top-tier economics departments and bottom-tier economics departments and second-tier economics departments and bottom-tier economics departments—indicate that, while holding the department size constant, top-tier economics departments employ 2.5 to 2.9 additional assistant professors with doctoral degrees from top departments compared to their middle-tier counterparts. Compared to bottom-tier economics departments, top-tier departments employ 3.5 to 3.8 additional assistant professors that hold doctoral degrees from top departments. Lastly, middle-tier economics departments employ, on average, about 1 to 1.3 additional assistant professors that hold doctoral degrees from top departments compared to their third-tier counterparts.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, J.R.F. and W.C.S.; methodology, J.R.F. and F.G.M.J.; writing—original draft preparation, J.R.F. and F.G.M.J.; writing—review and editing, J.R.F. and F.G.M.J.; project administration, F.G.M.J. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Data used in this study are contained herein.

Acknowledgments

The authors thank the five anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments on a prior version of the manuscript. The usual caveat applies.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Notes

1
Laband (1985) finds that articles published by authors from the same school as a journal’s editor are significantly longer than other articles, which is a result that could lead to bias in department rankings based on pages published. Similarly, Mixon (1998) reports that the ordering (placement) of articles in printed issues of top economics journals is influenced by editorial connections. There is, however, a body of work indicating that editorial connections lead to efficient outcomes in the publishing process (e.g., see Laband and Piette 1994; Medoff 2003; Hilmer and Hilmer 2011; Coehlo et al. 2014).
2
Yuret’s (2018) study is confined to undergraduate and graduate degrees attained within the U.S.
3
As indicated in Bryan (2019), these data trends are only accentuated when the analysis is confined to “star” students, as defined by the quality of institutions offering in-person job market interviews, in economics. See Wapman et al. (2022) for evidence that a large majority of U.S. faculty across all fields are trained by a small minority of universities.
4
Klein (2005) also reiterates the finding in Coupé (2004) that the top departments have disproportional influence with book publishers, foundations and government grant-making organizations.
5
This process also extends to major awards in economics. Cherrier and Svorenčík (2020) point out that of the 40 winners of the John Bates Clark Medal (up to 2018), which is a strong precursor to winning the Nobel Prize (Chan et al. 2018), 25 percent earned their undergraduate degrees from Harvard University, 50 percent earned their doctorates from either Harvard University or MIT and almost 90 percent were employed by a small group of institutions including Harvard University, MIT, the University of Chicago, Princeton University, Stanford University and the University of California—Berkeley. Updated data examined by Wright (2023) produce similar results.
6
See also Klein (2005) for a discussion of other, more philosophical, kinds of problems with the type of academic labor market segmentation described here.
7
In the context of our formal model, a department’s human capital, following Faria et al. (2016, 2017), is represented by the quality of the institutional affiliations of the doctorate degrees held by the department’s assistant professors.
8
See evidence of institutional oligopoly in the editorship of economic journals in Hodgson and Rothman (1999).
9
Data are collected from economics faculty rosters at the end of the 2020–2021 academic year.
10
Although Lehigh University is home to one of the bottom 10 economics departments, it was replaced by the next available institution because its website does not provide information on the education credentials of its economics faculty.
11
It is perhaps unsurprising that an unexpected result is found for Hunter College, which is located in New York City, given that its location affords it access to individuals with human capital N who have locational preferences favoring such an institution.
12
Again, we encounter an unexpected result associated with a New York City-based institution (i.e., Fordham University), which is perhaps explained by its locational advantage to many scholars with N human capital.
13
The six universities include the University of Chicago, Columbia University, Harvard University, MIT, Princeton University and Stanford University (Hoover and Svorenčík 2023).

References

  1. Akerlof, George A. 2020. Sins of omission and the practice of economics. Journal of Economic Literature 58: 405–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Baumann, Alexandra, and Klaus Wohlrabe. 2020. Where have all the working papers gone? Evidence from four major economics working paper series. Scientometrics 124: 2433–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Bedard, Kelly, Maxine Lee, and Heather Royer. 2021. Using longitudinal data to explore the gender gap for academic economists. AER Papers and Proceedings 111: 69–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Blank, Rebecca M. 1991. The effects of double-blind versus single-blind reviewing: Experimental evidence from the American Economic Review. American Economic Review 81: 1041–67. [Google Scholar]
  5. Bodenhorn, Howard. 1997. Teachers, and scholars too: Economic scholarship at elite liberal arts colleges. Journal of Economic Education 28: 323–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Bodenhorn, Howard. 2003. Economic scholarship at elite liberal arts colleges: A citation analysis with rankings. Journal of Economic Education 34: 341–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Bornmann, Lutz, Alexander Butz, and Klaus Wohlrabe. 2018. What are the top five journals in economics? A new meta-ranking. Applied Economics 50: 659–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Boustan, Leah, and Andrew Langan. 2019. Variation in women’s success across PhD programs in economics. Journal of Economic Perspectives 33: 23–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Bryan, Kevin A. 2019. Young ‘stars’ in economics: Where they go and what they do. Economic Inquiry 57: 1392–407. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Card, David, and Stefano DellaVigna. 2013. Nine facts about top journals in economics. Journal of Economic Literature 51: 144–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  11. Card, David, and Stefano DellaVigna. 2018. Update to ‘Nine facts about top journals in economics’. Unpublished. [Google Scholar]
  12. Chan, Ho Fai, Franklin G. Mixon Jr., and Benno Torgler. 2018. Relation of early career performance and recognition to the probability of winning the Nobel Prize in economics. Scientometrics 114: 1069–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Chang, Andrew C., and Phillip Li. 2022. Is economics research replicable? Sixty published papers from thirteen journals say ‘often not’. Critical Finance Review 11: 185–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Cherrier, Beatrice, and Andrej Svorenčík. 2020. Defining excellence: Seventy years of the John Bates Clark Medal. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 42: 153–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Coehlo, Philip R. P., James E. McClure, and Peter J. Reilly. 2014. An investigation of editorial favoritism in the AER. Eastern Economic Journal 40: 274–81. [Google Scholar]
  16. Colussi, Tommaso. 2018. Social ties in academia: A friend is a treasure. Review of Economics and Statistics 100: 45–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Combes, Pierre-Philippe, Laurent Linnemer, and Michael Visser. 2008. Publish or peer-rich? The role of skills and networks in hiring economics professors. Labour Economics 15: 423–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Conley, John P., and Ali S. Önder. 2014. The research productivity of new PhDs in economics: The surprisingly high non-success of the successful. Journal of Economic Perspectives 28: 205–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  19. Coupé, Tom. 2003. Revealed performances: Worldwide rankings of economists and economics departments, 1990–2000. Journal of the European Economic Association 1: 1309–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Coupé, Tom. 2004. What do we know about ourselves? On the economics of economics. Kyklos 57: 197–216. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Doleac, Jennifer L., Erin Hengel, and Elizabeth Pancotti. 2021. Diversity in economics seminars: Who gets invited? AER Papers and Proceedings 111: 55–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Ersoy, Fulya Y., and Jennifer Pate. Forthcoming. Invisible hurdles: Gender and institutional differences in the evaluation of economics papers. Economic Inquiry. [CrossRef]
  23. Faria, João Ricardo, Franklin G. Mixon Jr., and Kamal P. Upadhyaya. 2016. Human capital, collegiality, and stardom in economics: Empirical analysis. Scientometrics 106: 917–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Faria, João Ricardo, Franklin G. Mixon Jr., and Kamal P. Upadhyaya. 2017. Human capital and collegiality in academic beehives: Theory and analysis of European economics faculties. Theoretical and Applied Economics 24: 147–62. [Google Scholar]
  25. Fourcade, Marion, Etienne Ollion, and Yann Algan. 2015. The superiority of economists. Journal of Economic Perspectives 29: 89–114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. García-Suaza, Andrés, Jesús Otero, and Rainer Winkemann. 2020. Predicting early career productivity of PhD economists: Does advisor-match matter? Scientometrics 122: 129–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  27. Ghosh, Pallab, and Zexuan Liu. 2020. Coauthorship and the gender gap in top economics journal publications. Applied Economics Letters 27: 580–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Gnewuch, Matthias, and Klaus Wohlrabe. 2018. Super-efficiency of education institutions: An application to economics departments. Education Economics 26: 610–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Han, Shin-Kap. 2003. Tribal regimes in academia: A comparative analysis of market structure across disciplines. Social Networks 25: 251–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Hartley, James E., and Michael D. Robinson. 1997. Economic research at national liberal arts colleges: School rankings. Journal of Economic Education 28: 337–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Heckman, James J., and Sidharth Moktan. 2020. Publishing and promotion in economics: The tyranny of the top five. Journal of Economic Literature 58: 419–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Hilmer, Michael J., and Christiana E. Hilmer. 2011. Do editors favor their students’ work? A test of undue favoritism in top economics journals. Economics Bulletin 31: 53–65. [Google Scholar]
  33. Hodgson, Geoffrey M., and Harry Rothman. 1999. The editors and authors of economics journals: A case of institutional oligopoly? The Economic Journal 109: 165–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  34. Hoover, Kevin D., and Andrej Svorenčík. 2023. Who runs the AEA? Journal of Economic Literature. in press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Horta, Hugo, Michele Meoli, and João M. Santos. 2022. Academic inbreeding and choice of strategic research approaches. Higher Education Quarterly 76: 76–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Jones, Benjamin F., Stefan Wuchty, and Brian Uzzi. 2008. Multi-university research teams: Shifting impact, geography, and stratification in science. Science 322: 1259–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  37. Kim, E. Han, Adair Morse, and Luigi Zingales. 2009. Are elite universities losing their competitive edge? Journal of Financial Economics 93: 353–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  38. Kleemans, Marieke, and Rebecca L. Thornton. 2021. Who belongs? The determinants of selective membership into the National Bureau of Economic Research. AEA Papers and Proceedings 111: 117–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Klein, Daniel B. 2005. The Ph.D. circle in academic economics. Econ Journal Watch 2: 133–48. [Google Scholar]
  40. Kocher, Martin G., and Matthias Sutter. 2001. The institutional concentration of authors in top journals of economics during the last two decades. The Economic Journal 111: 405–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Laband, David N. 1985. Publishing favoritism: A critique of department rankings based on quantitative publishing performance. Southern Economic Journal 52: 510–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Laband, David N., and Michael J. Piette. 1994. Favoritism versus search for good papers: Empirical evidence regarding the behavior of journal editors. Journal of Political Economy 102: 194–203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Lan, Yihui, Ian W. Li, Zong Ken Chai, and Kenneth W. Clements. Forthcoming. The Market for Economics and Finance PhDs. Australian Economic Review. [CrossRef]
  44. Loewenstein, George F., Elke U. Weber, Christopher K. Hsee, and Ned Welch. 2001. Risk as feelings. Psychological Bulletin 127: 267–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  45. Lundberg, Shelly, and Jenna Stearns. 2019. Women in economics: Stalled progress. Journal of Economic Perspectives 33: 3–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  46. Medoff, Marshall H. 2003. Editorial favoritism in economics? Southern Economic Journal 70: 425–34. [Google Scholar]
  47. Mixon, Franklin G., Jr. 1998. Favoritism or showcasing high-impact papers? Modeling editorial placement of journal articles in economics. International Review of Economics 45: 327–40. [Google Scholar]
  48. Mixon, Franklin G., Jr. 2019. Sugar Daddy U: Human capital investment and the university-based supply of ‘romantic arrangements’. Applied Economics 51: 956–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Mixon, Franklin G., Jr., and Kamal P. Upadhyaya. 2011. From London to the Continent: Ranking European economics departments on the basis of prestigious medals and awards. Ekonomia 14: 119–26. [Google Scholar]
  50. Mixon, Franklin G., Jr., and Kamal P. Upadhyaya. 2012. The economics Olympics: Ranking U.S. economics departments based on prizes, medals, and other awards. Southern Economic Journal 79: 90–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Mixon, Franklin G., Jr., and Kamal P. Upadhyaya. 2014. Eyes on the prize: Human capital and demographic elements of economics’ Nobel Prize and John Bates Clark Medal. Briefing Notes in Economics 24: 1–18. [Google Scholar]
  52. Mixon, Franklin G., Jr., and Kamal P. Upadhyaya. 2022a. The impact of publications in core public choice journals: An analysis of institution rankings. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice 37: 95–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Mixon, Franklin G., Jr., and Kamal P. Upadhyaya. 2022b. Top to bottom: An expanded ranking of economics journals. Applied Economics Letters 29: 226–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Mixon, Franklin G., Jr., and Kamal P. Upadhyaya. Forthcoming. When forgiveness beats permission: Exploring the scholarly ethos of clinical faculty in economics. American Journal of Economics and Sociology. [CrossRef]
  55. Murray, Dennis L., Douglas Morris, Claude Lavoie, Peter R. Leavitt, Hugh MacIsaac, Michael E.J. Masson, and Marc-Andre Villard. 2016. Bias in research grant evaluation has dire consequences for small universities. PLoS ONE 11: e0155876. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  56. Naven, Matthew, and Daniel Whalen. 2022. The signaling value of university rankings: Evidence from top 14 law schools. Economics of Education Review 89: 102282. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Oyer, Paul. 2006. Initial labor market conditions and long-term outcomes for economists. Journal of Economic Perspectives 20: 143–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  58. Pjesky, Rex J., and Daniel Sutter. 2011. Does the lack of a profit motive affect hiring in academe? Evidence from the market for lawyers. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 70: 1053–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Qian, Chen, Steven B. Caudill, and Franklin G. Mixon Jr. 2016. Engaged in teaching, and scholarship too: Economics faculty productivity at liberal arts colleges. International Journal of Pluralism and Economics Education 7: 360–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Rybacki, Jakub, and Dobromił Serwa. 2021. What makes a successful scientist in a central bank? Evidence from the RePEc database. Central European Journal of Economic Modelling and Econometrics 13: 331–57. [Google Scholar]
  61. Segall, Eric J., and Adam Feldman. 2019. The elite teaching the elite: Who gets hired by the top law schools? Journal of Legal Education 68: 614–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Wallace, Frederick H., and Timothy J. Perri. 2018. Economists behaving badly: Publications in predatory journals. Scientometrics 115: 749–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  63. Wapman, K. Hunter, Sam Zhang, Aaron Clauset, and Daniel B. Larremore. 2022. Quantifying hierarchy and dynamics in US faculty hiring and retention. Nature 610: 120–7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Weber, Elke U., Ann-Renée Blais, and Nancy E. Betz. 2002. A domain-specific risk-attitude scale: Measuring risk perceptions and risk behaviors. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 15: 263–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. White, Halbert. 1980. A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity. Econometrica 48: 817–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Wright, Jack. 2023. The hierarchy in economics and its implications. Economics & Philosophy, 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Wu, Stephen. 2005. Where do faculty receive their PhDs? A comparison across six disciplines. Academe 91: 53–4. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Yuret, Tolga. 2018. Path to success: An analysis of US educated elite academics in the United States. Scientometrics 117: 105–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Zacchia, Giulia. 2021. What does it take to be top women economists? An analysis using rankings in RePEc. Review of Political Economy 33: 170–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. Summary of OLS Results.
Table 1. Summary of OLS Results.
RePEc Ranking TiersUSNWR Ranking Tiers
N1 vs. N2N1 vs. N3N2 vs. N3N1 vs. N2N1 vs. N3N2 vs. N3
Constant−1.867 ***
(−3.54)
−2.038 ***
(−3.22)
−1.628
(−1.45)
−2.246 ***
(−4.38)
−2.276 ***
(−5.21)
−0.059
(−0.15)
TotFaculty0.731 ***
(6.84)
0.628 ***
(5.92)
0.530 **
(2.15)
0.785 ***
(8.67)
0.683 ***
(5.87)
0.083
(0.83)
HigherTier2.480 ***
(3.21)
3.536 ***
(6.70)
0.904 *
(1.77)
2.896 ***
(3.75)
3.804 ***
(5.10)
1.250 ***
(3.05)
n202020203030
F-statistic54.1 ***101.7 ***8.23 ***57.1 ***120.6 ***6.60 ***
R20.8640.9230.4920.8700.8990.328
Notes: Numbers in parentheses are robust t-ratios (White 1980). ***, ** and * denotes the 0.01, 0.05 and 0.10 level of significance, respectively.
Table 2. Human Capital by the RePEc Ranking Tier.
Table 2. Human Capital by the RePEc Ranking Tier.
InstitutionsTotal FacultyN FacultyH FacultyGoodness-of-Fit Test StatisticsConcordant Percent
Tier 1 Economics Departments 90.0
Harvard University5500.000
MIT3300.000
University of California—Berkeley9811.125
University of Chicago9722.571
Princeton University161333.692
Stanford University8622.667
Columbia University7522.800
Brown University10822.500
New York University9634.500 **
Yale University10822.500
Tier 2 Economics Departments 80.0
Tufts University4311.000
University of Missouri2021.000
Purdue University9272.778
University of Connecticut3120.333
University of Illinois11924.455 **
University of Houston4131.000
University of Rochester6152.667
Syracuse University5320.200
University of California—Riverside8350.500
Florida State University5055.000 **
Tier 3 Economics Departments 80.0
Colorado School of Mines3030.000
University of Maryland—Baltimore County5141.250
Hunter College, CUNY220**
University of Richmond6060.000
University of Nevada—Reno4131.333
University at Buffalo4040.000
Hamilton College4040.000
Amherst College6060.000
Wesleyan University6243.000 **
University of Nebraska—Omaha2020.000
Notes: The numbers in the penultimate column are χ 2 statistics for goodness-of-fit tests of the actual distribution of faculty hires compared to the expected distribution of faculty hires. ** denotes the 0.05 level of significance. In each case, failure of the test statistic to reject the null hypothesis supports elements of the formal model. The numbers in the last column represent the percent of cases for each tier that support the formal model.
Table 3. Human Capital by the U.S. News & World Report Ranking Tier.
Table 3. Human Capital by the U.S. News & World Report Ranking Tier.
InstitutionsTotal FacultyN FacultyH FacultyGoodness-of-Fit Test StatisticsConcordant Percent
Tier 1 Academic Institutions 80.0
Harvard University5500.000
MIT3211.500
Princeton University161422.286
Stanford University8711.143
University of California—Berkeley9900.000
Yale University10911.111
Northwestern University111100.000
University of Chicago9722.571
Columbia University7435.250 **
University of Pennsylvania8534.800 **
Tier 2 Academic Institutions 80.0
University of Illinois—Chicago5320.500
University of Kentucky3033.000 **
University of Wyoming2110.000
Binghamton University 7251.286
Brandeis University5320.500
Clemson University6420.667
Tulane University7077.000 **
University of Kansas4131.000
University of Tennessee4131.000
Louisiana State University6152.667
Tier 3 Academic Institutions 95.0
Colorado State University3030.000
Fordham University43112.00 **
Kansas State University4040.000
Middle Tennessee State University3030.000
Mississippi State University3030.000
New Mexico State University4040.000
Northern Illinois University2020.000
Oklahoma State University3030.000
Suffolk University2020.000
Temple University5050.000
Texas Tech University5050.000
University of Arkansas7070.000
University of Central Florida3030.000
University of Hawai’i—Mānoa4040.000
University of Memphis2112.000
University of New Hampshire5050.000
University of New Mexico6060.000
University of Rhode Island2020.000
University of Southern Mississippi3030.000
Wayne State University4131.333
Note: The numbers in the penultimate column are χ 2 statistics for goodness-of-fit tests of the actual distribution of faculty hires compared to the expected distribution of faculty hires. ** denotes the 0.05 level of significance. In each case, failure of the test statistic to reject the null hypothesis supports elements of the formal model. The numbers in the last column represent the percent of cases for each tier that support the formal model.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Faria, J.R.; Mixon, F.G., Jr.; Sawyer, W.C. Human Capital, Networks and Segmentation in the Market for Academic Economists. Economies 2023, 11, 165. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11060165

AMA Style

Faria JR, Mixon FG Jr., Sawyer WC. Human Capital, Networks and Segmentation in the Market for Academic Economists. Economies. 2023; 11(6):165. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11060165

Chicago/Turabian Style

Faria, João Ricardo, Franklin G. Mixon, Jr., and William C. Sawyer. 2023. "Human Capital, Networks and Segmentation in the Market for Academic Economists" Economies 11, no. 6: 165. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11060165

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop