Next Article in Journal
Green Lifestyle: A Tie between Green Human Resource Management Practices and Green Organizational Citizenship Behavior
Previous Article in Journal
Study on Urban Land Ecological Security Pattern and Obstacle Factors in the Beijing–Tianjin–Hebei Region
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

An Introductory Review of Input-Output Analysis in Sustainability Sciences Including Potential Implications of Aggregation

by
Jonas Bunsen
*,† and
Matthias Finkbeiner
Chair of Sustainable Engineering, Technische Universität Berlin, 10623 Berlin, Germany
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Current address: Fachgebiet für Sustainable Engineering, Technische Universität Berlin, Institut für Technischen Umweltschutz, Sekr. Z 1, Straße des 17. Juni 135, 10623 Berlin, Germany.
Sustainability 2023, 15(1), 46; https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010046
Submission received: 21 November 2022 / Revised: 13 December 2022 / Accepted: 14 December 2022 / Published: 20 December 2022

Abstract

:
Input-output analysis has become a widely established method in sustainability sciences. It is primarily used in macroeconomic footprint analyses for allocating an economy’s externalities among the agents in that economy based on the agents’ input-output interdependencies. However, databases for input-output analyses are commonly compiled by aggregating data. Aggregation of input-output data inevitably leads to a loss of information and in some instances can lead to misinformed decision-making. The goal of this paper is to provide a simple hands-on numerical introduction to input-output analysis including the potential implications of data aggregation in an original manner. First, the calculation of production-based and consumption-based inventories is introduced based on a dummy 2 × 2 input-output table. Next, the inventories of the 2 × 2 input-output table are compared with the production-based and consumption-based inventories of a corresponding non-aggregated 4 × 4 input-output table. A comparison of the inventories of both dummy input-output tables allows for an exemplary demonstration of inaccurate allocation as a result of data aggregation and to conclude on potential implications for decision-making. Overall, this work offers a succinct and numerically substantiated introductory review of input-output analysis for practitioners in sustainability sciences including the potential implications of aggregation of input-output data. Its simplistic approach sets this work apart from other publications on aggregation in input-output analysis that are founded in economics or econometrics.

1. Introduction

Over the last few centuries, humanity’s footprint on planet earth has grown dramatically. Particularly since the middle of the 20th century, the world’s population and its wealth have increased enormously and accompanied by an escalated anthropogenic appropriation of the earth’s resources and exhaustion of the earth’s capacity to absorb emissions [1,2,3]. It is now widely accepted that humanity’s current patterns of consumption and production cannot be sustained without causing significant and potentially threatening changes to the earth’s biosphere [4,5,6,7,8]. Consequently, individuals, organisations and entire nations have committed to reducing their ecological footprint, as well as the entirety of humanity’s ecological footprint. Hence, there is a need for robust methods and tools to examine which agents in the global economy are responsible for the extraction and emission of physical substances.
One such method is input-output analysis. Initially, input-output analysis was founded in macroeconomics by Wassily Leontief for investigating the interdependencies between producers and consumers based on their input-output interdependencies [9,10,11]. Later, Leontief formulated how “undesirable by-products … are linked directly to the network of physical relationships … of our economic system” and elaborated on “how such ‘externalities’ can be incorporated into the […] input-output picture of [an] economy” [10]. In other words, Leontief extended the initially macroeconomic application of input-output analysis with e.g., environmental or social metrics [10]. This expanded the scope of application of input-output analysis to topics commonly understood as sustainability sciences.
Leontief [10] and Kitzes [12] offer concise introductions to environmental input-output analysis. Leontief [10] provides a solid introduction to the basic mathematics of environmentally-extended input-output analysis, including the derivation of the structural matrix of an economy from a set of linear equations. A strength of Kitzes [12] is its straightforward approach and its accessibility for those without a mathematical background. Miller and Blair [11] has become a standard reference for input-output analysis and elaborates extensively on the foundations of input-output analysis, data organisation, input-output multipliers, incorporation of environmental and social metrics into input-output analysis, decomposition analysis and numerous other topics.
Input-output analysis has been applied in countless sustainability-related studies e.g., on cities [13,14,15,16,17,18], organisations [19,20], economic sectors [21,22], nations [23,24,25,26,27,28,29,30], local impacts of global trade [26,31,32] and other topics. The externalities analysed using input-output analyses are versatile, and include carbon emissions [17,18,33], biodiversity [34], land use [35,36], water consumption [24,37], human exploitation [38] and other indicators.
Building databases for input-output analyses involves the temporal, sectoral and regional aggregation of source data. For instance, several products or small sectors are typically aggregated into one large sector. Aggregation is applied if detailed information is lacking as well as to reduce calculation requirements. The importance of aggregation in input-output analysis has been recognised ever since and is subject to thorough scientific debate [9,10,39,40,41]. A review of scientific literature on aggregation in input-output analysis was first published by Kymn [42]. Fisher [40], Ara [43] and Neudecker [44] studied the optimisation of aggregation for minimising the loss of information. Lenzen [45] elaborated on aggregation versus disaggregation as well as on the disaggregation of environmentally relevant sectors and Wood et al. [46] studied sectoral harmonisation.
However, most of these works are founded in economics or econometrics and target expert practitioners of input-output analysis. However, input-ouput analysis is subject to ever-increasing popularity in sustainability sciences. Often, sustainability scientists have different scientific backgrounds and varying levels of technical knowledge and may not be experts in input-output analysis.
A concise and numerical introduction to input-output analysis including the potential implications of aggregation of input-output data for those without a strong technical background does not exist. Yet, the aggregation of input-output data and implications thereof can potentially undermine the robustness of input-output analysis-based assessments and, in worst-case scenarios, lead to misinformed decision-making.
Therefore, the main aim of this work is to provide an introductory review of input-output analysis including the potential implications of aggregation of input-output data based on numerically substantiated examples. This work aids sustainability scientists and policymakers in betters understanding the potential implications of aggregation of input-output data for their work.
In this work, instead of the frequently used terms environmentally-extended input-output analysis [12] and environmental input-output analysis [11], the term input-output analysis is used. The reason is that the former terms neglect that non-environmental externalities, e.g., social metrics, can as well be incorporated into input-output analyses [38,47,48,49,50]. This paper uses the terms direct and total intensities for monetary requirements and direct or total externalities for the externalities that are associated with the monetary requirements.
First, a dummy 2 × 2 input-output table is introduced (Section 2.1), structural path analysis (Section 2.2) and the calculation of production-based and consumption-based inventories (Section 2.3) is explained. Next, a dummy 4 × 4 input-output table is gradually introduced which serves as the hypothetical non-aggregated counterpart of the lower-resolved 2 × 2 input-output table (Section 2.4.1 and Section 2.4.2). Subsequently, the inventories of both differently-resolved input-output tables are calculated (Section 3.4.2) and subject to discussion (Section 4). This work concludes with a summary of the findings including the potential implications of aggregation in input-output analysis (Section 5).

2. Method

This work expands on Kitzes [12] and the 2 × 2 dummy input-output table published therein. Because this work is considered introductory, the fundamentals of input-output analysis are covered in-depth. Equations (1)–(6) are the same as in Kitzes. However, more in-depth explanations are given on structural path analysis, geometric series expansion and the Leontief Inverse Matrix including explanatory depictions. Section 3 shows the production-based and consumption-based inventories of the differently resolved dummy input-output tables, which makes possible a discussion of the differences in production-based and consumption-based inventories, as well as the potential implications of aggregation of input-output data.
Readers should note that the input-output table adapted from Kitzes is fictitious. Moreover, all input-output tables in this work are a stark simplification of real input-output tables which are significantly more complex and typically consist of thousands or ten thousands region-sector combinations.

2.1. Input-Output Tables

Input-output tables represent the input-output characteristics of a given economy for a specified period of time, e.g., a particular year. The represented economy could, for example, comprise the economy of a country, the entire world, selected regions or sub-national entities, such as that of states or provinces. Typically, an input-output table consists of the following components (see Figure 1 and Figure A1):
  • Transactions (T)
  • Final demand (Y)
  • Value-added (V)
  • Total output ( x o u t ) and total input ( x i n )
  • Satellite accounts (Q)
The economy in the dummy input-output table in Kitzes [12] comprises two sectors: Agriculture and Manufacturing (Figure 1). The rows in the transaction matrix (also known as the Intermediate Demand Matrix) contain the sectors’ output to all other sectors (production). For example, the Agriculture sector produces €8 of output for itself (intra-sectoral transaction) and €5 of output for the Manufacturing sector (inter-sectoral transaction). In addition, the Agriculture sector produces €3 of output to satisfy final demand (e.g., household consumption). The total output of the Agriculture sector is €16. Analogously, the columns in the transaction matrix contain the sectors’ input from all other sectors (consumption). For example, the Manufacturing sector consumes €5 from the Agriculture sector and €2 of input from itself. In addition, the Manufacturing sector consumes €5 of added value (e.g., capital and labour). The total output of the Manufacturing sector is €12.
For sustainability assessments, input-output tables can be extended by the sectors’ externalities e.g., resource use (water, land, etc.), emissions (nitrogen, phosphorous, greenhouse gases, etc.), environmental impacts (water scarcity, global warming potential, etc.), social- (working hours, occupational fatalities, etc.) and other metrics. These extensions are also referred to as satellite accounts (or environmental extensions). The satellite account of the input-output table in Figure 1 contains information on Water consumption—Total. It indicates that 8 m3 and 4 m3 of Water consumption—Total are associated with the sectors’ total output of €16 and €12 worth of produce, respectively.
Large input-output databases are typically given in a monetary unit. The reason is that transactions of all sorts of goods (e.g., wheat, cheese, ore, iron, cars, etc.) and services (e.g., insurance, medical care, banking, education, etc.) in an economy can all be converted into transactions in a common monetary unit. This allows the aggregation of thousands of goods and services into a manageable number of aggregated sectors.
Figure 1. Monetary 2 × 2 dummy input-output table based on Kitzes [12]. The sectors’ structural paths are shown in Figure 2. The externalities per production layer are shown in Figure 3 and Figure A2. The production-based and consumption-based inventories are given in Section 3.1 and shown in Figure A3. Orange: Intra-sectoral and inter-sectoral transactions (T); Yellow: Value added (V) and final demand (Y); Green: Sectors’ total input ( x i n ) and sectors’ total output ( x o u t ); Blue: Sectors’ satellite account(s) (Q).
Figure 1. Monetary 2 × 2 dummy input-output table based on Kitzes [12]. The sectors’ structural paths are shown in Figure 2. The externalities per production layer are shown in Figure 3 and Figure A2. The production-based and consumption-based inventories are given in Section 3.1 and shown in Figure A3. Orange: Intra-sectoral and inter-sectoral transactions (T); Yellow: Value added (V) and final demand (Y); Green: Sectors’ total input ( x i n ) and sectors’ total output ( x o u t ); Blue: Sectors’ satellite account(s) (Q).
Sustainability 15 00046 g001

2.2. Structural Path Analysis

Structural path analysis refers to the systematic tracing of a sector’s inputs from all other sectors on an infinite number of production layers based on the transaction matrix [51,52,53]. A structural path can broadly be understood as a sector’s supply chain [33,51]. Before conducting a structural path analysis, the transaction matrix T and the externalities q are normalised by the sectors’ total output x o u t . The normalisation yields the sectors’ input requirements from all other sectors to produce one unit of output, also referred to as Technical Coefficient Matrix A (Equation (1)), and the sectors’ externalities per one unit of output, herein referred to as the sectors’ direct externalities f (Equation (2)). Consequently, the results of the structural path analysis are given in externality per one unit of output.
A = T / x o u t = 8 5 4 2 / 16 12 = 8 / 16 5 / 12 4 / 16 2 / 12 = 0.50 0.42 0.25 0.17
f = q / x o u t = 8 4 / 16 12 = 8 / 16 4 / 12 = 0.50 0.33
In the following, an example of a structural path analysis is given. For instance, the Agriculture sector requires inputs from itself and the Manufacturing sector. Analogously, the Agriculture and Manufacturing sectors require inputs from sectors further up the supply chain. In theory, this trace can be continued indefinitely. However, for sustainability assessments a purely hierarchical description of the sectors’ structural paths is of limited informative value. Mostly, structural paths and the quantity of an externality associated with the respective structural path are of interest. The externalities associated with €1 of output from the Agriculture sector are calculated by multiplying the corresponding direct externality f A g r i c u l t u r e by €1, thus yielding 0.5 m 3 × 1 = 0.5 m 3 / . The externalities associated with €1 of output from the Agriculture sector on the subsequent production layers (first, second, third, etc.) are calculated by multiplying €1 by the corresponding series of technical coefficients and the direct externalities of the final sector in the structural path. For example, the externalities of the Manufacturing sector on the first production layer, the structural path AgricultureManufacturing, are 0.33 m 3 × 1 × 0.25 = 0.521 m 3 / . The externalities of the Agriculture sector on the second production layer, the structural path AgricultureManufacturingAgriculture, are 0.5 m 3 × 1 × 0.25 × 0.42 = 0.347 m 3 / (Figure 2). If this series is continued indefinitely, it becomes possible to determine a sector’s total externalities associated with €1 of the sector’s output.
Figure 2. Structural paths and the associated externalities of the Agriculture and Manufacturing sectors for the first three production layers (per one unit of final demand). The totals of the externalities of a given production layer are shown at the bottom (see also Figure 3 and Figure A2).
Figure 2. Structural paths and the associated externalities of the Agriculture and Manufacturing sectors for the first three production layers (per one unit of final demand). The totals of the externalities of a given production layer are shown at the bottom (see also Figure 3 and Figure A2).
Sustainability 15 00046 g002
For each production layer, the number of branches of a sector’s structural path equals the number of sectors in the input-output table to the power of the number of the production layer. In a 2 × 2 input-output table for example: zeroth production layer 2 0 = 1 branch; first production layer 2 1 = 2 branches; second production layer 2 2 = 4 branches; … tenth production layer 2 10 = 1024 branches, etc. Overall, a limited number of production layers contribute the highest proportion of a sector’s externalities (Figure A2) [51].
Figure 3. (A) Intensities (monetary requirements) associated with a single unit of final demand per production layer in € per €1; (B) Diagonalised direct externalities; (C) Externalities associated with a single unit of final demand per production layer in m3 per €1. The total of F i equals the sum of all externalities of all sectors on a production layer i in the structural path analysis in Figure 2. While the sum of externalities per production layer decreases with each ensuing production layer, the cumulative externalities from the considered production layers increase (Figure A2).
Figure 3. (A) Intensities (monetary requirements) associated with a single unit of final demand per production layer in € per €1; (B) Diagonalised direct externalities; (C) Externalities associated with a single unit of final demand per production layer in m3 per €1. The total of F i equals the sum of all externalities of all sectors on a production layer i in the structural path analysis in Figure 2. While the sum of externalities per production layer decreases with each ensuing production layer, the cumulative externalities from the considered production layers increase (Figure A2).
Sustainability 15 00046 g003

2.3. Production-Based and Consumption-Based Inventories

The calculation of production-based and consumption-based inventories based on matrix multiplication is a simpler approach than structural path analysis. Yet, often it is equally suitable for many research objectives and more straightforward if the goal is to allocate an externality between producers and consumers based on final demand.
If a matrix C is the product of two matrices A and B, each element in C is the result of multiplying each element in A with each corresponding element in B. C is then also referred to as the dot product of two matrices. In input-output analysis, the dot product is used to determine all externalities associated with the production of one unit of output on a given production layer. Mathematically, the dot product is the same as determining the structural paths and associated externalities of all sectors. The following paragraphs demonstrate an example of this process.
First, the transaction matrix T and externalities q are again normalised by the sectors’ total output x o u t (Equations (1) and (2)). On the zeroth production layer, the sectors’ externalities are equal to the direct externalities f. Mathematically, this is expressed by multiplying the direct externalities f by an identity matrix I (Equation (3) and Figure 4). However, multiplying a vector by a matrix yields a vector, which implies that one of the two dimensions of the input-output table, input (consumption) or output (production), is lost. To preserve both dimensions, the direct externality vector f is diagonalised ( f ^ ) before calculating the dot product.
F 0 = f ^ I = 0.50 0 0 0.33 × 1 0 0 1 = 0.5 0 0 0.33
The externalities from the subsequent production layers (first, second, third, etc.) are determined by calculating the dot product of f ^ and a series of the technical coefficient matrix A (Equation (4)). Eventually, the sum of the externalities from the zeroth ( F 0 ) and the externalities from an infinite number of subsequent production layers yields the sectors’ total externalities per unit of output F (Figure 3). Although the sum of externalities per production layer decreases with each ensuing production layer, the cumulative externalities from the considered production layers increase (Figure A2). If an input-output table contains more than one row of satellite accounts, this step can be repeated for each row of the satellite accounts separately.
F = f ^ I + f ^ A + f ^ A A + = 0.50 0 0 0.33 × 1 0 0 1 + 0.50 0 0 0.33 × 0.50 0.42 0.25 0.17 + 0.5 0 0 0.33 × 0.50 0.42 0.25 0.17 × 0.50 0.42 0.25 0.17 + = 1.33 0.67 0.27 0.53
To account for the total externalities on an infinite sum of production layers, the series expansion in Equation (4) can be rewritten using the Leontief Inverse Matrix L (Equation (5)).
F = f ^ L = f ^ ( I A ) 1 = 0.50 0 0 0.33 × 1 0 0 1 0.50 0.42 0.25 0.17 1 = 1.33 0.67 0.27 0.53
Finally, the sectors’ total externalities per unit of output F can be multiplied by a given region’s final demand to determine the total externalities associated with the region’s consumption (Equation (6)). The sum of the rows in E (outputs or production) is the production-based inventory. The sum of the columns in E (inputs or consumption) is the consumption-based inventory (see Figure 1).
E = F × y = 1.33 0.67 0.27 0.53 × 3 6 = 4.00 4.00 0.08 3.20

2.4. Disaggregating the Input-Output Table

Real input-output tables consist of significantly more sectors, regions, and satellite accounts than the dummy input-output in Figure 1. Typically, they consist of aggregated data. This leads to the question of potential implications of aggregation in input-output analysis. To address this question, in this section, we disaggregate the satellite accounts (Section 2.4.1) and sectors (Section 2.4.2) of the 2 × 2 dummy input-output in Figure 1 are disaggregated into hypothetical non-aggregated dummy input-output tables.

2.4.1. Disaggregating Satellite Accounts

A common approach to approximate a sector’s total externalities is to multiply the production volumes of products produced by the sector with the externalities associated with a single unit of each product’s production. If, for example, the Agriculture sector produces Wheat and Cotton, the sector’s total water consumption would be the sum of the production volumes of Wheat and Cotton multiplied by their respective water consumption, e.g., per ton of production. In the input-output table in Figure 4, the externalities of Water consumptionTotal of the 2 × 2 dummy-input-output table in Figure 1 is disaggregated into the separate externalities of Water consumptionCotton, Water consumptionWheat, Water consumptionTextiles and Water consumptionAgricultural machinery. The sum of these separate satellite accounts equals the externalities of Water consumptionTotal in the input-output table in Figure 1.
Figure 4. Hypothetical 2 × 2 dummy input-output table. Expanded based on the input-output table in Figure 1. The production-based and consumption-based inventories are shown in Figure 5.
Figure 4. Hypothetical 2 × 2 dummy input-output table. Expanded based on the input-output table in Figure 1. The production-based and consumption-based inventories are shown in Figure 5.
Sustainability 15 00046 g004
Figure 5. The production-based and consumption-based inventories of the input-output table are given in Figure 4. The numeric contributions of externalities are shown in Figure A5.
Figure 5. The production-based and consumption-based inventories of the input-output table are given in Figure 4. The numeric contributions of externalities are shown in Figure A5.
Sustainability 15 00046 g005

2.4.2. Disaggregating the Transaction- and Final Demand Matrix

Large input-output databases with hundreds or thousands of sectors are typically assembled by aggregating data from, e.g., annual macroeconomic databases with a high level of detail. To demonstrate the potential implications of aggregation in input-output analysis, also the sectors in the 2 × 2 dummy input-output in Figure 1 were subject to (hypothetical) disaggregation and a second region was introduced. The resulting 4 × 4 dummy input-output table is given in Figure 6 and can be interpreted as the non-aggregated correct or true counterpart of the 2 × 2 dummy input-output table in Figure 1.
It should be noted that the disaggregation did not change the total transaction volume, value-added, total input, final demand, total output, or sum of externalities. For example, the sum of all transactions among the agricultural sectors in the input-output table in Figure 6 is the same as the intra-sectoral transaction of the Agriculture sector in the input-output table in Figure 1 (€3 + €5 = €8). The same applies, e.g., to the total input of the manufacturing sectors (€0.25 + €3.75 + €1.25 + €0.5 + €0.5 + €0.25 + €0.5 = €5 + €2), final demand among all regions from the agriculture sectors (€1.5 + €0.25 + €0.75 + €0.5 = €3), the total output from the manufacturing sectors (€7.5 + €4.5 = €12), Water consumptionTotal from the agricultural sectors (6.5 m3 + 1.5 m3 = 8 m3), etc.
The 4 × 4 dummy input-output table in Figure 6 can be interpreted as a two-sector economy in which Region A has a rather agrarian economy, and a rather low final demand and Region B has a rather industrial economy and a rather high final demand. The agrarian economy of Region A is rather water-intensive. Region A’s staple crop (wheat) is mainly consumed domestically, while its cash crop (cotton) is mainly consumed abroad. The industrial economy of Region B has a rather low water intensity. Region B’s textile industry imports a lot of cotton from Region A and produces mainly for the domestic market. Region B’s agricultural machinery is mainly sold to Region A’s agricultural sectors.
Figure 6. Hypothetical 4 × 4 dummy input-output table. Expanded based on the input-output table in Figure 1. The production-based and consumption-based inventories are shown in Figure 7. See Figure A9 for a hypothetical counterpart of this input-output table with non-monetary values.
Figure 6. Hypothetical 4 × 4 dummy input-output table. Expanded based on the input-output table in Figure 1. The production-based and consumption-based inventories are shown in Figure 7. See Figure A9 for a hypothetical counterpart of this input-output table with non-monetary values.
Sustainability 15 00046 g006
Figure 7. Production-based and consumption-based inventories of Region A and Region B based on the monetary-based input-output in Figure 6. The exact quantities are given in Figure A6.
Figure 7. Production-based and consumption-based inventories of Region A and Region B based on the monetary-based input-output in Figure 6. The exact quantities are given in Figure A6.
Sustainability 15 00046 g007

2.5. Implementation

All calculations were done in the Python programming language [54] using the Pandas [55,56] and Numpy [57] libraries. The structural path analysis was conducted using pySPA [58]. The results plots were created with Matplotlib [59]. A most simple implementation of the basic steps of input-output analysis described in Kitzes [12] in Python is available via Zenodo [60].

3. Results

This section shows the production-based and consumption-based inventories of the input-output tables in Figure 1, Figure 4 and Figure 6. It also touches on the differences in the inventories and potential implications for policymaking. Section 4 discusses more general aspects with no specific reference to the calculated inventories. For definitions of production-based and consumption-based inventories, readers are advised to revisit Section 2.3 or refer to Table A1.

3.1. Baseline Input-Output Table

In the production-based inventory of the input-output table in Figure 1, 8 m3 and 4 m3 of Water consumption—Total induced by the final demand of Region A is allocated to the Agriculture and Manufacturing sectors, respectively (where the externality occurs). In the consumption-based inventory of the input-output table in Figure 1, 4.8 m3 and 7.2 m3 of Water consumption—Total created by the final demand of Region A is allocated to the Agriculture and Manufacturing sectors, respectively (which correspond to the final demand/consumption).
The comparison of the production-based and consumption-based inventories shows a shift in the allocation of a major share of Water consumption—Total from the Agriculture sector in the production-based inventory towards the Manufacturing sector in the consumption-based inventory (Figure A1). The reason for this is that a larger proportion of the output of the Agriculture sector is an input for the Manufacturing sector than for the Agriculture sector itself or the final demand of Region A. This means that a large proportion of the water consumption associated with the final demand from the Manufacturing sector originates from the Agriculture sector (Figure 1).
If the inventories are calculated for the entire final demand, the total amount of a satellite account is the same in the production-based and consumption-based inventories, and the production-based inventory is equal to the satellite account q.

3.2. Disaggregated Satellite Accounts

Figure 5 depicts the production-based and consumption-based inventories of the input-output table in Figure 4. The overall results are the same as those shown in the input-output table in Figure 1 (8 m3 and 4 m3 and 4.8 m3 and 7.2 m3 in the production-based and consumption-based inventories, respectively; see the previous section). However, disaggregating the Water consumption—Total satellite account into its (fictitious) subparts allows for a more in-depth analysis of the composition of the inventories. The production-based inventory shows that all water consumption associated with wheat (6 m3) and cotton (2 m3) originates from the Agriculture sector, and all water consumption associated with textiles (2.5 m3) and agricultural machinery (1.5 m3) originates from the Manufacturing sector. This is different compared to the consumption-based inventory, which comprises water consumption originating from all sectors. The added level of detail shows of what externalities an inventory consists of. This helps practitioners understanding the implications of aggregation in input-output analysis and potentially misleading inventories as a result (see Section 3.4).

3.3. Disaggregated Transactions and Final Demand—Production-Based Inventory

In the production-based inventory of the 4 × 4 dummy input-output in Figure 6 (Figure 7), 3.63 m3 of Water consumption—Wheat originating from Region A is allocated to Region A. The remaining 2.87 m3 are allocated to Region B. Although all the 1.5 m3 of Water consumption—Cotton originate from Region A, only 0.22 m3 are allocated to Region A, with the remainder allocated to Region B. Water consumption—Textiles and Water consumption—Agricultural machinery solely originate from Region B, but most of these externalities are also allocated to Region B. Nevertheless, the overall sum of the externalities allocated to agricultural sectors (wheat and cotton) and manufacturing sectors (textiles and agricultural machinery) in both regions are the same as in the inventories of the 2 × 2 dummy input-output tables (8 m3 and 4 m3).

3.4. Implications of Aggregation

3.4.1. Sectoral Contributions in the Consumption-Based Inventory

The externalities allocated to the agricultural sectors (AgricultureWheat and AgricultureCotton) and the manufacturing sectors (ManufacturingTextiles and ManufacturingAgricultural machinery) in the production-based inventory of the 4 × 4 dummy input-output table in Figure A8 are different compared to the externalities allocated to the agricultural (Agriculture) and manufacturing (Manufacturing) sectors in the production-based inventory of the 2 × 2 dummy input-output table in Figure A7. Instead of 4.8 m3 (as in the 2 × 2 dummy input-output table), in the 4 × 4 input-output table 6.06 m3 of water consumption (3.63 m3 + 0.21 m3 + 1.82 m3 + 0.41 m3 = 6.06 m3) is allocated to the agricultural sectors (1.26 m3 or 26.3% more; see Table 1). Instead of 7.2 m3 in the 2 × 2 dummy input-output table, in the 4 × 4 input-output table 5.94 m3 of water consumption (0.49 m3 + 5.44 m3 = 5.94 m3) is allocated to the manufacturing sectors (1.57 m3 or 17.5% less; see Table 1).

3.4.2. Composition of the Externalities in the Consumption-Based Inventory

The consumption-based inventory of the 2 × 2 input-output table in Figure 4 suggests that Region A’s final demand from both sectors, Agriculture and Manufacturing, causes most externalities through Water consumption—Wheat (Figure 5). In contrast, the consumption-based inventory of the 4 × 4 input-output table in Figure 6 suggests that both regions’ manufacturing sectors together cause the most externalities, through Water consumption—Textiles followed by Water consumption—Cotton (Figure 7). If it is assumed that the 4 × 4 input-output table provides a more accurate representation of the fictitious economy, the less detailed aggregated 2 × 2 input-output table would misinform any decision-making process. Table 2 summarises the differences in the allocation of the externalities in the consumption-based inventories of the 2 × 2 and 4 × 4 dummy input-output tables. The values can be interpreted as the changes in the inventories because of aggregation. Table 2 shows that the aggregation led to:
  • An increase in the allocation of Water consumption—Cotton from the agricultural sectors (AgricultureWheat and AgricultureCotton) to the Agriculture sector by +141.5%
  • An increase in the allocation of Water consumption—Wheat from the manufacturing sectors (ManufacturingTextiles and ManufacturingAgricultural machinery) to the Manufacturing sector by +185%
  • An increase in the allocation of Water consumption—Textiles from the agricultural sectors (AgricultureWheat and AgricultureCotton) to the Agriculture sector by +1040%
  • An increase in the allocation of Water consumption—Agricultural machinery from the manufacturing sectors (ManufacturingTextiles and ManufacturingAgricultural machinery) to the Manufacturing sector by 42.5%
  • … as well as corresponding decreases in the allocation of water consumption to the other sectors.

4. Discussion

This section reflects on the implications of aggregation in input-output analysis (Section 4.1) and lists some of the most established input-output databases (Section 4.2). It concludes with a summary of the study’s limitations (Section 4.3).

4.1. Aggregation

In input-output analysis, the input mixes of all sectors consuming from another sector are proportional to the producing sector’s output mix. Leontief formulated this as “the distribution […] among the different consumers is made […] on a strictly proportional basis. For each kind of use, each source of supply is drawn upon in proportion to its total output” [9]. In most cases, this is unlikely to be the case in any real economic scenario. Consequently, aggregation of economic data in input-output tables inevitably leads to loss of information and distorted inventories (Section 3.2). The comparison of the inventories of differently-resolved input-output tables (Figure 1, Figure 4 and Figure 6) has shown the potential implications e.g., in a worst case, misinformed decision-making. In the given examples, the difference in allocation between the differently resolved input-output tables diverges by more than 1000% for one specific sector and by more than 100% for two other sectors (Table 2). Other studies on aggregation in input-output analysis corroborate these observations. Bouwmeester and Oosterhaven [61] analysed regional and sectoral aggregation errors of carbon dioxide emissions and water use. Steen-Olsen et al. [62] investigated the required level of detail of input-output data to mitigate the effects of sectoral aggregation. De Koning et al. [63] applied a scenario-based approach to investigate the effects of sectoral aggregation, satellite account aggregation and regional aggregation. Schulte et al. [64] quantified the aggregation-induced uncertainty in the Exiobase database and found particularly high coefficients of variations for small economies with a high share of trade.
To improve the robustness of input-output analyses, scholars have repeatedly advocated the development of input-output databases with a high resolution [9,65,66,67]. This endeavour was also formulated by Wassily Leontief [9] who suggested that “a distribution of all […] transactions among some smaller, more homogeneous, quasi-independent accounting units appears to be highly desirable” and, despite major advancements, continues. Yet, for the near future, even the most comprehensive input-output tables for sustainability assessments will always be subject to aggregation. Therefore, practitioners’ awareness of and clear communication of potential aggregation-induced distortions of inventories is crucial. Particular attention should be paid to those sectors, products or product groups that are of high relevance concerning a study’s objective or the externality under study. For instance, concerning agricultural primary production. According to best practice, some input-output tables feature dedicated sectors for the most prevalent staple crops such as rice or wheat [68,69].
Alternatively, practitioners can develop custom satellite accounts to best meet the requirements of their research objective. However, eventually, the resolution of any satellite account must match the input-output data’s given level of aggregation. Even if this implies aggregating data concerning an externality with a resolution higher than the resolution of the input-output data. Nonetheless, providing separate satellite accounts for the aggregated externalities can still introduce transparency regarding the composition of inventories (Section 3.2). This can help practitioners better understand the impacts of aggregation on their research results—and the implications this has for decision-making. An approach superior to working with separate satellite accounts is to disaggregate input-output data through hybridisation with other data sources offering a higher resolution [45]. A challenge in hybridisation that remains is that even if a sector has been disaggregated, it is often unknown for which sectors the disaggregated outputs serve as an input [66].

4.2. Input-Output Databases

A recent overview of input-output databases for sustainability assessments was published by Pfister and Kulionis [70]. It covers the Eora [71,72], Exiobase [69,73], WIOD [74], GTAP [75] and OECD ICIO [76] databases. More recently published input-output databases for sustainability assessments include RMRIO [77,78], FABIO [79] and GLORIA [68]. RMRIO is a merge of the Eora and Exiobase databases. FABIO is a food and agriculture biomass input-output model. At the time of writing, GLORIA is the most comprehensive global generic input-output database in terms of regional and sectoral coverage.

4.3. Limitations

Both, the 2 × 2 dummy input-output table in Figure 1 by Kitzes [12] as well as the hypothetically non-aggregated 4 × 4 dummy input-output tables in Figure 4 and Figure 6 are fictitious. The input-output tables were devised to facilitate an accessible yet comprehensive introduction to input-output analysis and the implications aggregation has for decision-making. None of the given tables represents the full complexity of real input-output databases. It should also be noted that aggregation can as well be performed in an optimised manner to minimise the effects of aggregation.
It is worth taking note that production-based and consumption-based allocation schemes are the two opposite extremes along a more nuanced range of avaialble allocation schemes. Other allocation schemes include extraction-based, income-based, and value-based [80] as well as combinations thereof such as shared producer and consumer responsibility [81].
This study did not cover the derivation of an input-output table from a set of linear equations. Readers interested in this matter are referred to Leontief [10]. To better understand how input-output analysis is founded in the field of economics, readers are advised to resort to the literature referenced in the introduction e.g., Miller and Blair [11] who published the most exhaustive overview of input-output analysis.

5. Conclusions

Albeit having been found in economics, input-output analyses have become an established tool in sustainability sciences for allocating the externalities of a given economy to agents in that economy based on the agents’ input-output interdependencies.
This work aimed to provide a hands-on introduction to input-output analysis with a particular focus on the potential effects of the aggregation of input-output data. For this, a set of differently resolved fictitious dummy input-output tables was presented. The production-based and consumption-based inventories of the presented tables were compared which allowed for demonstrating the potential effects of aggregation. This work’s numerical and hands-on approach communicates the topic of aggregation in input-output analysis in an original manner and targets non-technical practitioners of input-output analysis from the field of sustainability sciences to whom this work aims to offer new perspectives. It supplements other works on aggregation in input-output analysis, some of which are summarised in Section 1.
This work has demonstrated that aggregation of input-output data, which is rather the rule than the exception, can distort the allocation of externalities in consumption-based inventories. In worst-case scenarios, this can lead to misinformed decision-making. Consequently, it is crucial to always consider the potential implications of aggregation in input-output analysis-based assessments and in the decision-making processes that involve input-output analysis-based assessments. In many input-output analysis-based studies, however, aggregation is not considered or receives negligible attention.
Assessments based on input-output analysis can offer valuable insights for exploring many sustainability-related macroeconomic research questions. Consequently, input-output analysis is an essential method in sustainability sciences, and the endeavour to develop ever more comprehensive and detailed input-output databases, possibly with specific foci, continues and keeps improving input-output analysis-based assessments. In the meantime, practitioners should carefully consider the potential implications of aggregation in input-output analysis-based assessments and communicate findings transparently and with consideration of the potential effects of the aggregation of input-output data.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, J.B.; methodology, J.B.; formal analysis, J.B.; data curation, J.B.; writing—original draft preparation, J.B.; writing—review and editing, J.B. and M.F.; visualization, J.B.; supervision, M.F. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

We acknowledge support by the German Research Foundation and the Open Access Publication Fund of TU Berlin.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. Supplementary Information on Input-Output Analysis

Figure A1. Schematic illustration of the typical structure of an input-output table. See Figure 1 (2 × 2), Figure 4 (4 × 4) and Figure 6 (4 × 4) for numeric dummy input-output tables with different dimensions.
Figure A1. Schematic illustration of the typical structure of an input-output table. See Figure 1 (2 × 2), Figure 4 (4 × 4) and Figure 6 (4 × 4) for numeric dummy input-output tables with different dimensions.
Sustainability 15 00046 g0a1
Table A1. Definitions of the terms “production-based inventory” and “consumption-based inventory”. See Section 3.2 in the manuscript for additional allocation schemes.
Table A1. Definitions of the terms “production-based inventory” and “consumption-based inventory”. See Section 3.2 in the manuscript for additional allocation schemes.
InventoryPeters [82]Wood et al. [73]Arnold et al. [80]
Production-based“Domestic production including exports”“The production-based indicators account for the value added as well as the substances emitted within the geographical bounds of a region or country.”“emissions generated during production. Responsibility is fully allocated to producers of goods and services where they occur in the value chain.”
Consumption-based“Domestic consumption ([excluding] exports but includ[ing] imports)”“On the other hand, consumption-based indicators (footprints) represent the direct and indirect value added/emitted substances caused by the final demand in a specific country or region.”“emissions generated for satisfying consumption. Responsibility of life cycle emissions is fully allocated to final consumers of goods and services.”

Appendix B. Supplementary Information on the Results

Figure A2. (A) The externalities associated with a single unit of final demand; (B) The externalities associated with the total final demand of Region A; Both are given per production layer (absolute) and cumulative. Calculated based on the 2 × 2 dummy input-output table in Figure 1. More than 95% of all externalities accrue on the first nine production layers. The figures were determined using series expansion (see Equation (4) and Figure 3) and can also be determined using structural path analysis (see Figure 2).
Figure A2. (A) The externalities associated with a single unit of final demand; (B) The externalities associated with the total final demand of Region A; Both are given per production layer (absolute) and cumulative. Calculated based on the 2 × 2 dummy input-output table in Figure 1. More than 95% of all externalities accrue on the first nine production layers. The figures were determined using series expansion (see Equation (4) and Figure 3) and can also be determined using structural path analysis (see Figure 2).
Sustainability 15 00046 g0a2
Figure A3. The production-based and consumption-based inventories of the input-output in Figure 1.
Figure A3. The production-based and consumption-based inventories of the input-output in Figure 1.
Sustainability 15 00046 g0a3
Figure A4. (Re-)Aggregated production-based and consumption-based inventories from Figure 7. The figure allows a comparison of the production-based inventories of the input-output table in Figure 5 (2 × 2) shown in Figure 4 with the production-based and consumption-based inventory of the input-output table in Figure 6 (4 × 4) shown in Figure 7.
Figure A4. (Re-)Aggregated production-based and consumption-based inventories from Figure 7. The figure allows a comparison of the production-based inventories of the input-output table in Figure 5 (2 × 2) shown in Figure 4 with the production-based and consumption-based inventory of the input-output table in Figure 6 (4 × 4) shown in Figure 7.
Sustainability 15 00046 g0a4

Heat Maps

Figure A5. The production-based and consumption-based inventories of the monetary input-output table in Figure 4. See Figure 5 for the corresponding bar charts.
Figure A5. The production-based and consumption-based inventories of the monetary input-output table in Figure 4. See Figure 5 for the corresponding bar charts.
Sustainability 15 00046 g0a5
Figure A6. The production-based and consumption-based inventories of the monetary input-output table in Figure 6. See Figure 7 for the corresponding bar chart.
Figure A6. The production-based and consumption-based inventories of the monetary input-output table in Figure 6. See Figure 7 for the corresponding bar chart.
Sustainability 15 00046 g0a6

Appendix C. Supplementary Information on the Implications of Aggregation

Figure A7. (A) Production-based and consumption-based inventories of the input-output in Figure 4; (B.1) Production-based and consumption-based inventories associated with the final demand of Region A in the input-output in Figure 6; (B.2) Production-based and consumption-based inventories associated with the final demand of Region B in the input-output table in Figure 6; (C) A comparison of the sums of the contributions by the agricultural sectors (wheat and cotton) and manufacturing sectors (textiles and agricultural machinery) in the inventories of the 4 × 4 dummy input-output table (A) and the contributions of the agriculture and machinery sectors in the 2 × 2 dummy input-output table (B.1,B.2). The background colours of the cells indicate which cells were used to calculate the respective sums (see Section 3.4).
Figure A7. (A) Production-based and consumption-based inventories of the input-output in Figure 4; (B.1) Production-based and consumption-based inventories associated with the final demand of Region A in the input-output in Figure 6; (B.2) Production-based and consumption-based inventories associated with the final demand of Region B in the input-output table in Figure 6; (C) A comparison of the sums of the contributions by the agricultural sectors (wheat and cotton) and manufacturing sectors (textiles and agricultural machinery) in the inventories of the 4 × 4 dummy input-output table (A) and the contributions of the agriculture and machinery sectors in the 2 × 2 dummy input-output table (B.1,B.2). The background colours of the cells indicate which cells were used to calculate the respective sums (see Section 3.4).
Sustainability 15 00046 g0a7
Figure A8. (A) Comparison of the allocation of externalities from the consumption-based inventory of the input-output table in Figure 4; (B) Consumption-based inventories associated with the final demand of Region A and Region B in the input-output table in Figure 6; (C) A sectoral comparison of the consumption-based inventories of the 2 × 2 and 4 × 4 input-output tables in Figure 4 and Figure 6, respectively. The background colours of the cells indicate which cells were used to calculate the respective sums (see Section 3.4.2).
Figure A8. (A) Comparison of the allocation of externalities from the consumption-based inventory of the input-output table in Figure 4; (B) Consumption-based inventories associated with the final demand of Region A and Region B in the input-output table in Figure 6; (C) A sectoral comparison of the consumption-based inventories of the 2 × 2 and 4 × 4 input-output tables in Figure 4 and Figure 6, respectively. The background colours of the cells indicate which cells were used to calculate the respective sums (see Section 3.4.2).
Sustainability 15 00046 g0a8

Appendix D. Non-Monetary Input-Output Table

In theory, monetary input-output tables can be derived from non-monetary input-output tables based on the value of transferred goods and services. An example is given in Figure A9, which is the non-monetary counterpart of the monetary input-output table in Figure 6. The production-based and consumption-based inventories of the input-output table in Figure A9 are the same as those of the input-output in Figure A6 (Figure A8). A major advantage of non-monetary input-output tables is that they are not affected by currency conversions, subsidies or taxation schemes [83]. However, large input-output databases are the result of complex aggregation processes, and usually each sector covers a heterogeneous range of products and services [84].
Figure A9. A hypothetical non-monetary input-output table based on Figure 6 in the manuscript. The conversion factors for turning the monetary values in the input-output in Figure 6 into non-monetary values are given in the bottom-right corner. The production-based and consumption-based inventories are shown in Figure 7 in the manuscript.
Figure A9. A hypothetical non-monetary input-output table based on Figure 6 in the manuscript. The conversion factors for turning the monetary values in the input-output in Figure 6 into non-monetary values are given in the bottom-right corner. The production-based and consumption-based inventories are shown in Figure 7 in the manuscript.
Sustainability 15 00046 g0a9

References

  1. McNeill, J.R. The Great Acceleration: An Environmental History of the Anthropocene since 1945; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Steffen, W.; Sanderson, R.A.; Tyson, P.D.; Jäger, J.; Matson, P.A.; Moore, B., III; Oldfield, F.; Richardson, K.; Schellnhuber, H.J.; Turner, B.L.; et al. Global Change and the Earth System: A Planet Under Pressure; Global Change—The IGBP Series; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Steffen, W.; Richardson, K.; Rockstrom, J.; Cornell, S.E.; Fetzer, I.; Bennett, E.M.; Biggs, R.; Carpenter, S.R.; de Vries, W.; de Wit, C.A.; et al. Planetary boundaries: Guiding human development on a changing planet. Science 2015, 347, 1259855. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  4. Meadows, D.H.; Meadows, D.L.; Randers, J.; Behrens, W.W. The Limits to Growth: A Report for the Club of Rome’s Project on the Predicament of Mankind, 2nd ed.; Universe Books: New York, NY, USA, 1972. [Google Scholar]
  5. Rockström, J.; Steffen, W.; Noone, K.; Persson, A.; Chapin, F.S.; Lambin, E.F.; Lenton, T.M.; Scheffer, M.; Folke, C.; Schellnhuber, H.J.; et al. A safe operating space for humanity. Nature 2009, 461, 472–475. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  6. Rockström, J.; Steffen, W.; Noone, K.; Persson, A.; Chapin, F.S.I.; Lambin, E.; Lenton, T.M.; Scheffer, M.; Folke, C.; Schellnhuber, H.J.; et al. Planetary Boundaries: Exploring the Safe Operating Space for Humanity. Ecol. Soc. 2009, 14, art32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Masson-Delmotte, V.; Zhai, P.; Pirani, A.; Connors, S.L.; Péan, C.; Berger, S.; Caud, N.; Chen, Y.; Goldfarb, L.; Gomis, M.I.; et al. (Eds.) Climate Change 2021: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  8. WCED. Our Common Future; Oxford Paperbacks; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK; New York, NY, USA, 1987. [Google Scholar]
  9. Leontief, W. Quantitative input and output relations in the economic systems of the United States. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1936, 18, 105–125. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Leontief, W. Environmental Repercussions and the Economic Structure: An Input-Output Approach. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1970, 52, 262–271. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Miller, R.E.; Blair, P.D. Input–Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions, 2nd ed.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2009; p. 784. [Google Scholar]
  12. Kitzes, J. An Introduction to Environmentally-Extended Input-Output Analysis. Resources 2013, 2, 489–503. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Chen, B.; Han, M.; Peng, K.; Zhou, S.; Shao, L.; Wu, X.; Wei, W.; Liu, S.; Li, Z.; Li, J.; et al. Global land-water nexus: Agricultural land and freshwater use embodied in worldwide supply chains. Sci. Total Environ. 2018, 613–614, 931–943. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Hung, C.C.W.; Hsu, S.C.; Cheng, K.L. Quantifying city-scale carbon emissions of the construction sector based on multi-regional input-output analysis. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2019, 149, 75–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Lenk, C.; Arendt, R.; Bach, V.; Finkbeiner, M. Territorial-Based vs. Consumption-Based Carbon Footprint of an Urban District—A Case Study of Berlin-Wedding. Sustainability 2021, 13, 7262. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Long, Y.; Yoshida, Y. Quantifying city-scale emission responsibility based on input-output analysis—Insight from Tokyo, Japan. Appl. Energy 2018, 218, 349–360. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Moran, D.; Kanemoto, K.; Jiborn, M.; Wood, R.; Többen, J.; Seto, K.C. Carbon footprints of 13.000 cities. Environ. Res. Lett. 2018, 13, 064041. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Wiedmann, T.; Chen, G.; Owen, A.; Lenzen, M.; Doust, M.; Barrett, J.; Steele, K. Three-scope carbon emission inventories of global cities. J. Ind. Ecol. 2021, 25, 735–750. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Martinez, S.; Marchamalo, M.; Alvarez, S. Organization environmental footprint applying a multi-regional input-output analysis: A case study of a wood parquet company in Spain. Sci. Total Environ. 2018, 618, 7–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Martinez, S.; Delgado, M.d.M.; Martinez Marin, R.; Alvarez, S. Organization Environmental Footprint through Input-Output Analysis: A Case Study in the Construction Sector. J. Ind. Ecol. 2019, 23, 879–892. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Acquaye, A.A.; Duffy, A.P. Input–output analysis of Irish construction sector greenhouse gas emissions. Build. Environ. 2010, 45, 784–791. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Martínez-Blanco, J.; Forin, S.; Finkbeiner, M. Challenges of organizational LCA: Lessons learned from road testing the guidance on organizational life cycle assessment. Int. J. Life Cycle Assess. 2020, 25, 311–331. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Lenzen, M. An input–output analysis of Australian water usage. Water Policy 2001, 3, 321–340. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Zhang, C.; Anadon, L.D. A multi-regional input–output analysis of domestic virtual water trade and provincial water footprint in China. Ecol. Econ. 2014, 100, 159–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Dawkins, E.; Moran, D.; Palm, V.; Wood, R.; Björk, I. The Swedish footprint: A multi-model comparison. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 209, 1578–1592. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Bunsen, J.; Berger, M.; Finkbeiner, M. Planetary boundaries for water—A review. Ecol. Indic. 2021, 121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Wiedmann, T.O.; Schandl, H.; Lenzen, M.; Moran, D.; Suh, S.; West, J.; Kanemoto, K. The material footprint of nations. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2015, 112, 6271–6276. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  28. Wiedmann, T.; Wood, R.; Minx, J.C.; Lenzen, M.; Guan, D.; Harris, R. A Carbon Footprint Time Series of the Uk—Results from a Multi-Region Input–Output Model. Econ. Syst. Res. 2010, 22, 19–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Tukker, A.; Bulavskaya, T.; Giljum, S.; Koning, A.d.; Lutter, S.; Simas, M.; Stadler, K.; Wood, R. The Global Resource Footprint of Nations. Carbon, Water, Land and Materials Embodied in Trade and Final Consumption, Calculated with EXIOBASE 2.1; TNO: The Hague, The Netherlands, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  30. Ivanova, D.; Stadler, K.; Steen-Olsen, K.; Wood, R.; Vita, G.; Tukker, A.; Hertwich, E.G. Environmental Impact Assessment of Household Consumption. J. Ind. Ecol. 2016, 20, 526–536. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Lenzen, M.; Moran, D.; Bhaduri, A.; Kanemoto, K.; Bekchanov, M.; Geschke, A.; Foran, B. International trade of scarce water. Ecol. Econ. 2013, 94, 78–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Moran, D.; Kanemoto, K. Tracing global supply chains to air pollution hotspots. Environ. Res. Lett. 2016, 11, 094017. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  33. Davis, S.J.; Peters, G.P.; Caldeira, K. The supply chain of CO2 emissions. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2011, 108, 18554–18559. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  34. Lenzen, M.; Moran, D.; Kanemoto, K.; Foran, B.; Lobefaro, L.; Geschke, A. International trade drives biodiversity threats in developing nations. Nature 2012, 486, 109–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Bjelle, E.L.; Többen, J.; Stadler, K.; Kastner, T.; Theurl, M.C.; Erb, K.H.; Olsen, K.S.; Wiebe, K.S.; Wood, R. Adding country resolution to EXIOBASE: Impacts on land use embodied in trade. J. Econ. Struct. 2020, 9, 14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Bjelle, E.L.; Kuipers, K.; Verones, F.; Wood, R. Trends in national biodiversity footprints of land use. Ecol. Econ. 2021, 185, 107059. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Bunsen, J.; Berger, M.; Ward, H.; Finkbeiner, M. Germany’s global water consumption under consideration of the local safe operating spaces of watersheds worldwide. Clean. Responsible Consum. 2021, 3, 100034. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Shilling, H.J.; Wiedmann, T.; Malik, A. Modern slavery footprints in global supply chains. J. Ind. Ecol. 2021, 25, 1518–1528. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Theil, H. Linear Aggregation in Input-Output Analysis. Econometrica 1957, 25, 111–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Fisher, W.D. Criteria for Aggregation in Input-Output Analysis. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1958, 40, 250–260. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Miller, R.E.; Blair, P. Spatial aggregation in interregional input-output models. Pap. Reg. Sci. Assoc. 1981, 48, 149–164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Kymn, K.O. Aggregation in Input–Output Models: A Comprehensive Review, 1946–71. Econ. Syst. Res. 1990, 2, 65–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Ara, K. The Aggregation Problem in Input-Output Analysis. Econometrica 1959, 27, 257–262. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Neudecker, H. Aggregation in Input-Output Analysis: An Extension of Fisher’s Method. Econometrica 1970, 38, 921–926. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Lenzen, M. Aggregation Versus Disaggregation in Input–Output Analysis of the Environment. Econ. Syst. Res. 2011, 23, 73–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Wood, R.; Hawkins, T.R.; Hertwich, E.G.; Tukker, A. Harmonising National Input—Output Tables for Consumption-Based Accounting—Experiences from Exiopol. Econ. Syst. Res. 2014, 26, 387–409. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Papong, S.; Itsubo, N.; Malakul, P.; Shukuya, M. Development of the Social Inventory Database in Thailand Using Input–Output Analysis. Sustainability 2015, 7, 7684–7713. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  48. Costa, D.; Quinteiro, P.; Pereira, V.; Dias, A.C. Social life cycle assessment based on input-output analysis of the Portuguese pulp and paper sector. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 330, 129851. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Benoît Norris, C.; Norris, G. Chapter 8: The Social Hotspots Database Context of the SHDB. In The Sustainability Practitioner’s Guide to Social Analysis and Assessment; McBain, D., Murray, J., Wiedmann, T., Eds.; Common Ground Research Networks: Champaign, IL, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  50. Ciroth, A.; Eisfeldt, F. A new, comprehensive database for social LCA: PSILCA. In Proceedings of the ILCM 2015, New Delhi, India, 14–15 September 2015. [Google Scholar]
  51. Lenzen, M. Structural path analysis of ecosystem networks. Ecol. Model. 2007, 200, 334–342. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Defourny, J.; Thorbecke, E. Structural Path Analysis and Multiplier Decomposition within a Social Accounting Matrix Framework. Econ. J. 1984, 94, 111–136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Crama, Y.; Defourny, J.; Gazon, J. Structural decomposition of multipliers in input-output or social accounting matrix analysis. Économie Appliquée 1984, 37, 215–222. [Google Scholar]
  54. Van Rossum, G.; Drake, F.L., Jr. Python Tutorial; Centrum voor Wiskunde en Informatica: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 1995. [Google Scholar]
  55. Reback, J.; Jbrockmendel; McKinney, W.; Van Den Bossche, J.; Augspurger, T.; Cloud, P.; Hawkins, S.; Gfyoung; Roeschke, M.; Sinhrks; et al. Pandas-dev/pandas: Pandas 1.3.4. Zenodo 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. McKinney, W. Data Structures for Statistical Computing in Python. In Proceedings of the 9th Python in Science Conference, Austin, TX, USA, 28 June–3 July 2010; pp. 51–56. [Google Scholar]
  57. Harris, C.R.; Millman, K.J.; van der Walt, S.J.; Gommers, R.; Virtanen, P.; Cournapeau, D.; Wieser, E.; Taylor, J.; Berg, S.; Smith, N.J.; et al. Array programming with NumPy. Nature 2020, 585, 357–362. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Stephan, A.; Bontinck, P.A. pyspa—An Object-Oriented Python Package for Structural Path Analysis; GitHub: San Francisco, CA, USA, 2019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Hunter, J.D. Matplotlib: A 2D graphics environment. Comput. Sci. Eng. 2007, 9, 90–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Bunsen, J. A most simple implementation of Kitzes (2013) in Python. Zenodo 2022. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Bouwmeester, M.C.; Oosterhaven, J. Specification and Aggregation Errors in Environmentally Extended Input–Output Models. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2013, 56, 307–335. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Steen-Olsen, K.; Owen, A.; Hertwich, E.G.; Lenzen, M. Effects of Sector Aggregation on Co2 Multipliers in Multiregional Input–Output Analyses. Econ. Syst. Res. 2014, 26, 284–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. de Koning, A.; Bruckner, M.; Lutter, S.; Wood, R.; Stadler, K.; Tukker, A. Effect of aggregation and disaggregation on embodied material use of products in input–output analysis. Ecol. Econ. 2015, 116, 289–299. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Schulte, S.; Jakobs, A.; Pauliuk, S. Relaxing the import proportionality assumption in multi-regional input–output modelling. J. Econ. Struct. 2021, 10, 20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  65. Tukker, A.; Dietzenbacher, E. Global Multiregional Input-Output Frameworks: An Introduction and Outlook. Econ. Syst. Res. 2013, 25, 1–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  66. Wiedmann, T.O.; Suh, S.; Feng, K.; Lenzen, M.; Acquaye, A.; Scott, K.; Barrett, J.R. Application of Hybrid Life Cycle Approaches to Emerging Energy Technologies—The Case of Wind Power in the UK. Environ. Sci. Technol. 2011, 45, 5900–5907. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  67. Kitzes, J.; Galli, A.; Bagliani, M.; Barrett, J.; Dige, G.; Ede, S.; Erb, K.; Giljum, S.; Haberl, H.; Hails, C.; et al. A research agenda for improving national Ecological Footprint accounts. Ecol. Econ. 2009, 68, 1991–2007. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Lenzen, M.; Geschke, A.; Abd Rahman, M.D.; Xiao, Y.; Fry, J.; Reyes, R.; Dietzenbacher, E.; Inomata, S.; Kanemoto, K.; Los, B.; et al. The Global MRIO Lab—Charting the world economy. Econ. Syst. Res. 2017, 29, 158–186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Stadler, K.; Wood, R.; Bulavskaya, T.; Södersten, C.J.; Simas, M.; Schmidt, S.; Usubiaga, A.; Acosta-Fernández, J.; Kuenen, J.; Bruckner, M.; et al. EXIOBASE 3: Developing a Time Series of Detailed Environmentally Extended Multi-Regional Input-Output Tables: EXIOBASE 3. J. Ind. Ecol. 2018, 22, 502–515. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  70. Pfister, S.; Kulionis, V. Feasibility Study on Strengthening the Environmental Footprints and Planetary Boundaries Concepts within the Green Economy Progress Measurement Framework; UN Environment Document Repository Home; UNEP: Nairobi, Kenya, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  71. Lenzen, M.; Kanemoto, K.; Moran, D.; Geschke, A. Mapping the Structure of the World Economy. Environ. Sci. Technol. 2012, 46, 8374–8381. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Lenzen, M.; Moran, D.; Kanemoto, K.; Geschke, A. Building Eora: A global multi-region input-output database at high country and sector resolution. Econ. Syst. Res. 2013, 25, 20–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Wood, R.; Stadler, K.; Bulavskaya, T.; Lutter, S.; Giljum, S.; de Koning, A.; Kuenen, J.; Schütz, H.; Acosta-Fernández, J.; Usubiaga, A.; et al. Global Sustainability Accounting - Developing EXIOBASE for Multi-Regional Footprint Analysis. Sustainability 2015, 7, 138–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  74. Timmer, M.P.; Dietzenbacher, E.; Los, B.; Stehrer, R.; de Vries, G.J. An Illustrated User Guide to the World Input-Output Database: The Case of Global Automotive Production: User Guide to World Input-Output Database. Rev. Int. Econ. 2015, 23, 575–605. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Aguiar, A.; Chepeliev, M.; Corong, E.L.; McDougall, R.; Mensbrugghe, D.v.d. The GTAP Data Base: Version 10. J. Glob. Econ. Anal. 2019, 4, 1–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  76. OECD. OECD Inter-Country Input-Output Database; OECD: Paris, France, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  77. Cabernard, L.; Pfister, S. A highly resolved MRIO database for analyzing environmental footprints and Green Economy Progress. Sci. Total Environ. 2021, 755, 142587. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Cabernard, L.; Pfister, S. A highly resolved MRIO database for analyzing environmental footprints and Green Economy Progress—A. Code and data from 2006–2015. Zenodo 2020. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Bruckner, M.; Wood, R.; Moran, D.; Kuschnig, N.; Wieland, H.; Maus, V.; Börner, J. FABIO—The Construction of the Food and Agriculture Biomass Input–Output Model. Environ. Sci. Technol. 2019, 53, 11302–11312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  80. Tukker, A.; Pollitt, H.; Henkemans, M. Consumption-based carbon accounting: Sense and sensibility. Clim. Policy 2020, 20, S1–S13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  81. Lenzen, M.; Murray, J.; Sack, F.; Wiedmann, T. Shared producer and consumer responsibility—Theory and practice. Ecol. Econ. 2007, 61, 27–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Peters, G. From production-based to consumption-based national emission inventories. Ecol. Econ. 2008, 65, 13–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Suh, S. A note on the calculus for physical input–output analysis and its application to land appropriation of international trade activities. Ecol. Econ. 2004, 48, 9–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Hubacek, K.; Giljum, S. Applying physical input–output analysis to estimate land appropriation (ecological footprints) of international trade activities. Ecol. Econ. 2003, 44, 137–151. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. A comparison of the sums of externalities allocated to the agricultural sectors (wheat and cotton) and manufacturing sectors (textiles and agricultural machinery) in the inventories of the 4 × 4 dummy input-output table and the externalities allocated to the agriculture and machinery sectors in the 2 × 2 dummy input-output table. See also Figure A7.
Table 1. A comparison of the sums of externalities allocated to the agricultural sectors (wheat and cotton) and manufacturing sectors (textiles and agricultural machinery) in the inventories of the 4 × 4 dummy input-output table and the externalities allocated to the agriculture and machinery sectors in the 2 × 2 dummy input-output table. See also Figure A7.
InventorySector(s)2 × 2 IO-Table4 × 4 IO-Table Δ (abs.) Δ (rel.)
Production-basedAgriculture8 m38 m300
Production-basedManufacturing4 m34 m300
Consumption-basedAgriculture4.80 m36.06 m3+1.26 m3+26%
Consumption-basedManufacturing7.20 m35.94 m3−1.26 m3−18%
Table 2. Comparison of the allocation of externalities in the consumption-based inventories of the 2 × 2 and 4 × 4 dummy input-output tables in Figure 4 and Figure 6, respectively. The Agriculture rows in the 2 × 2 input-output table column contain the values of the Agriculture (Region A) sector. The Agriculture rows in the 4 × 4 input-output table column contain the sum of the values of the AgricultureWheat (Region A) and AgricultureCotton (Region A) sectors. The Manufacturing rows in the 2 × 2 input-output table column contain the values of the Manufacturing (Region A) sector. The Manufacturing rows in the 4 × 4 input-output table column contain the sum of the values of the ManufacturingTextiles (Region B) and ManufacturingAgricultural machinery (Region B) sectors. The changes in the “ Δ (abs.)” and “ Δ (abs.)” columns consider the 4 × 4 dummy input-output table as a baseline scenario (Figure A8). The results in the resolution of the input-output table in Figure 4 are shown in Figure A4.
Table 2. Comparison of the allocation of externalities in the consumption-based inventories of the 2 × 2 and 4 × 4 dummy input-output tables in Figure 4 and Figure 6, respectively. The Agriculture rows in the 2 × 2 input-output table column contain the values of the Agriculture (Region A) sector. The Agriculture rows in the 4 × 4 input-output table column contain the sum of the values of the AgricultureWheat (Region A) and AgricultureCotton (Region A) sectors. The Manufacturing rows in the 2 × 2 input-output table column contain the values of the Manufacturing (Region A) sector. The Manufacturing rows in the 4 × 4 input-output table column contain the sum of the values of the ManufacturingTextiles (Region B) and ManufacturingAgricultural machinery (Region B) sectors. The changes in the “ Δ (abs.)” and “ Δ (abs.)” columns consider the 4 × 4 dummy input-output table as a baseline scenario (Figure A8). The results in the resolution of the input-output table in Figure 4 are shown in Figure A4.
ExternalitySector(s)2 × 2 IO-Table4 × 4 IO-Table Δ (abs.) Δ (rel.)
Water consumption—WheatAgriculture3.00 m34.95 m3−1.95 m3−39.4%
Water consumption—WheatManufacturing3.00 m31.05 m3+1.95 m3+185%
Water consumption—CottonAgriculture1.00 m30.41 m3+0.59 m3+141.5%
Water consumption—CottonManufacturing1.00 m31.59 m3−0.59 m3−36.9%
Water consumption—TextilesAgriculture0.50 m30.04 m3+0.46 m3+1040%
Water consumption—TextilesManufacturing2.00 m32.46 m3−0.46 m3−18.6%
Water consumption—Agricultural machineryAgriculture0.30 m30.66 m3−0.36 m3−54.4%
Water consumption—Agricultural machineryManufacturing1.20 m30.84 m3+0.36 m3+42.5%
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Bunsen, J.; Finkbeiner, M. An Introductory Review of Input-Output Analysis in Sustainability Sciences Including Potential Implications of Aggregation. Sustainability 2023, 15, 46. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010046

AMA Style

Bunsen J, Finkbeiner M. An Introductory Review of Input-Output Analysis in Sustainability Sciences Including Potential Implications of Aggregation. Sustainability. 2023; 15(1):46. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010046

Chicago/Turabian Style

Bunsen, Jonas, and Matthias Finkbeiner. 2023. "An Introductory Review of Input-Output Analysis in Sustainability Sciences Including Potential Implications of Aggregation" Sustainability 15, no. 1: 46. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010046

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop