Next Article in Journal
Brown Coal Waste in Agriculture and Environmental Protection: A Review
Next Article in Special Issue
Sustainability of Income Convergence in the European Union: Two Downturns—Two Different Stories
Previous Article in Journal
Counterattacking Cyber Threats: A Framework for the Future of Cybersecurity
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Impact of Environmental Management on Labour Productivity
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

How Does Corporate Innovation Affect Sustainable Business Investment?

1
Division of Business Administration, Gyeongsang National University, Jinju 52828, Republic of Korea
2
Division of Business Administration, Chosun University, Gwangju 61452, Republic of Korea
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2023, 15(18), 13367; https://doi.org/10.3390/su151813367
Submission received: 6 June 2023 / Revised: 22 August 2023 / Accepted: 30 August 2023 / Published: 6 September 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Sustainability in Business Development and Economic Growth)

Abstract

:
This study examines the impact of corporate innovation on sustainable business investments of companies listed on the Korea exchange from 2011 to 2019. To this end, our study applies Hennessy’s investment model, which presents the relationship between corporate investment and Tobin’s mean Q in a probabilistic space. We find evidence of a positive relationship between corporate investment and Tobin’s average Q . Greater corporate growth opportunities lead to greater business investments, whereas the expected recovery ratio of debt capital has a negative relationship with corporate investments. The innovation performance variable is positively associated with the investments. Our results are suggestive of business investments being determined by investment outcomes, rather than the financial resource inputs for corporate innovation. Our study holds significance not only in the academic dimension, but also in policymaking. Since corporate growth is the outcome of corporate investments, the government may establish and implement economic policies that induce such investments.

1. Introduction

This study aims to examine the impacts of innovation on the sustainable investments of Korean companies, listed on the Korean exchange. Corporate innovation induces investments, which are the managers’ allocation of corporate resources, leading to qualitatively positive changes in the industry. In addition, corporate innovation creates new industries by producing new products, and contributes to the country’s overall and sustainable economic development. Therefore, it is important to explore the relationship between corporate innovation and investment.
Despite this importance, studies on the relationship between corporate innovation and (business) investment are sparse. In reality, studies on innovation are heavily concentrated on the relation between innovation, performance, growth, and value at the company, industry, or country (e.g., [1,2,3,4,5,6] among others). Specifically, at a company level, the two studies of [1,2] show evidence that innovation is positively associated with company performance variables (ROA, ROE, Tobin’s Q, corporate market value, etc.). Ref. [6] reports empirical evidence that via adjusting the input mix and capital structure, companies with innovation capacity enhance their corporate equity value and financial performance. Showing that high-tech industry has a positive moderating effect, Ref. [7] finds that innovative efficiency obviously enhances a Chinese-listed firm’s valuation on the securities market. They additionally suggest that portfolio returns with different innovative efficiencies can be appropriately determined by the market. At a country level, the recent study of [4] confirms that an innovation capacity increases a country’s GDP for economic growth. However, these studies do not suggest any process or channel where innovation has a positive relationship with a country’s economic growth and corporate performances.
Very exceptionally, using Australian industry sector data, Ref. [8] sets up a relation between innovation and investment in historical time without reference to any static equilibrium. The two recent studies of [9,10] argue that from the perspective of foreign direct investment (FDI) rather than corporate innovation, corporate investment causes corporate innovation. That is, the corporate investment of FDI can trigger corporate innovation, leading to corporate temporary developments. In the perspective of the effect of corporate innovation performance on the cost of financing in private investments in public equity, Ref. [11] reports that innovative US companies issue securities in private equity placements at a lower cost than the cost of non-innovative firms. However, it is still questionable whether the corporate investment heads corporate sustainable development. To overcome this problem, corporate innovation should substantially lead to their business investments, and the profits from the investments should be sustainably reinvested for greater innovation. Eventually, this virtuous cycle structure enables companies to achieve their sustainable developments. However, for the economic effect of corporate innovation on corporate business investment, there is a lack of extant studies, to the best of our knowledge.
There are two reasons to explain this. First, an appropriate theoretical model for an effect of innovation on tangible asset investment is not available at a corporate level. That is, there are a variety of theoretical models between corporate investment, growth (Tobin’s Q), value, and so on. On the other hand, there is no direct theoretical model for the relationship between innovation variables and investment. Second, the results of the empirical analysis on innovation and investment at an enterprise level might be unsatisfactory. Corporate R&D costs are widely used as the proxy for innovation (e.g., [12,13,14] among others). However, the R&D expense variable has no significant influence on corporate investments on tangible assets. This result agrees with our empirics.
To fill up the lacuna to the literature, our study rarely attempts to examine that at the company level, innovation induces investment on tangible assets. Thus, this study sheds light on how innovation induces corporate growth. To this end, our study systematically examines the economic effect of corporate innovation on business investment, targeting the companies listed in Korea, one of leading countries in innovation and investment. To examine the impact of innovation on Korean companies’ investment, this study applies Hennessy’s [15] investment model, which presents the relationship between corporate investment and Tobin’s mean Q in a probabilistic space. Unlike [15,16], we specifically assume a firm’s complete dependence on both internal and external (i.e., debt) capital for corporate investment, whereas the former assumes a firm’s sole dependence on internal capital.
Under these assumptions, Ref. [15] suggests a theoretical model of the relationship between Tobin’s average Q of corporate investments and corporate debt’s expected recovery ratio. He also demonstrated the negative relationship between corporate investments with Tobin’s average Q and the debt capital’s expected recovery ratio. However, Ref. [17] leaves an additional task of testing for the research model, by substituting the debt capital’s expected recovery ratio with the leverage ratio’s debt capital ratio (i.e., total liabilities/total assets), and empirically testing it. The expected recovery of debt capital refers to the shares attributable to creditors, in the event of a company’s bankruptcy. Accordingly, it is somewhat difficult to conduct an empirical analysis by only replacing the debt capital’s expected recovery ratio with debt capital. To solve this problem, we derive debt capital’s expected recovery amount using the put option pricing model devised by [18], and use it for our empirical analysis. The main empirical work of our study is to check for the following research questions (RQs):
RQ 1.
How do corporate investments affect corporate growth?
RQ 2.
What kind of relationship does the expected recovery ratios of debt capital have with corporate investments.
The main findings obtained by this study are as follows: First, corporate investments are positively associated with Tobin’s average Q proxied for corporate growth. This result suggests that greater growth opportunities for companies promote greater investments. The expected recovery ratio of debt capital has a negative relationship with corporate investments. This finding confirms that the debt capital’s expected recovery ratio decreases corporate investments.
Second, the innovation outcomes have a significant positive effect on companies’ investments, regardless of the types of industries (i.e., manufacturing or non-manufacturing industries). However, we find no relationship between the R&D expense ratio and corporate investment. These results imply that corporate investments are determined by outcomes by innovation, rather than corporate input activities of the financial resources for it. This suggests that the performance of innovation could improve corporate investments for corporate growth rather than innovation input itself. Therefore, this study sheds valuable light on how innovation induces corporate investments for corporate growth.
Our study holds significance not only in the academic dimension, but also in policymaking. Since corporate growth is the outcome of corporate investments, the government may establish and implement economic policies that induce such investments. These investments are determined by many corporate management factors, including corporate innovation. Hence, policymakers are concerned about the probability of corporate innovations stimulating corporate investments.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Followed by the introduction in Section 1, Section 2 discusses the analytical and empirical methods to examine the relationship between innovation and investments. Section 3 describes the data used in our empirical analysis. Section 4 presents the empirical results on the relationship between corporate innovation and investment. Section 5 discusses the main results of our study and Section 6 briefly concludes our study.

2. Research Method

2.1. Establishing the Relationship between Tobin’s Marginal q and Average Q

A firm’s investment F I can be implemented in the amount of new investment I at the point of coincidence of the marginal cost and marginal profit, expressed as Tobin’s marginal q . This relationship can be expressed as Equation (1). For more detail, refer to [15,16].
F I I , K = q K , ε t
where I and K denote a new investment and capital stock, respectively. ε is a state variable.
Given that Tobin’s average Q is defined as corporate value V on corporate capital stock K , the relationship between Tobin’s marginal q and average Q is expressed by Equation (2). This equation shows that corporate marginal profit is the value obtained by deducting the value obtained and by dividing the present value of the expected recovery of debt capital, for corporate bankruptcy by capital stock, defined as the corporate value.
q K 0 , ε 0 = Q K 0 , ε 0 R K 0 , ε 0 K 0
where R K 0 , ε 0 presents the value of debt capital’s expected recovery.

2.2. Present Value of Expected Recovery on Debt Capital

We note that Tobin ‘s marginal q is expressed as the relationship between Tobin’s average Q and the present value of debt capital’s expected recovery, following bankruptcy R K 0 , ε 0 . However, there exists the challenge of an unknown present value of the debt capital’s expected recovery amount, of debt capital at the current time period ( t 0 ). Therefore, we assume the following to derive the expected recovery of debt capital R K 0 , ε 0 , based on Merton’s study [19].
➀ There are no transaction costs and taxes. ➁ There are numerous investors in the capital market who may buy and sell assets at given prices. ➂ It is possible to borrow and lend at the same interest rate. ➃ Short-selling of all assets is available. ➄ Assets are continuously tradable. ➅ The term structure of the interest rate is flat and deterministic. ➆ The corporate value V follows a stochastic process, as shown in Equation (3). (Equation (3) assumes that corporate value follows a probabilistic process different from [16] and Hennessy [15]. It is assumed that the value is the sum of the present value of the balance of deducting total investment costs from the expected future operating profits. However, this is to derive the present value of the corporate value and expected recovery amount.)
d V Z = μ v d t + σ v V t d z
where V , μ v ,   a n d   σ v denote the corporate value, its expected return, and its volatility, respectively. z is the winner process.
It is also assumed that the entity raises debt capital by issuing one pure discount bond, with par value D T and maturity T . Given that the corporate value at maturity is greater than D T , shareholders will pay debt capital and continue operating their company. On the contrary, if the corporate value is less than D T , the company might be confronted with bankruptcy. There is no cost involved in this event, and an absolute priority rule is guaranteed. This means that, in the case of bankruptcy, assets are allocated according to the priority of debt capital repayment, and shareholders are only responsible for their equity.
Given the risk-neutral probability distribution of the corporate value at maturity f ^ , the expected recovery amount of debt capital is measured using Equation (4):
R K T , ε T = D T max D T V T , 0 f ^ V T d V T
where R K T , ε T , D , and f ^ denote the expected recovery of debt capital at maturity, the par value of net discount bonds, and the risk-neutral probability distribution, respectively.
According to the risk-neutral valuation argument, Equation (4), which expresses the present value, is the same as Equation (5) [20].
R K 0 , ε 0 = e r f T D T max D T V T , 0 f ^ V T d V T
where r f is the risk-free rate.
In Equation (5), e r f T D T max D T V T , 0 f ^ V T d V T represents the present value of a European put option, with an underlying asset V T and strike price D T . This can be derived using Black and Scholes’s [18] put option pricing model, as shown in Equation (6). In that equation, N . is the cumulative probability distribution function of the normal distribution.
R K 0 , ε 0 = e r f T D T D T e r f T N d 2 + V 0 N d 1
where d 1 = ln V 0 D T + r f + σ v 2 2 T T σ   and   d 2 = d 2 T σ The computation of Equation (6) requires the whole value of the parameters r f , T , D T , V 0 , and σ v , but V 0 and σ v are unknown. To solve this problem, the present value E 0 of equity capital is considered as a European call option, with the underlying asset   V T and strike price   D T , as shown in Equation (7) [19].
E 0 = V 0 N d 1 D r f T N d 2
Applying Ito’s Lemma, Equation (8) is obtained:
σ E E 0 = E V σ v V 0   or   σ E E 0 = N d 1 σ v V 0
Since it is possible to estimate the parameters σ E and E 0 using companies’ stock price data, we can obtain the parameters V 0 and σ by simultaneously solving Equations (7) and (8). In addition, by substituting the estimated values V 0 and σ v in Equation (6), we can derive the present value of debt capital’s expected recovery R K 0 , ε 0 .

2.3. Investment and Innovation

Assume that for changing a corporate capital stock, the total investment cost T I C is expressed in the form of Equation (9) (see [15,16,21,22,23]).
T I C I t , K t = I t + 1 2 η K t I K δ 2
where η and δ denote the unknown parameter and average investment rate, respectively.
In Equation (9), η is an unknown parameter to be estimated and δ denotes the average rate of corporate investment [23]. This equation shows that a higher (or lower) investment rate than the current average rate of investment entails adjustment costs 1 2 η K t I K δ 2 according to the changes in outcomes. For the adjustment cost to have a greater value than zero, η should be a positive constant. If Equation (9) is partially differentiated with respect to I t , Equation (10) can be obtained as follows:
T I C I t , K t = 1 η δ + η I K t
Equation (10) is changeable to Equation (11), by plugging Equation (10) into Equation (11).
I K t = δ 1 η + 1 η q t
Substituting Equation (2) for Tobin’s marginal q and average Q into Equation (11), we obtain Equation (12).
I K t = δ 1 η + 1 η Q t 1 η R K t
This equation presents the relationship between corporate investments, Tobin’s average Q , the expected recovery of debt capital (i.e., expected return on debt divided by total assets), and R K . The absolute values of the constant terms for Tobin’s average, Q , and R K are identical. This may lower the logic of the model but simplifies the basic assumptions for effectively deriving the model. As Tobin’s average Q is defined as the corporate market value with respect to the replacement cost of capital stock, some studies use Tobin’s average Q as a proxy for growth opportunities [24].
Equation (13) is the regression equation for Equation (12), adding the industry dummy I d and year dummy Y d to control for the effects of industry and year.
I K t = α + β 1 Q t + β 2 R K t + β 3 I d + β 4 Y d + ε t
where I K and R K denote the investment rate and ratio of the expected recovery of debt capital, respectively. I d and Y d are the industry and year dummy, respectively.
The investment rate of the dependent variable I K aggregates the acquisition of land in the cash outflow account from investment activities in the statement of cash flow; the acquisition of buildings, structures, and equipment; machinery tools and equipment, vehicle carriers, and the increment and acquisition of assets under construction and mergers (i.e., transfer of business) in cash outflows. Next, for the investment rate, we sum the following cash inflow items: the disposal of land in the cash inflow account from investment activities in the statement of cash flow; the disposal of building structures and equipment; the disposal of machinery; the disposal of tools and equipment; the disposal of vehicle carriers; and the decrement and merger of assets (i.e., business transfer) under construction. The sum of the cash inflows is deducted. The deducted value is then divided by the total assets [12].
Another measurement can be calculated by subtracting the cash inflow from the cash outflow from investment activities, on the cash flow statement, and dividing it by the total assets [25]. When the investment ratio is measured by the amount of cash flows (i.e., inflows and outflows), there is a detrimental problem in its accuracy, because this measurement includes investment activities that are not associated with the intrinsic business of the company. Since cash outflows and inflows through investment activities particularly include R&D costs, the flows have the problem of endogeneity with the R&D expense ratio R & D , a proxy for innovation [3] measured by the cash inflow and outflow from investment activities, by dividing the increment and decrement of tangible assets, excluding lands and the depreciation in total assets, or by dividing the increment in total assets and fixed assets by total assets. However, the aforementioned method of measuring corporate investments with the actual amount of cash spent is more desirable [25].

2.4. Innovation Indicator

To analyze the effect of innovation on corporate investments, this study sets up Equations (14) and (19) below, which are extensions of the regression equation (Equation (13)). Equation (14) adds an innovation input indicator, R&D expense ratio R & D , and the square of R&D expense ratio R & D 2 to Equation (13). A variety of indicators, such as the R&D cost ratio (or R&D costs), the purchase cost of machinery and tools relevant to new products and processes, and costs of technology introduction, are used as proxies for innovation inputs. Of these indicators, the R&D expense ratio, calculated as R&D expenditures divided by total sales, is more commonly accepted as the most representative innovation input indicator in studying innovation.
Studies that use the R&D ratio emphasize the importance of technological innovation in launching new products and improving processes. Technological innovation is, above all, the outcome of companies’ ceaseless R&D activities. Then, it is appropriate to measure innovation in terms of the costs invested in technological innovation. In addition, the R&D expense ratio has the advantages of easy measurement and collection of associated data, compared to the availability of data on new products, processes, sources, markets, and reorganization. In the case of new products, there is a problem of how they embrace many new characteristics to be recognized as new ones. It is also difficult to quantify and secure such data for numerous companies. For these reasons, many studies by [16,26,27,28,29,30] use the R&D ratio or R&D expenses as the innovation input variable. To control for corporate financial characteristics, we define the company size variable ( S i z e ), and the rate of sales growth variable (Growth), in Equation (14).
Despite the above-mentioned advantages, the R&D expense ratio for innovation inputs has a limit in that the indicator does not effectively account for aspects of innovation that are not associated with corporate R&D activities, such as new sources of supply, new market development, and business reorganization. In addition, the R&D expense ratio includes not only the cost spent in a knowledge utilization process (e.g., a process improvement), but also the cost input in the knowledge creation process (e.g., the discovery of new substances). Ref. [31] points out that the R&D ratio might be an inappropriate proxy for innovation.
I K t = α + β 1 Q t + β 2 R K t + β 3 R & D t + β 4 R & D t 2 + β 5 S i z e t + β 6 G r o w t h t + β 7 I d + β 8 Y d + ε t
where R & D , S i z e , and G r o w t h denote the R&D expense ratio, company size, and rate of sales growth, respectively.
To supplement the limitation of the R&D expense ratio of the innovation input, we measure a corporate innovation performance indicator of the innovation output. The innovation output indicator in this study is driven from the Cobb–Douglas production function. This indicator represents the portion of corporate gross profits not explained by capital stock and labor quantity. Corporate innovation (CI) contributes to the gross profits. If so, it would be more reasonable to view the term as an outcome of CI rather than CI itself.
l n G P t = l n C I t + a 1 l n K t + a 2 l n L t
where G P ,   C I ,   K ,   and   L denote the gross profits, corporate innovation, capital stock, and amount of labor, respectively.
Basically, Equation (15) is the modified form of the Cobb–Douglas production function, which indicates that a firm’s gross profit is a function of innovation, capital, and labor. l n G P   , l n K ,   and   l n L can be measured by taking the natural logarithm of gross profits in the income statement, total liabilities and equity on the balance sheet, and number of employees, respectively. Given that a 1   and   a 2 are known, the corporate innovation outcome ( C I O ) at time ( t ) can be derived using Equation (15). When one assumes that companies a 1   and   a 2 are constant, Equation (15) can be transformed into Equation (16) of a first-order differential type.
l n G P t = l n C I O t + a 1 l n K t + a 2 l n L t
We can consider the following regression model of Equation (17), where the first difference of the natural log of gross profits is the dependent variable, and the first differences of the natural log of capital stock and labor quantity are the explanatory variables. In Equation (18), α   and   ϵ denote the intercept and random error, respectively.
l n G P t = α + a 1 l n K t + a 2 l n L t + ε t
The estimates a 1 ^ and a 2 ^ for a 1 and a 2 are obtained by running the regression model of Equation (17), respectively. Substituting the estimated values a 1 ^ and a 2 ^ of innovation performance into the right-hand side of Equation (18) with the natural logarithm e as the base, we can obtain the estimated value C I O ^ for C I O , the corporate innovation outcome.
C I O t = ^ e l n G P t ( a 1 ^ l n K t + a 2 ^ l n L t )
Finally, our regression model of Equation (19) includes innovation performance variables, such as the innovation outcome indicator C I O in the regression model of Equation (14) above.
I K t = α + β 1 Q t + β 2 R K t + β 3 C I O t + β 4 S i z e t + β 5 G r o w t h t + β 6 I d + β 7 Y d + ε t
where C I O indicates the corporate innovation outcome.
Tobin’s average Q is measured by dividing the corporate value by total assets, and the corporate value is calculated using Equation (6). The expected recovery ratio of debt capital R K is calculated by dividing the expected recovery of debt capital, calculated in Equation (6), by the total assets. The explanatory variable of the R&D expense ratio R & D is calculated by dividing R&D expenses by sales. R&D expenses are calculated as the sum of assets and expenses accounting for R&D expenses. Asset-accounted R&D expenses are calculated by subtracting the R&D expenses of the previous year from that of the current period on the financial statement and adding the amortization amount for R&D expenses on the income statement. The innovation performance variable was measured in C I O [13]. For the regression analysis, we take the natural logarithm of this value.
Corporate temporary profits can be determined by non-innovative factors, such as market conditions, but long-term sustainable profit creation is the outcome of innovation [4]. Profits provide companies with substantial incentives to stimulate new investments. Therefore, corporate innovation is positively associated with corporate investment.
Ref. [1] argues that each company has an optimal level of R&D activities. To examine whether companies’ R&D activities beyond their optimal level are an impediment to their investments, we add the square of the R&D expense ratio R & D 2 in Equation (14). If R&D activities beyond the optimal level hinder corporate investments, R & D 2 is expected to have a negative coefficient. The control variable, company size (Size), is calculated by taking the natural logarithm of total assets. The larger the size of the company, the more diversified and lower the default risk; thus, large companies have more flexibility and cost advantage in raising capital than small companies [32]. By contrast, larger companies have a more complex decision-making structure. This nature of larger companies does not allow them to respond promptly and flexibly to changes in the business environment. Thus, company size has a negative relationship with investments. The rate of sales growth (= S a l e s t S a l e s t 2   −1) is measured as the geometric average growth rate of annual sales for the previous two years. An increase in market demand is an important factor that induces corporate investment, and the rate of sales growth is used as a proxy for the increase in market demand. Accordingly, we expect that the sales growth rate has a positive (+) relationship with a company’s investments.
For a simpler understanding on our methods, the complexity of the numerous equations can be visualized in the three following steps:
Step 1: Basic theoretical model in Equation (12):
I K t = δ 1 η + 1 η Q t 1 η R K t
Step 2: Augmented model 1 (innovation inputs model) for empirical analysis in Equation (14):
I K t = α + β 1 Q t + β 2 R K t + β 3 R & D t + β 4 R & D t 2 + β 5 S i z e t + β 6 G r o w t h t + β 7 I d + β 8 Y d + ε t
Step 3: Augmented model 2 (innovation outcome model) for empirical analysis in Equation (19):
I K t = α + β 1 Q t + β 2 R K t + β 3 C I o t + β 4 S i z e t + β 5 G r o w t h t + β 6 I d + β 7 Y d + ε t

3. Data Issues

This study focuses on companies listed on the Korea exchange that do not issue preferred stocks and are not engaged in the financial and construction industries according to industry classification over the full sample period from 2011 to 2019. Companies in the financial industry were excluded from our sample because the standard booking of financial statements is different from those of other industries. Companies in the construction industry are also excluded because their total assets and employee contribution to gross profits are different from those of other industries due to the existence of subcontracting.
Targeting listed companies in this study enables us to efficiently obtain data on the market value of equity capital and its volatility to calculate the expected recovery of debt capital, corporate value, and default risk. Companies issuing preferred stocks are excluded because we assume companies with no preferred stocks for the derivation of the research model above. Outliers with a debt capital ratio of one or more than 1 are excluded from our sample because they may distort the estimates.
Finally, we exclude holding companies, real estate and leasing businesses, hotels, and resorts that are not matched with the nature of this study, and companies whose data on the variables used in this study are unavailable during the sample periods. Through the above-mentioned process, we finally collect 3349 observations for 492 companies over the full sample period. Table 1 reports the sample companies by industry for the entire sample period. Including companies in agriculture, forestry, and fisheries; electricity, gas, steam, and water businesses; and wholesale and retail industries in Table 1, non-manufacturing companies refer to companies categorized into the remaining industries that do not fall into the manufacturing industry. Out of our full sample of 3349 companies, 2484 are overwhelmingly in the manufacturing sector and 865 are in the non-manufacturing sector.
All the data used in this study are collected from the KISVALUE (the KISVALUE is a paid database of Korean corporate financial statements and a variety of the data of the Korean stock markets operated by Korean NICE Ltd.). Table 2 presents the descriptive statistics for all the variables. Prior to our regression analysis, all the correlation coefficients for the pairs of the independent variables are overall low. The results suggest that there are no serious multicollinearities across the covariates. This enhances the reliance of the coefficients of the covariates estimated in the regressions (the specific results are not reported, to save space, but are available upon a request).

4. Empirical Results

This section discusses the regression results to investigate the effects of innovation on corporate investments. Table 3 presents the regression results for Tobin’s average Q on the corporate investment equation. The coefficient of Tobin’s average Q shows highly significant positive values (0.004, 0.004, 0.003) at the 1% level for the entire industry, manufacturing industry, and non-manufacturing companies, respectively. On the other hand, the expected recovery of debt capital R K shows significant negative coefficients (−0.010, 0.010) at the 1% level for all the companies and manufacturing companies, although the variable shows no significant value for the non-manufacturing companies. The results suggest that the investment ratio is positively associated with Tobin’s average Q and negatively associated with the expected recovery ratio of debt capital R K .
Table 4 presents the regression results for innovation on corporate investment. Regressions 2 and 3 estimate very significant positive coefficients (0.004, 0.003) at the 1% level for the Tobin’s average Q . By contrast, the two models estimate very significant negative values (−0.011, −0.009) at the 1% level for the expected recovery ratio of debt capital, R K . As for R&D expense ratio R & D and the square of R&D expense ratio R & D 2 , Regression 2 estimates no significant coefficient for either. However, in Regression 3, the innovation performance variable C O I shows a significantly positive coefficient (0.002) at the 1% level. Based on the regression results, we suggest that corporate investments could be promoted by the outcomes resulting from innovation rather than their input activities. In a similar line with our finding, Ref. [33] reports empirical evidence that the R&D activity enhances corporate investment responsiveness to the news of the present value of growth opportunities. With regard to the control variables, company size S i z e shows an insignificant coefficient on Regression 2 but a significant negative one (−0.002) at the 1% level on Regression 3. For the sales growth rate, both regressions estimate insignificant coefficients.
Table 5 shows the results of the regressions by classifying all the sample companies into manufacturing and non-manufacturing companies to check for whether there is a difference in the results by industry. In the case of manufacturing companies, Regressions 2-1 and 3-1 estimate the highly significant positive coefficients (0.004, 0.002) at the 1% level for Tobin’s average Q . In the case of non-manufacturing industries, the two regressions estimate highly significant values (0.003, 0.002) at the 5% level for the Tobin’s average Q , as well. For the manufacturing companies, the expected recovery ratio of debt capital R K shows the highly significant negative estimates (−0.011, −0.010) at the 1% level for Regressions 2-1 and 3-1. Meanwhile, for non-manufacturing companies, this variable has insignificant values in the regression models.
The coefficients of R&D ratio R & D and its square R & D 2 are not significant at the standard level, regardless of the types of industries in which the companies fall. This result suggests that corporate investments are not associated with innovation input activities. Interestingly and importantly, for the innovation outcome variable C I O , Regressions 3-1s estimate the highly significant positive coefficients (0.002, 0.002) at 1% and 5% levels, respectively, in the two sample groups of manufacturing and non-manufacturing companies. Our findings for both manufacturing and non-manufacturing companies confirm that innovation outcomes are an important factor in corporate investment, rather than innovation input activity itself.
In addition, we attempt to examine the persistent nature of the impacts of innovation in the previous period (t−1) on the investments in the current period (t), replacing the current time lag (t) of the independent variables with their previous time lag (t−1). Our regressions estimate the very significant coefficients (0.004, 0.003) for the first lag of the Tobin’s average Q t 1 at the 1% level. As for the first lag of the variable of the expected recovery ratio of debt capital R K t 1 , the regressions estimate the significant negative coefficients. The first lagged R&D expense ratio R & D t 1 and its first lagged square R & D 2 t 1 show insignificant values. These results indicate that both the input activities in the current period (t) for innovation and the input activities in the previous period (t−1) do not affect corporate investments. On the contrary, the first lag of the innovation outcome variable C I O t 1 shows a highly significant positive value. This result confirms that both the innovation performance of the current period (t) and the innovation performance of the previous period (t−1) are crucial factors in determining corporate investments (the specific results are untabulated to save space but are available upon request).

5. Discussion

This study aims to examine economic impacts of innovation on the sustainable investments of Korean companies, listed on the Korean exchange from 2011 to 2019. Extending the theories by [15,16], we establish a relationship between the investment ratio, Tobin’s average Q , and the debt capital’s expected recovery ratio. To empirically examine this relationship, we derive debt capital’s expected recovery ratio, using Black and Scholes’s [18] option pricing model. To test for Tobin’s average investment equation Q suggested by [15], we use the ratio of the expected recovery of the corporate debt capital. Complementing Hennessy’s model [15], this study is the first to explore the usefulness of Tobin’s average Q investment equation for Korean-listed companies, one of the leading countries in innovation and investment.
Our principal findings are as follows: First, corporate investments are positively associated with Tobin’s average Q proxied for corporate growth. This confirms that greater growth opportunities for companies promote greater investments. The expected recovery ratio of debt capital has a negative relationship with corporate investments, thus suggesting the debt capital’s expected recovery ratio to decrease corporate investments. Separating the full sample into companies in the manufacturing and non-manufacturing industries, our findings remain confirmed still.
Next and principally, the innovation outcomes have a significant positive effect on Korean-listed companies’ investments, regardless of the industries (i.e., manufacturing or non-manufacturing industries) of the sample companies. However, we find no relationship between the R&D expense ratio and corporate investment. These results of our main findings reflect that corporate investments are determined by the innovation outcomes rather than the input activities of the financial resources for innovation. To test for this, like Equations (14) and (19) above, we modified the investment model of Hennessy [15] on Equation (12). Specifically, Equation (14) estimates the relation between corporate input (R&D) and investment and Equation (19) estimates the relation between corporate innovation outcome (CIO) derived from the augmented Cobb–Douglas production function (Equation (15)) and corporate investment. Shortly, our main findings obtained by our investment model modified from the Hennessy investment model could shed invaluable light on the economic effect of corporate innovation (outcome) on the investment, given that there are few on the relationship between corporate innovation and investment. The flows of our analysis are in line with the three aforementioned steps of this study.
Importantly, as [8] addresses, both innovation and investment have been the source of capitalism and economic growth, following the beginning of the industrial revolution in the eighteenth century. In this respect, it should be meaningful to examine the relationship between innovation and investment at the levels of country, industry, and company, respectively. The empirical study on the relationship between innovation and investment is variously analyzed. As aforementioned, Ref. [8] using Austrian industry section data identifies the relationship between the instability of industry life cycles and growth trends. However, the study of [8] looks at the relationship between innovation and investment indirectly rather than directly. Along the similar vein, Ref. [34] demonstrates that innovation promoted in the public sector contributes to the increase in total factor productivity in the market. Unlike previous studies, our study directly empirically tested for whether corporate innovation promotes investment on tangible assets at the corporate level using the data of Korean-listed companies and found evidence of a significant positive relationship between both.

6. Conclusions

Our findings suggesting that corporate investments are predominately affected by the performances of corporate innovation provide policymakers with the necessity of seeking substantial policy instruments, to use the outcomes of innovation more effectively, rather than increasing the inputs of a variety of financial resources. To derive debt capital’s expected recovery ratio, we assume corporate value to follow a probabilistic process expressed in terms of expected return, volatility, and the winner process. Different assumptions for corporate value may cause differences in the empirical results, due to the under-estimation (or over-estimation) of debt capital’s expected recovery ratio, which could be a good venue for future studies on this topic.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, J.K. and H.L.; Validation, H.L.; Formal analysis, J.K.; Investigation, J.K. and H.L.; Data curation, J.K.; Writing—original draft, J.K.; Writing—review & editing, H.L.; Supervision, J.K.; Project administration, H.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This study was supported by research fund from Chosun University 2022.

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to the Editor and three anonymous referees for valuable comments to improve the article but are responsible for any remaining errors.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Czarnitzki, D.; Kraft, K. Innovation indicators and corporate credit ratings: Evidence from German firms. Econ. Lett. 2004, 82, 377–384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Fazzari, S.M.; Hubbard, R.G.; Petersen, B.C.; Blinder, A.S.; Poterba, J.M. Financing constraints and corporate investment. Brook. Pap. Econ. Act. 1988, 1, 141–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Kinney, M.; Trezevant, R.H. Taxes and the timing of corporate capital expenditure. J. Am. Tax. Assoc. 1993, 15, 40–62. [Google Scholar]
  4. Merton, R.C.; Bodie, Z. The design of financial systems: Towards a synthesis of function and structure. J. Investig. Manag. 2005, 3, 1–23. [Google Scholar]
  5. Tulchynska1, S.; Vovk, O.; Popelo, O.; Saloid, S.; Kostiunik, O. Innovation and investment strategies to intensify the potential modernization and to increase the competitiveness of microeconomic systems. Int. J. Comput. Sci. Netw. Secur. 2021, 21, 161–168. [Google Scholar]
  6. Wang, X.; Yu, J. Accumulating human capital: Corporate innovation and firm value. Financ. Res. Lett. 2023, forthcoming. [CrossRef]
  7. Kong, D.; Yang, Y.; Wang, Q. Innovative efficiency and firm value: Evidence from China. Int. Rev. Financ. 2023, forthcoming. [CrossRef]
  8. Courvisanos, J. The Dynamics of Innovation and Investment, with Application to Australia 1984–1998; MERIT Research Memoranda No. 003; MERIT, Maastricht Economic Research Institute on Innovation and Technology: Maastricht, The Netherlands, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  9. Crescenzi, R.; Gagliardi, L.; Iammarinoa, S. Foreign multinationals and domestic innovation: Intra-industry effects and firm heterogeneity. Res. Policy 2015, 44, 596–609. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Yue, W. Foreign direct investment and the innovation performance of local enterprises. Humanit. Soc. Sci. Commun. 2022, 9, 252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Liu, Y. Does innovation success reduce the cost of financing? Evidence from private investments in public equity. Financ. Res. Lett. 2022. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Kwak, T.; Lee, B.; Kwon, H. Does Tax Policy Affect Corporate Investment?: Tax Adjustment Tobin Empirical Analysis of Korea Using the q Model. Econ. Res. 2006, 54, 5–39. [Google Scholar]
  13. Kim, S.; Kim, J. The Effect of Innovation on Bankruptcy Risk. Bus. Stud. 2009, 38, 773–797. [Google Scholar]
  14. Lee, H.; Lee, K. The effects of technology innovation activity on CSR: Emphasizing the nonlinear and heterogenous effects. Sustainability 2021, 13, 10893. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Hennessy, C.A. Tobin’s Q, debt overhang, and investment. J. Financ. 2004, 59, 1717–1742. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Abbey, A.; Dickson, J.W. R&D work climate and innovation in semiconductors. Acad. Manag. J. 1983, 26, 362–368. [Google Scholar]
  17. He, M.; Estébanez, R.P. Exploring the relationship between R&D investment and business performance—An empirical analysis of Chinese ICT SMEs. Sustainability 2023, 15, 5142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Black, F.; Scholes, M. The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J. Political Econ. 1973, 81, 637–659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Merton, R.C. On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interest rates. J. Financ. 1974, 29, 449–470. [Google Scholar]
  20. Hull, J.C. Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 5th ed.; Prentice Hall: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  21. Chirinko, R. Tobin’s Q and financial policy. J. Monet. Econ. 1987, 19, 69–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Summers, L.H. Taxation and corporate investment: A q-theory approach. Brook. Pap. Econ. Act. 1981, 1, 67–127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. White, T.M. Debt, liquidity constraints, and corporate investment: Evidence from panel data. J. Financ. 1992, 47, 1425–1460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Datta, S.; Iskandar, M.; Patel, A. Some evidence on the uniqueness of initial public debt offerings. J. Financ. 2000, 56, 715–743. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Black, E.L.; Legoria, J.; Sellers, K.F. Capital investment effects of dividend imputation. J. Am. Tax. Assoc. 2000, 22, 40–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Capon, N.; Farley, J.U.; Lehman, D.R.; Hulbert, J.M. Profiles of product innovators among large U.S. manufacturers. Manag. Sci. 1992, 38, 157–169. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Kelm, K.M.; Narayanan, V.K.; Pinches, G.E. Shareholder value creation during R&D innovation and commercialization stages. Acad. Manag. J. 1995, 38, 770–786. [Google Scholar]
  28. Mohamed, M.M.A.; Liu, P.; Nie, G. Do knowledge economy indicators affect economic growth? Evidence from developing countries. Sustainability 2022, 14, 4774. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Palillo, J.G.; Brown, W.B. How organizational factors affect R&D innovation. Res. Manag. 1978, 2, 12–15. [Google Scholar]
  30. Robinson, W.T. Product innovation and start-up business market share performance. Manag. Sci. 1990, 36, 1279–1289. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Kleinknecht, A.; Montfort, K.V.; Brouwer, E. Non-trivial choice between innovation indicators. Econ. Innov. New Technol. 2002, 11, 109–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Molina, C.A. Are firms underleveraged? an examination of the effect of leverage on default probabilities. J. Financ. 2005, 60, 1427–1459. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Sanford, A.; Yang, M.J. Corporate investment and growth opportunities: The role of R&D capital complementarity. J. Corp. Financ. 2022, 72, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  34. Haskel, J.; Walis, G. Public support for innovation, intangible investment, and productivity growth in the UK market sector. Econ. Lett. 2013, 119, 195–198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. Classification of sample companies by industry over the entire sample period.
Table 1. Classification of sample companies by industry over the entire sample period.
IndustryNumber of
Samples
201120122013201420152016201720182019
Agriculture, Forestry,
Fishing
32443333444
Manufacturing2484262274240243242287302314320
Electricity, Gas, Steam, and Water Utilities62666679877
Wholesale
and Retail
359353733343543454750
Transportation118121312121215141414
Publishing, Video, Broadcasting communication, and Information services186192219181723262022
Etc.10813131191013121314
Sum3349351369324325326393411419431
Table 2. Descriptive statistic of each variable.
Table 2. Descriptive statistic of each variable.
VariablesMeanStandard
Deviation
MedianMinimumMaximum
I K Investment ratio0.0150.0270.002−0.0840.190
Q Tobin’s average Q 1.1330.6780.9370.3186.692
R K Expected recovery ratio on debt capital0.3850.1840.3830.0010.956
R & D R&D expense ratio0.0140.0350.0010.0000.676
C I O Corporate innovation outcome10.1251.01910.1034.19312.611
S i z e Corporate size26.5961.29426.38423.02432.300
GrowthRate of sales growth0.0480.2420.027−0.9586.242
Table 3. Regression results for Tobin’s average Q on corporate investment.
Table 3. Regression results for Tobin’s average Q on corporate investment.
Regression 1:
I K t = α + β 1 Q t + β 2 R K t + β 3 I d + β 4 Y d + ε t
VariablesAll the CompaniesManufacturing CompaniesNon-Manufacturing Companies
Constant0.010
(0.501)
0.010 ***
(0.000)
0.003
(0.368)
Q 0.004 ***
(0.000)
0.004 ***
(0.000)
0.003 ***
(0.014)
R K −0.010 ***
(0.000)
−0.010 ***
(0.000)
−0.003
(0.442)
I d InclusiveInclusiveInclusive
Y d InclusiveInclusiveInclusive
Adjusted  R 2 0.0660.0500.025
F -value12.240 ***14.060 ***7.370 ***
Observations33492484865
Notes: *** denotes significance at 1% level. Figures in brackets are p-values.
Table 4. Regression results of innovation on investment.
Table 4. Regression results of innovation on investment.
Regression 2:
I K   t = α + β 1 Q t + β 2 R K t + β 3 R & D t + β 4 R & D 2 t + β 5 S i z e t + β 6 G r o w t h t + β 7 I d + β 8 Y d + ε t
Regression 3:
I K t = α + β 1 Q t + β 2 R K t + β 3 C I t + β 4 S i z e t + β 5 G r o w t h t + β 6 I d + β 7 Y d + ε t
VariablesRegression 2Regression 3
Constant0.024
(0.202)
0.029
(0.121)
Q 0.004 ***
(0.000)
0.003 ***
(0.000)
R K −0.011 ***
(0.000)
−0.009 ***
(0.000)
R & D −0.028
(0.220)
R & D 2 −0.065
(0.329)
C I O 0.002 ***
(0.000)
S i z e −0.001
(0.158)
−0.002 ***
(0.000)
Growth0.002
(0.245)
0.002
(0.289)
I d InclusiveInclusive
Y d InclusiveInclusive
Adjusted  R 2 0.0690.071
F -value10.960 ***11.700 ***
Observations33493349
Notes: *** denotes significance at the 1% level. Figures in brackets are p-values.
Table 5. Regression results of innovation on corporate investment by industry.
Table 5. Regression results of innovation on corporate investment by industry.
Regression 2-1:
I K   t = α + β 1 Q t + β 2 R K t + β 3 R & D t + β 4 R & D 2 t + β 5 S i z e t + β 6 G r o w t h t + + β 7 Y d + ε t
Regression 3-1:
I K t = α + β 1 Q t + β 2 R K t + β 3 C I O t + β 4 S i z e t + β 5 G r o w t h t + β 7 Y d + ε t
VariablesManufacturing CompaniesNon-Manufacturing Companies
Regression 2-1Regression 3-1Regression 2-1Regression 3-1
constant0.034 ***
(0.000)
0.039 ***
(0.002)
−0.005
(0.735)
−0.002
(0.922)
Q 0.004 ***
(0.000)
0.002 ***
(0.009)
0.003 **
(0.024)
0.002 **
(0.048)
R K −0.011 ***
(0.000)
−0.010 ***
(0.001)
−0.004
(0.445)
−0.003
(0.498)
R & D −0.038
(0.135)
−0.022
(0.779)
R & D 2 −0.050
(0.477)
0.450
(0.472)
C I O 0.002 ***
(0.009)
0.002 **
(0.020)
S i z e −0.001
(0.059)
−0.002 ***
(0.001)
0.000
(0.587)
−0.001
(0.398)
Growth0.012 ***
(0.001)
0.011 ***
(0.002)
−0.002
(0.458)
−0.001
(0.513)
Y d InclusiveInclusiveInclusiveInclusive
Adjusted  R 2 0.0600.0580.0660.072
F -value12.320 ***12.790 ***5.380 ***6.180 ***
Observations24842484865865
Notes: *** and ** denote significance at 1% and 5% levels, respectively. Figures in brackets are p-values.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kim, J.; Lee, H. How Does Corporate Innovation Affect Sustainable Business Investment? Sustainability 2023, 15, 13367. https://doi.org/10.3390/su151813367

AMA Style

Kim J, Lee H. How Does Corporate Innovation Affect Sustainable Business Investment? Sustainability. 2023; 15(18):13367. https://doi.org/10.3390/su151813367

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kim, Jinsu, and Hyunchul Lee. 2023. "How Does Corporate Innovation Affect Sustainable Business Investment?" Sustainability 15, no. 18: 13367. https://doi.org/10.3390/su151813367

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop