Next Article in Journal
Spatiotemporal Dynamics of Aboveground Biomass and Its Influencing Factors in Xinjiang’s Desert Grasslands
Previous Article in Journal
Analyzing the Effect of Crowds on Passenger Behavior Inside Urban Trains through Laboratory Experiments—A Pilot Study
Previous Article in Special Issue
Environmental Regulation, Family Involvement and Green Innovation Efficiency—Based on Sew Theory Framework
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Government Reserve of Rare Earths under Total Quota Management: An Interactive Game between Government and Rare-Earth Firms

1
Non-Ferrous Metal Industry Development Research Institute, Jiangxi University of Science and Technology, Ganzhou 341000, China
2
Jiangxi Key Laboratory of Efficient Development and Utilization of Rare Metal Resources, Jiangxi University of Science and Technology, Ganzhou 341000, China
3
School of Business, Jiangxi University of Science and Technology, Nanchang 330044, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2022, 14(22), 14883; https://doi.org/10.3390/su142214883
Submission received: 30 September 2022 / Revised: 3 November 2022 / Accepted: 8 November 2022 / Published: 10 November 2022
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Advanced in Market Economy and Industrial Policy)

Abstract

:
The total quota control and reserve of rare earths are important means for the sustainable development and utilization of rare-earth resources. Focusing on the government reserve of rare-earth products under stochastic demand, this paper analyses the interactive decisions of the government and the rare-earth firms from a game-theoretic perspective. The government determines the total quantity, reserve quantity and reserve–release quantity of the rare-earth products to maximize social warfare, while the firm decides the price of rare-earth products to maximize its own profit. The results show that the production cost and the expected net present value (NPV) of the reserve are important factors affecting the government’s decisions. When the expected NPV of the reserve is below a threshold, the government adopts the no-reserve strategy: it determines only a total quota index that maximizes the current-period social welfare but keeps no reserve. When the expected NPV of a reserve is higher than the above threshold but lower than the production cost, the government adopts the low-reserve strategy: it determines a total quota index and a low reserve that are both in increasing in the expected NPV of reserve, and will release the reserve as many as possible if there is a supply shortage. When the expected NPV of a reserve is higher than both the above threshold and the production cost, the government adopts the high-reserve strategy: it sets a total quota index which is sufficiently large to cover the entire market demand, reserves a large amount, and releases part of the reserve to completely fill the demand gap (if any).

1. Introduction

Rare earth is a non-renewable strategic mineral resource and a material treasure chest in the new era. Known as “industrial vitamin” and “industrial monosodium glutamate”, rare earth is an indispensable element in modern industry [1]. With good characteristics in photo-electro-magnetism, superconductivity, activity, catalysis and other aspects, rare earth plays an important role in improving product performance and productivity, and is widely used in areas such as aerospace, new energy, environmental protection, new materials, electronic information, etc. [2]. As a non-renewable resource experiencing increasing demand, the sustainable utilization of rare earth is very important. However, there still exist various problems in the development of the rare-earth industry, including illegal mining, the rapid expansion of smelting and separation capacities, the serious waste of resources, ecological and environmental damage, backward research and the development of high-end applications, and a chaotic export order [3]. These problems seriously threaten the sustainable development and utilization of rare-earth resources.
Total quota control and strategic reserves of rare earth are effective means to achieve rare-earth sustainability. On the one hand, rare-earth total quota control and reserves are beneficial to balance the intergenerational allocation of rare-earth resources and their benefits. On the other hand, rare-earth total quota control and reserve can promote the progress of utilization technologies and the development of alternative products, reduce predatory exploitation under the condition of the current immature technological level, reduce the waste of resources, protect the ecological environment, realize the orderly development of rare-earth mines, and promote the sustainable development of national economies and society.
In order to strengthen the sustainable utilization and effective protection of rare-earth resources, the Chinese government has introduced a series of policies on the total quota control and strategic reserve of rare earth. On 10 May 2011, China proposed a strategic reserve of rare-earth products (including rare-earth mineral products and rare-earth smelting separation products) for the first time, including a government reserve, enterprise (commercial) reserve, resource (land) reserve and physical reserve [4]. On 18 October 2016, the Ministry of Industry and Information Technology issued the Rare Earth Industry Development Plan (2016–2020), which clearly stipulates that, by the end of 2020, the six major rare-earth groups in China will complete the integration of all rare-earth enterprises (including rare-earth mining enterprises, rare-earth smelting and separation enterprises, rare-earth comprehensive utilization enterprises and rare-earth metal-smelting enterprises). The “13th Five-Year Plan” for rare earth states that the mining quantity of rare earth in 2020 should be strictly controlled to within 140,000 tons [5]. On 15 January 2021, the Ministry of Industry and Information Technology issued Rare Earth Management Regulations (Draft for Comments), in which Article 16 pointed out that China should implement the strategic reserve of rare-earth resources and rare-earth products [6]. On 30 September 2021, the Ministry of Industry and Information Technology and the Ministry of Natural Resources issued the 2021 annual total quota control indexes of rare-earth mining (168,000 tons) and smelting and separation (162,000 tons), with both increased by 20% compared with the corresponding indexes in 2020 [7].
Although the total quota management and strategic reserve of rare-earth products are being increasingly scrutinized, the related theoretical research is very scarce. Previous studies mainly discussed, at the conceptual level, the effects of rare-earth reserves on rare-earth price stabilization [8,9,10], national defense security [11,12], and ecological environment protection [13,14,15], etc. Some articles study the rare-earth industry or resources from the perspective of game theory. For example, Han et al. (2015) attempt to analyze adjustments in China’s rare-earth regulation policies and the effects on the rare-earth market supply by using a static game-theoretic model and a dynamic game-theoretic model with complete information in the contextof China strengthening protection of rare-earth resources and the environment [16]. Brown and Eggert (2018) use a Stackelberg model to explore the effects of Chinese rare-earth reserves, environmental taxation, and improvements in recovery rates on rare-earth markets [17]. Lee et al. (2018) investigate how competition for limited resources influences firms’ adoption of environmentally sustainable strategies [18]. None of the above studies consider the interactions between total quota control and rare-earth reserve or pricing, which is the very focus of this study.
We also employ the game-theoretic framework to analyze the decision-making interactions of the rare-earth industry chain. However, in contrast to the above studies, our focus falls on the interactions between the government’s total quota management and strategic reserve of rare-earth products and rare-earth firm’s pricing decisions, which is not examined by the above studies. We also examine the influence of key parameters such as production cost, expected net present value (NPV) of reserve, market potential and price sensitivity coefficient on the above decision results. Although the literature on government reserves of rare-earth products under total quota management is small, the literature on government reserves of other mineral resources (e.g., petroleum, iron ore and coal) and emergency supplies (e.g., protective suits and goggles) is relatively rich. Using a dynamic programming model, Wu et al. (2012) examine the optimal stockpiling and drawdown strategies for China’s strategic petroleum reserve under various scenarios, with the goal of minimizing the total cost of reserves [19]. Cui and Wei (2017) study the phenomenon of thermal-coal price distortion through economic theoretical modeling and empirical cointegration analysis from the perspective of market forces [20]. Rademeyer et al. (2021) find that a profit-maximizing trader will seek to sell more volumes to domestic consumers of higher grade coal to compensate for earnings lost due to lower export volumes [21]. With the goal of minimizing the expected cost of the government (buyer) and maximizing the profit of the enterprise (supplier), Hu et al. (2019) examine the optimal reserve of emergency materials and investigate the coordination of an emergency supply chain [22]. Hu and Dong (2019) design a two-stage stochastic programming model to optimize firms’ material storage management in a humanitarian supply chain [23]. Liang et al. (2012) design an option-contract pricing model for a relief-material supply chain [24]. These studies provide important references for our study of reserves of rare-earth products. However, rare-earth products have an important difference from the aforementioned minerals or materials, that is, the government implements total quota management for rare-earth products. The total quota control of rare-earth products will affect the reserve decision, so the two should be considered together. Then, under the total quota management of rare-earth products, how will the government make decisions on the reserve and release of rare-earth products, taking into account the potential response of enterprises and market demand? How will rare-earth companies set prices? In addition, how should the government optimize the total quota management plan? This paper aims to address these issues.
To sum up, this study employs a game-theoretic framework to investigate the interactions between the government and rare-earth enterprises under the total quota management policy, examining issues of rare-earth products reserve, pricing, and reserve release. This study contributes to the literature by enriching the theoretical results on the optimization of operation decisions related to the quantity and price of rare-earth products, and by providing managerial insights for the government and rare-earth enterprises on the sustainable exploitation and utilization of rare-earth resources.

2. Model Description

Consider a single-period, multi-stage decision-making problem for a rare-earth product supply chain composed of the government, a rare-earth firm (hereafter referred to as the firm), and consumers (or downstream firms) (see Figure 1). At time T1, the beginning of the period, the government determines the total quota control index q ¯ of rare-earth products in this period, and issues production plans to the rare-earth firm according to the relevant requirements of the Interim Measures for the Management of Rare Earth Mandatory Production Plans (which came into effect on 13 June 2012) [25]. Let the firm’s unit production cost in the current period be c , and assume that the firm always arranges the maximum production allowed by the total quota index q ¯ . It is worth mentioning that the total quota index q ¯ includes the quantities from mining, smelting and separation (which are collectively called production in this paper), but not imports. Although rare-earth imports and exports may have an impact on the model results, the current study does not explicitly model them due to the following reasons. First, rare-earth imports are small compared with the total quota control index. For example, in 2021, China’s total quota control index of rare earth (converted to REO) was 330,000 tons (https://bit.ly/3ThW519, accessed on 28 September 2022), while the import quantity (converted to REO) was at the level of 20,000~30,000 tons (http://www.customs.gov.cn/, accessed on 28 September 2022). Second, rare-earth exports do not need to be characterized separately, because they are already included in the market demand. Third, the current model analysis is already complicated, and considering the influences of imports and exports will further increase analytical difficulties.
At T2, the government decides the amount q [ 0 , q ¯ ] of rare-earth products to be reserved in the period. In general, the government buys rare-earth products from rare-earth firms at a price (set as w ) below the market level, and the rare-earth products bought are reserved and managed by the China State Reserve Bureau. The unit reserve cost of the government is denoted as c G . At T3, the firm decides the market price p of rare-earth products in the current period. Influenced by price p and other factors (e.g., supply, demand, policy, etc.), the demand D of rare-earth products in this period is realized. At time T4, according to the market supply and demand situation, the government can choose to release part of the reserve q ^ [ 0 , q ] to alleviate the market demand when necessary. The rare-earth products put into the market but not sold in the current period will be disposed of with a certain salvage value; the unit salvage value of residual rare-earth products processed by the government and enterprises are v G and v F , respectively. If the rare-earth products put on the market in the current period fail to meet all the demand, the seller (possibly the government or the firm) shall bear the loss of shortage. Assume that the unit loss of shortage of the government and the firm are t G and t F , respectively. Unreleased reserve will enter the next period and generate some value in the future. Assume the expected net present value (NPV) of the unreleased government reserve to be r G per unit. In order to make the model conform to reality, it is assumed that the expected NPV of (unreleased) reserve is higher than the salvage value in the current period, i.e., r G > v G .
In order to formulate the consumer surplus, this paper refers to the modeling of market demand by Xue et al. (2014) [26] and Li Yao et al. (2006) [27], and assumes that consumers’ purchase willingness ζ for rare-earth products follows the cumulative distribution function (cdf) Φ ( ξ ) = b ζ / a , ζ [ 0 , a / b ] (the probability density function (pdf) is denoted as ϕ ( ξ ) ). Thus, given the price p of rare-earth products, the probability that consumers are willing to buy is Pr ( ξ p ) = 1 Φ ( p ) = ( a b p ) / a , which represents the proportion of consumers who can form demand when the market price is p . Denote this ratio as y ( p ) = ( a b p ) / a and refer to it as demand ratio, where a > 0 is the market potential and b > 0 is the price sensitivity coefficient. Assuming the size of potential consumers as a random variable ε , the demand at price p (assuming that each consumer can only buy one product at most) can be expressed as D = y ( p ) ε . Similar multiplicative form of price-dependent stochastic demand is very common in the operation management literature (e.g., [28,29]). Assume that the cdf, pdf and mean of ε are F ( ) , f ( ) and μ , respectively, and write F ¯ ( ) = 1 F ( ) . Suppose that ε satisfies the property of increasing generalized failure rate (IGFR), i.e., x f ( x ) / F ¯ ( x ) increases with x . Many common distributions satisfy this assumption, such as uniform distribution, normal distribution, and exponential distribution, etc. (e.g., [30,31,32]). Based on the above model assumptions, it can be known that, given the market price p [ 0 , a / b ] , the expected surplus of a single consumer is p a / b ( ξ p ) ϕ ( ξ ) d ξ = a y ( p ) 2 / ( 2 b ) . After taking into account the government’s reserve ( q ) and release ( q ^ ) decisions, the final product supply is q ¯ q + q ^ , and the volume of consumers that can be satisfied is min { ε , ( q ¯ q + q ^ ) / y ( p ) } . Thus, the total expected consumer surplus is:
π C ( q ¯ , q , p , q ^ ) = min ε , q ¯ q + q ^ y ( p ) p a b ( ξ p ) ϕ ( ξ ) d ξ = a y ( p ) min { D , q ¯ q + q ^ } 2 b
For the firm, it faces a demand D and offers a supply quantity of q ¯ q . Thus, the profit of the firm is:
π F ( q ¯ , q , p ) = c q ¯ + w q + p min { D , q ¯ q } t F ( D q ¯ + q ) + + v F ( q ¯ q D ) +          = ( v F c ) q ¯ + ( w v F ) q t F D + ( p + t F v F ) min { D , q ¯ q }
where ( D q ¯ + q ) + = D min { D , q ¯ q } and ( q ¯ q D ) + = q ¯ q min { D , q ¯ q } .
In the first equation of Equation (2), the first to the fifth terms are the production cost, reserve-offer revenue, sales revenue, backorder loss, and salvage value, respectively. Moreover, since the firm’s supply is assumed to be sold before the government’s supply, the firm’s profit is independent of the government’s release of reserve q ^ .
For the government, it faces a demand of ( D q ¯ + q ) + (assuming that the firm’s supply is sold before the government’s in the case of market supply shortage), offers a supply of q ^ , and keeps an unreleased reserve of q q ^ . Thus, the government’s profit is:
π G ( q ¯ , q , p , q ^ ) = w q c G q + p min { ( D q ¯ + q ) + , q ^ } t G [ ( D q ¯ + q ) + q ^ ] + + v G [ q ^ ( D q ¯ + q ) + ] + + r G ( q q ^ ) = ( r G c G w ) q + ( v G r G ) q ^ + ( p + t G v G ) min { D , q ¯ q + q ^ } ( p v G ) min { D , q ¯ q } t G D
where
min { ( D q ¯ + q ) + , q ^ } = min { D , q ¯ q + q ^ } min { D , q ¯ q } ,
[ ( D q ¯ + q ) + q ^ ] + = D min { D , q ¯ q + q ^ } , and
[ q ^ ( D q ¯ + q ) + ] + = q ^ min { D , q ¯ q + q ^ } + min { D , q ¯ q } .
In the first equation of Equation (3), the first to the sixth terms are the government’s procurement cost, reserve cost, sales revenue, backorder loss, salvage value, and total expected NPV of unreleased reserve, respectively.
In line with previous studies examining the interactions between rare-earth firms and the government (e.g., [33]), the firm in our model aims to maximize its own profit π F , while the government aims to maximize the social welfare, defined as the sum of producer surplus and consumer surplus ([33,34,35]). Since the government purchasing and selling reserve plays part of producer’s role, the social welfare in our model (denoted as π S W ) is the sum of the firm’s profit, the consumer’s surplus, and the government’s profit, i.e., π S W = π G + π F + π C . From the perspective of sustainable supply-chain management, social-welfare maximization reflects the government’s emphasis on both economic sustainability (i.e., the firm’s and government’s profit) and social sustainability (i.e., the consumer surplus) [36]. The third dimension of sustainability is environmental sustainability (e.g., [37]), which is beyond the scope of the current study and may be worth investigating in future research.
Table 1 summarizes the notations used in this paper.

3. Model Analysis

Since the model involves a multi-stage game, by backward induction, we successively analyzed the government’s optimal release strategy, the firm’s optimal pricing strategy, and the government’s optimal reserve and total quota control strategy.

3.1. The Government’s Optimal Release Decision

At time T4, given the total quota index q ¯ , the reserve quantity q , the price p , and the current-period demand D , the government’s problem is to choose the optimal release quantity q ^ [ 0 , q ] to maximize the social welfare π S W :
π S W ( q ¯ , q , p , q ^ ) π G ( q ¯ , q , p , q ^ ) + π F ( q ¯ , q , p ) + π C ( q ¯ , q , p , q ^ ) = ( v F c ) q ¯ + ( r G c G v F ) q + ( v G r G ) q ^ ( t G + t F ) D + ( v G + t F v F ) min { D , q ¯ q } + ( a + b p ) / ( 2 b ) + t G v G D q ^ > D q ¯ + q ( a + b p ) / ( 2 b ) + t G v G ( q ¯ q + q ^ ) q ^ D q ¯ + q
One can verify that π S W ( q ¯ , q , p , q ^ ) is a piecewise linear function of the government’s decision variable q ^ . Therefore, the government’s optimal decision on q ^ can be easily obtained by examining the first-order condition.
Proposition 1. 
The government’s optimal release quantity q ^ * at time T4 is given by
q ^ * = 0   ( a + b p ) / ( 2 b ) + t G r G min { D , q ¯ } min { D , q ¯ q }   ( a + b p ) / ( 2 b ) + t G > r G
and the corresponding social welfare is given by
π S W ( q ¯ , q , p ) π S W ( q ¯ , q , p , q ^ * ) = ( v F c ) q ¯ + ( r G c G v F ) q ( t G + t F ) D + ( r G + t F v F ) min { D , q ¯ q } + ( a + b p ) / ( 2 b ) + t G r G min { D , q ¯ q } ( a + b p ) / ( 2 b ) + t G r G ( a + b p ) / ( 2 b ) + t G r G min { D , q ¯ } ( a + b p ) / ( 2 b ) + t G > r G
All proofs are provided in Appendix A. Proposition 1 shows that the government’s reserve release strategy at T4 is either not to release at all ( q ^ * = 0 ), or to release according to the demand gap within its maximum reserve ( q ^ * = min { q , D q ¯ + q } ). There are two factors that determine the government’s release strategy. One is whether the current market supply can meet the demand. If the market is adequately supplied ( D [ 0 , q ¯ q ] ), there is certainly no reason for the government to release the reserve. If the market supply is insufficient ( D [ q ¯ q , ) ), the government needs to weigh the expected NPV of reserve r G against the social welfare loss ( a + b p ) / ( 2 b ) + t G caused by the current-period supply shortage. If and only if the latter exceeds the former, will the government release reserves to meet the demand gap as much as possible.

3.2. The Firm’s Optimal Pricing Decision

At time T3, given the total quota index q ¯ and the reserve quantity q , and expecting the subsequent demand D , the firm’s objective is to determine the optimal price that maximizes its own expected profit:
Π F ( q ¯ , q , p ) = ( v F c ) q ¯ + ( w v F ) q μ t F y ( p ) + ( p + t F v F ) S ( z 1 ) y ( p )
where S ( z ) = E ε [ min { ε , z } ] and z 1 = ( q ¯ q ) / y ( p ) . In order to simplify the subsequent analysis, we define η ( z ) = z F ¯ ( z ) / S ( z ) and g ( z ) = z f ( z ) / F ¯ ( z ) as in [26], and then the following lemma can be obtained by following [26] and [38]:
Lemma 1.
For any z > 0 , (a) S ( z ) = 0 z F ¯ ( ξ ) d ξ μ ; (b) η ( z ) is monotonically non-increasing with respect to z ; and(c) η ( z ) < 1 .
Based on Lemma 1, the optimal pricing decision of the firm can be solved, as characterized in the following proposition:
Proposition 2.
The firm’s optimal price p * at time T3 is the unique solution of the equation T ( p * ) = 0 and satisfies p * ( v F , a / b ) , where:
T ( p ) ( a / b t F + v F 2 p ) S ( z 1 ) + ( p + t F v F ) z 1 F ¯ ( z 1 ) + μ t F
By investigating the influence of relevant parameters on the firm’s optimal price, the following proposition is obtained:
Proposition 3.
The firm’s optimal price p * is:
(a)
decreasing in the rare-earth supply ( q ¯ q ), i.e., p * / ( q ¯ q ) < 0 ;
(b)
increasing in the firm’s unit shortage loss t F , i.e., p * / t F > 0 ;
(c)
increasing in the firm’s unit salvage value v F , i.e., p * / v F > 0 ;
(d)
increasing in the market potential a , i.e., p * / a > 0 ;
(e)
decreasing in the price sensitivity coefficient b , i.e., p * / b < 0 .
Proposition 3 has important implications for the market pricing of rare-earth firms. First, the larger the market supply q ¯ q , the more rare-earth firms should lower the price p * to reduce the loss of shortage or salvage. If the government wants to boost the price of rare earth, it should cut the total quota index q ¯ or increase the reserve q to reduce the amount of rare earths in circulation in the market q ¯ q . Second, when the unit loss of shortage t F is larger or the salvage value v F of rare-earth products is higher, the firm should increase the price p * to reduce the market demand, because in this case, the backorder will cause great losses to the firm, but the value loss due to over-supply is small. Third, when the market potential a is larger, the firm has more pricing power due to the favourable demand situation. Finally, when the price sensitivity of rare-earth products is higher, the firm should reduce the price, because a small price reduction can bring about a large increase in demand.

3.3. The Government’s Optimal Reserve Decision

By substituting the firm’s optimal price p * in Proposition 2 into Equation (6) and calculating the expectation of potential consumer size ε , the expected social welfare at time T2 can be obtained as follows:
Π S W ( q ¯ , q ) = E ε [ π S W ( q ¯ , q , p * ) ] = ( v F c ) q ¯ + ( r G c G v F ) q + ( r G + t F v F ) S ( z 1 * ) ( t F + t G ) μ y ( p * ) + [ ( a + b p * ) / ( 2 b ) + t G r G ] S ( z 1 * ) y ( p * ) ( a + b p * ) / ( 2 b ) + t G r G [ ( a + b p * ) / ( 2 b ) + t G r G ] S ( z 2 * ) y ( p * ) ( a + b p * ) / ( 2 b ) + t G > r G
where z 1 * = ( q ¯ q ) / y ( p * ) and z 2 * = q ¯ / y ( p * ) . The government’s objective at time T2 is to select the optimal reserve quantity q [ 0 , q ¯ ] to maximize Π S W ( q ¯ , q ) .
Under the general demand distribution F ( ) , the firm’s optimal price p * is given by the implicit function (Equation (8)), which makes it very difficult to solve the government’s reserve decision. In order to obtain an analytical solution, the following assumptions are made hereafter to simplify the analysis:
Assumption 1.
Reserve cost, salvage value and loss of shortage are not considered, i.e., c G = v G = v F = t G = t F = 0 .
Assumption 2.
The size of potential consumers ε is drawn from the uniform distribution on [ 0 , 2 μ ] , which means that:
F ( ε ) = ε / ( 2 μ ) ε [ 0 , 2 μ ] 1 ε ( 2 μ , )   and   S ( z ) = z z 2 / ( 4 μ ) z [ 0 , 2 μ ] μ z ( 2 μ , )
Assumption 3.
The market supply q ¯ q is no greater than the upper bound of demand 2 μ y ( p * ) , i.e., q ¯ q 2 μ y ( p * ) , which is equivalent to q ¯ q μ after transformation. To ensure that this condition holds for any reserve quantity q [ 0 , q ¯ ] , assume q ¯ μ .
Under the above assumptions, the expected social welfare (Equation (9)) can be reformulated as a function of Q :
Π S W ( Q ) = Π S W 1 = μ t Q [ 4 ( 1 X ) Q 2 + Q 4 X ] / 8 + μ Y 2 ( t t X c ) Q [ 0 , A 1 ] Π S W 2 = μ t [ 2 ( 1 X ) Q 4 + Y 2 Q 2 + 2 Y 4 X ] / ( 4 Q ) + μ Y 2 t Y 2 / 8 + t c Q ( A 1 , A 2 ] Π S W 3 = μ t Q 2 [ Q 2 6 Q + 8 X ] / 8 + μ Y 2 ( t t X c ) Q ( A 2 , Y ]
where t = a / b , X = 1 r G / t ( 0 , 1 ) , Q = ( q ¯ q ) / μ , Y = q ¯ / μ 1 , A 1 = min { 4 X , Y 2 } and A 2 = min { 4 X , Y } . Due to the one-to-one mapping between Q and q , optimizing Π S W with respect to q is equivalent to optimizing Π S W with respect to Q .
Proposition 4.
Under Assumptions 1–3, the government’s optimal reserve quantity q * at time T2 is given by:
q = q 1 * = q ¯ μ κ 2 r G [ t / 8 , t )   a n d   q ¯ μ κ q 2 * = q ¯ q ¯ κ r G [ t / 8 , t )   a n d   q ¯ < μ κ q 3 * = 0 r G ( 0 , t / 8 )
where  κ [ 1 + 1 + 48 X ( 1 X ) ] / [ 12 ( 1 X ) ]  (increasing in  X ), X 1 ( 6 Y 2 + 1 ) Y 2 / [ 2 ( 3 Y 4 + 1 ) ] (increasing in  Y ). The corresponding expected social welfare is:
Π S W * = Π S W 1 * = μ t [ 8 ( 1 X ) κ + 1 ] κ 2 / 8 + μ Y 2 [ t ( 1 X ) c ] r G [ t / 8 , t )   a n d   q ¯ μ κ Π S W 2 * = μ t Y 3 [ 4 ( 1 X ) κ + 1 ] κ / 2 + μ Y 2 ( 8 t 8 c + t Y 2 ) / 8 r G [ t / 8 , t )   a n d   q ¯ < μ κ Π S W 3 * = μ Y 2 ( 8 t 8 c + t Y 2 6 t Y ) / 8 r G ( 0 , t / 8 )
Proposition 4 shows that, depending on the expected NPV of its unreleased reserve ( r G ), the government may adopt three different reserve strategies. When r G is low ( r G ( 0 , t / 8 ) ), there is little value in reserving the rare-earth products. Therefore, the government’s strategy is not to reserve ( q 3 * = 0 ), and all rare-earth products under the total quota index q ¯ enter the market circulation. When r G is not too low ( r G t / 8 ), rare-earth products have reserve value, but the amount of the government reserve will vary according to the size of the total quota index q ¯ : if q ¯ is low ( q ¯ < μ κ ), the government will keep a low reserve level ( q * = q 2 * ), and will release as much as possible to fill the demand gap in the case of market supply shortage. If the total quota index q ¯ is high ( q ¯ > μ κ ), the government will keep a high reserve level ( q * = q 1 * ), which will cause the firm to set a high price. In this case, even if there is a market supply shortage, the government can fully fill the demand gap by only releasing a part of the reserve. Figure 2 illustrates the conditions where each of the above three strategies is applicable.
By investigating the influence of parameters on the government’s optimal reserve, we obtain the following proposition:
Proposition 5. 
The government’s optimal reserve quantity q * is:
(a)
Increasing in the expected NPV r G of unreleased reserve, i.e., q * / r G 0 ;
(b)
Decreasing in the market potential a , i.e., q * / a 0 ;
(c)
Increasing in the price sensitivity factor b , i.e.,  q * / b 0 ;
(d)
Increasing in the total quota index q ¯ , i.e., q * / q H 0 ;
(e)
Decreasing in the average size μ of potential consumers, i.e., q * / μ 0 .
The implications of Proposition 5 are as follows. With a higher expected NPV r G of its unreleased reserve, the government should naturally stockpile to meet future demand. When the market potential a is larger, the market demand of the current period is larger, and the government should reduce the reserve quantity to better meet the current market demand. When the rare-earth product is more sensitive to the price ( b is larger), the government should reduce the current market supply to maintain a high market price, so it should increase the reserve quantity. A higher total quota index q ¯ means there may be more leftover if demand remains unchanged, so the government should increase the reserve quantity. When the expected size μ of potential consumers is larger, the total demand in the current period is larger, so the government should reduce the reserve quantity to better meet the current market demand.

3.4. The Government’s Total Quota Index Decision

At time T1, the government needs to make a decision on the total quota index q ¯ by maximizing the expected social welfare Π S W * (Equation (12)). Due to the one-to-one correspondence between Y = q ¯ / μ and q ¯ , the optimization of Π S W * with respect to q ¯ is equivalent to the optimization of Π S W * with respect to Y .
Proposition 6. 
Under Assumptions 1–3, the government’s optimal decision of total quota index at time T1 is q ¯ * = μ Y * 2 , where:
Y * = Y 1 * = 1 r G [ t / 8 , t )   a n d   r G c Y 2 * = 3 κ [ 2 ( 1 X ) κ + 1 / 2 ] 9 κ [ 2 ( 1 X ) κ + 1 / 2 ] 2 4 ( 1 c / t ) r G [ t / 8 , t )   a n d   r G < c Y 3 * = 9 / 4 64 c t + 17 t 2 / ( 4 t ) r G ( 0 , t / 8 ) =
The corresponding expected social welfare is:
Π S W * * = Π S W 1 * * = μ t [ 8 ( 1 X ) κ + 1 ] κ 2 / 8 + μ [ t ( 1 X ) c ] r G [ t / 8 , t )   a n d   r G c Π S W 2 * * = ( t c ) μ Y 2 * 2 / 2 μ Y 2 * 2 t κ [ 4 ( 1 X ) κ + 1 ] Y 2 * / 8 r G [ t / 8 , t )   a n d   r G < c Π S W 3 * * = μ t ( 3 Y 3 * ) Y 3 * 3 / 8 r G ( 0 , t / 8 )
By Proposition 6, the government will formulate the total quota index according to the relationship between the expected NPV r G of the unreleased reserve and the unit production cost c . When r G is very low ( r G < t / 8 ), the government only needs to consider meeting the market demand of the current period, but will not consider the need of reserving, so its optimal decision of total quota index does not include r G . When r G exceeds a certain threshold ( r G > t / 8 ) but is not enough to cover the production cost ( r G < c ), the government will appropriately increase the total quota index to meet the current market demand as much as possible. At the same time, if the current supply is sufficient, the government will reserve part of it. When r G exceeds the aforementioned threshold ( r G > t / 8 ) and is higher than the production cost ( r G < c ), the government will set the total quota index to the maximum extent and supply the current period according to the maximum possible value of market demand, with the remaining part being reserved.

4. Numerical Analysis

In this section, numerical simulation is used to verify the model results and observe the relevant equilibrium properties. Firstly, we investigate the decision results regarding the rare-earth quantities (i.e., the total quota index q ¯ * , the reserve quantity q * , and expected unreleased reserve q * E [ q ^ * ] ) and their influencing factors. Assume that the mean value of potential consumer size is μ = 1 and the relative market potential is t = a / b = 1 . Figure 3 depicts how the total quota index q ¯ * , the reserve quantity q * , and the expected unreleased reserve q * E [ q ^ * ] change with the expected NPV r G of the unreleased reserve, under production costs (a) c = 0.3 , (b) c = 0.5 and (c) c = 0.7 , respectively.
As can be seen from any sub-figure in Figure 3, when r G changes from small to large, the government’s reserve strategy will go through three different stages: no reserve, low reserve and high reserve (Proposition 4). Among them, the total quota index q ¯ * in the no-reserve stage is low, and is independent of r G . Both q ¯ * and q * increase in r G , and the government will release part of the reserve in the case of insufficient market supply (the release amount is equal to the difference between the dot-dashed line and the dashed line). In this case, the supply may still be insufficient after the release of the reserve (part r G ( 0.125 , 0.5 ) in Figure 3c), but the expected unreleased reserve increases in r G . When r G crosses the threshold of production cost c , the government will enter the stage of high reserve, and both the total quota and reserve quantity will see a sharp increase. In this case, even if there is a shortage of supply, the government only needs to release a part of the reserve to fully satisfy the market, and the expected quantity of unreleased reserve still increases in r G . Note that Figure 3 shows that the expected release quantity E [ q ^ * ] (the difference between the dotted line and the dashed line) first increases and then decrease in r G . A horizontal comparison of the three sub-figures in Figure 3 shows that, given that other conditions remain unchanged, when the production cost c increases: (i) the possibilities of no reserve, low reserve, and high reserve are unchanged, increased, and decreased, respectively; and (ii) the government’s total quota index decreases under the strategy of no reserve and low reserve, and the reserve quantity decreases under the low-reserve strategy.
Next, the influence of parameters on the equilibrium rare-earth price p * is investigated. Figure 4 plots p * as a function of r G under (a) relative market potential t = a / b = 1 and rare-earth production cost c = 0.5 (solid line), (b) t = 1 and c = 0.7 (dashed line), and (c) t = 1.1 and c = 0.5 (dot-dashed line).
As can be seen from any curve in Figure 4, with the increase in r G , p shows three different changes: When r G is small, the government adopts the no-reserve strategy, and the equilibrium price p is independent of r G . When r G is at a medium level, the government adopts the low-reserve strategy. In this case, p increases first and then decreases in r G , because the market supply q ¯ * q * decreases first and then increases in r G . When r G is high, the government adopts the high-reserve strategy, and p increases with r G . By comparing the solid line with the dashed line in Figure 4, it can be seen that when the production cost c increases, the equilibrium price will increase both in the case of no reserve and low reserve, while the price will remain unchanged in the case of high reserve. The former is because the firm’s rare-earth supply q ¯ * q * decreases with the production cost in the case of no reserve or low reserve, so the firm should adjust the price in the opposite direction to balance the supply and demand. The latter is because, in the case of high-reserve, the government will always control the firm’s supply quantity according to q ¯ * q * = μ κ 2 (Equation (11)), which is not affected by the firm’s production cost. Comparing the solid line with the dot-dashed line in Figure 4, it is found that an increase in the relative market potential t = a / b leads to an increase in rare-earth price. This is because, when the relative market potential t increases, either the potential market demand faced by the firm increases (i.e., the market potential a increases) or the consumer becomes less sensitive to the rare-earth price (i.e., the price sensitivity factor b decreases), both of which will prompt the firm to set a higher price.
Finally, the influence of parameters on the expected social welfare and the firm’s expected profit is investigated. Figure 5a shows how the expected social welfare Π S W * * varies with r G under different parameter conditions. For the whole system, the expected NPV r G of unreleased reserve, the mean size of potential consumers μ and the relative market potential t can be regarded as efficiency parameters, while the firm’s production cost c is a cost parameter. Therefore, Figure 5a shows that the expected social welfare increases with r G , μ , and t and decreases with c . Figure 5b shows how the firm’s expected profit is affected by parameters when the government acquires rare-earth reserves at the price equaling the firm’s production cost. It can be seen that the firm’s expected profit increases with the mean size of potential consumers μ and the relative market potential t , and decreases with the production cost c , for the same reasons as before. However, Figure 5b also shows that the impact of r G on the firm’s expected profit is not monotone: when r G is small, the government does not reserve, and the firm’s expected profit is independent of r G ; when r G is not very small, the government adopts the low-reserve or high-reserve strategy, and an increase in r G will impact both the firm’s price and sales volume, so the firm’s expected profit may either increase or decrease. In addition, the firm’s expected profit is also related to the government’s reserve price w . Figure 5c simulates the relationship between the firm’s expected profit and r G when the government purchases reserves at a price that is α { 1 , 1.1 , 1.2 } times of the firm’s production cost.

5. Conclusions

In the new wave of scientific and technological revolution and industrial transformation, the application value of rare earth in social development and national economies has been further enhanced, and the importance of the total quota management and strategic reserve of rare-earth products has become increasingly prominent. This paper examines a multi-stage decision model of a rare-earth supply chain in a game-theoretic framework, and examines the government’s reserve decision and the rare-earth firm’s pricing decision under total quota management.
Several meaningful implications are generated for both the government and rare-earth firms. For the government, critical conditions of whether and at what level the government should keep rare-earth reserves are identified. The production cost and the expected net present value (NPV) of unreleased reserves are found to be key factors affecting the above decision. When the expected NPV of reserves is below a threshold, the government should not keep any reserve. Otherwise, it should keep a low or high level of reserve, depending on the relationship between the expected NPV of the reserve and the production cost: a low-reserve (high-reserve) strategy should be adopted if the former is lower (higher). Under situations where the low-reserve strategy is appropriate, the total quota index should be set as an increasing function of the expected NPV of the reserve, and the government should also release as much of the reserve as possible to meet the demand gap (if any). Under situations where the high-reserve strategy is appropriate, the total quota index should be set to be sufficiently large to cover the entire market demand, and the government can fill the demand gap (if any) by releasing only part of the reserve.
For the rare-earth firm, implications are derived from how the rare-earth price should be determined under different reserve strategies of the government. Under situations where the government adopts the no-reserve strategy, the firm should set a relatively low price that is independent of the expected NPV of reserve. Under situations where a low-reserve strategy is adopted, the firm should determine a price that first increases and then decreases with the expected NPV of reserves. Under situations where a high-reserve strategy is adopted, the firm should set a price that is increasing with the expected NPV of reserves. Moreover, a somewhat counterintuitive finding is observed: Under situations where the government adopts a high-reserve strategy, the equilibrium price does not change with the production cost. This is because the government, in this case, will always control the firm’s supply quantity to a certain level that is not affected by the production cost.
It should be noted that in order to obtain analytical solutions to the government’s optimization problem, we made some simplifications to the model, such as assuming a uniform demand distribution and ignoring the reserve costs of the government and the firm. In addition, China implements the policy of combining government reserves and commercial reserves. The preliminary study of the government reserve of rare earth in this paper will provide useful reference for future research on commercial and hybrid reserves of rare-earth products.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, J.C.; Methodology, J.C.; Formal analysis, J.C.; Investigation, J.C.; Writing—original draft preparation, J.C.; Writing—review and revision, J.C.; Supervision, W.Z. and X.L.; Project administration, W.Z. and X.L.; Funding acquisition, W.Z. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research is funded by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (grant no. 20XGL016).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Proof of Proposition 1. 
The first-order derivative of π S W ( q ¯ , q , p , q ^ ) with respect to q ^ is:
π S W q ^ = v G r G < 0 q ^ > D q ¯ + q ( a + b p ) / ( 2 b ) + t G r G q ^ D q ¯ + q
(i) when ( a + b p ) / ( 2 b ) + t G r G 0 , obviously, π S W / q ^ 0 always holds, and the optimal solution is q ^ = 0 . (ii) When ( a + b p ) / ( 2 b ) + t G r G > 0 , π S W ( q ¯ , q , p , q ^ ) increases in q ^ first and then decreases, and reaches the maximum value at q ^ = D q ¯ + q . Combined with the range of q ^ , i.e., [ 0 , q ] , the optimal solution can be obtained as follows:
q ^ = q D [ q ¯ , ) D q ¯ + q D [ q ¯ q , q ¯ ) 0 D [ 0 , q ¯ q ) = min { D , q ¯ } min { D , q ¯ q }
Summarizing the above two cases, it can be seen that the government’s optimal release quantity is Equation (5).
Substituting Equation (5) back into the government’s objective function (Equation (4)), the social welfare under the optimal release quantity can be obtained after necessary transformations, as given by Equation (6). □
Proof of Lemma 1.
For part (a), S ( z ) = 0 z F ¯ ( ξ ) d ξ is easily obtained by applying integration by parts according to the definition of expectation. In addition, S ( z ) E ε [ ε ] = μ since min { ε , z } ε . Part (b) is directly obtained from [38]. Part (c) is because S ( z ) = 0 z F ¯ ( ξ ) d ξ > 0 z F ¯ ( z ) d ξ = z F ¯ ( z ) . □
Proof of Proposition 2. 
The first-order derivative of Π F with respect to p is Π F / p = b T ( p ) / a . Since both a and b are positive, the sign of Π F / p depends entirely on T ( p ) . Easy to verify is that T ( p ) is decreasing in p :
T ( p ) = 2 S ( z 1 ) [ 1 η ( z 1 ) ] b z 1 2 ( p + t F v F ) f ( z 1 ) / ( a b p ) < 0
when p = v F ( < a / b ) , we have: T ( v F ) = ( a / b v F ) S ( z 1 ) + t F z 1 F ¯ ( z 1 ) + t F [ μ S ( z 1 ) ] > 0 (where μ S ( z 1 ) > 0 is guaranteed by Lemma 1a); when p a / b , we have: z 1 , S ( z 1 ) μ and z 1 F ¯ ( z 1 ) 0 , so lim p a / b T ( p ) = ( a / b v F ) μ < 0 holds. Therefore, there exists a unique p * ( v F , a / b ) such that T ( p * ) = 0 , and p * is the firm’s optimal price. □
Proof of Proposition 3. 
Proposition 2 and its proof have shown that p * is the unique solution to T ( p * ) = 0 , and T ( p ) < 0 holds for all p [ 0 , a / b ] and z > 0 . Since η ( z ) = F ¯ ( z ) [ 1 g ( z ) η ( z ) ] / S ( z ) (by definition) and η ( z ) 0 (by Lemma 1b), it follows that 1 g ( z ) η ( z ) 0 , i.e., g ( z ) 1 η ( z ) , there is:
T ( p ) / z 1 = F ¯ ( z 1 ) [ a / b p ( p + t F v F ) g ( z 1 ) ]                                F ¯ ( z 1 ) { a / b p ( p + t F v F ) [ 1 η ( z 1 ) ] } = F ¯ ( z 1 ) [ T ( p ) μ t F ] / S ( z 1 )
Thus, at p = p * , T ( p ) / z 1 μ t F F ¯ ( z 1 ) / S ( z 1 ) < 0 holds. Below, we prove the conclusions in Proposition 3 one by one.
(a) Take ( q ¯ q ) as a whole, and take the derivatives with respect to ( q ¯ q ) from both sides of Equation T ( p * ) = 0 , there is:
T ( p * ) p * ( q ¯ q ) + T ( p ) z 1 1 y ( p ) p = p * = 0
As T ( p * ) < 0 , [ T ( p ) / z 1 ] | p = p * < 0 and y ( p * ) 1 > 0 , there must be p * / ( q ¯ q ) < 0 to make the equation hold.
(b) Take the derivatives with respect to t F on both sides of the equation T ( p * ) = 0 , and one obtains
T ( p * ) p * t F S ( z 1 * ) + z 1 * F ¯ ( z 1 * ) + μ = 0
As T ( p * ) < 0 and S ( z 1 * ) + z 1 * F ¯ ( z 1 * ) + μ > 0 , there must be p * / t F > 0 for the equation to hold.
(c) Take the derivatives with respect to v F on both sides of Equation T ( p * ) = 0 , and one obtains:
T ( p * ) p * v F + S ( z 1 * ) z 1 * F ¯ ( z 1 * ) = 0
As S ( z 1 * ) z 1 * F ¯ ( z 1 * ) = S ( z 1 * ) [ 1 η ( z 1 * ) ] > 0 (Lemma 1c) and T ( p * ) < 0 , there must be p * / v F > 0 for the equation to hold.
(d) Take the derivatives with respect to a on both sides of Equation T ( p * ) = 0 , and we obtain
T ( p * ) p * a + T ( p ) z 1 z 1 * a p = p * + S ( z 1 * ) b = 0
As T ( p * ) < 0 , [ T ( p ) / z 1 ] | p = p * < 0 , z 1 * / a = b p * z 1 * / ( a 2 y ( p * ) ) < 0 , and S ( z 1 * ) / b > 0 , there must be p * / a > 0 to make the equation hold.
(e) Take the derivatives with respect to b on both sides of the equation T ( p * ) = 0 , and we obtain
T ( p * ) p * b + T ( p ) z 1 z 1 * b p = p * a S ( z 1 * ) b 2 = 0
As T ( p * ) < 0 [ T ( p ) / z 1 ] | p = p * < 0 a S ( z 1 * ) / b 2 < 0 , and z 1 * / b = p * z 1 * / ( a b p * ) > 0 , there must be p * / b < 0 for the equation to hold. □
Proof of Proposition 4. 
Noting that Π S W ( Q ) is a piecewise function of Q , we will solve the local optimal solution for each piece, and then determine the global optimal solution by comparing the local optimal values of the three pieces.
(1) When Q [ 0 , A 1 ] , the second-order derivative of Π S W 1 ( Q ) with respect to Q is Π S W 1 ( Q ) = μ t [ 12 Q ( 1 X ) + 1 ] / 4 < 0 , implying that Π S W 1 ( Q ) is concave in Q . Therefore, its local optimal solution can be uniquely determined by the following Kuhn–Tucker (KT) conditions:
Π S W 1 ( Q ) + λ 1 λ 2 = 0 , λ 1 Q = 0 , λ 2 ( A 1 Q ) = 0 , 0 Q A 1 , λ 1 0 , λ 2 0
where Π S W 1 ( Q ) = μ t ( 6 X Q 2 6 Q 2 Q + 2 X ) / 4 . Solving the above KT conditions yields the local optimal solution on the interval [ 0 , A 1 ] :
Q 1 = Q 1 * κ i f   6 A 1 2 ( 1 X ) + A 1 2 X 0 A 1 i f   6 A 1 2 ( 1 X ) + A 1 2 X < 0
(2) When Q [ A 1 , A 2 ] , the second-order derivative of Π S W 2 ( Q ) with respect to Q is Π S W 2 ( Q ) = μ t [ 3 Q 4 ( 1 X ) + X Y 4 ] / Q 3 < 0 , implying that Π S W 2 ( Q ) is concave in Q . Therefore, its local optimal solution can be uniquely determined by the following KT conditions:
Π S W 2 ( Q ) + λ 1 λ 2 = 0 , λ 1 ( Q A 1 ) = 0 , λ 2 ( A 2 Q ) = 0 , A 1 Q A 2 , λ 1 0 , λ 2 0
where Π S W 2 ( Q ) = μ t ( 6 X Q 4 + 2 X Y 4 6 Q 4 Q 2 Y 2 ) / ( 4 Q 2 ) . Solving the above KT conditions yields the local optimal solution on the interval [ A 1 , A 2 ] :
Q 2 = A 1 i f   6 A 1 4 ( 1 X ) + A 1 2 Y 2 2 X Y 4 > 0 Q 2 * = Y κ i f   6 A 1 4 ( 1 X ) + A 1 2 Y 2 2 X Y 4 0 6 A 2 4 ( 1 X ) + A 2 2 Y 2 2 X Y 4 0 A 2 i f   6 A 2 4 ( 1 X ) + A 2 2 Y 2 2 X Y 4 < 0
(3) When Q [ A 2 , Y ] , the first-order derivative of Π S W 3 ( Q ) with respect to Q is Π S W 3 ( Q ) = μ t Q ( 2 Q 2 9 Q + 8 X ) / 4 , whose sign is determined by the term 2 Q 2 9 Q + 8 X . On the interval [ A 2 , Y ] , 2 Q 2 9 Q + 8 X is decreasing in Q , and Q 3 = [ 9 81 64 X ] / 4 is the root of 2 Q 2 9 Q + 8 X = 0 (the other larger root is rounded off). Therefore, the local optimal solution of Π S W 3 ( Q ) on [ A 2 , Y ] is
Q 3 = A 2 i f   2 A 2 2 9 A 2 + 8 X < 0 Q 3 i f   2 A 2 2 9 A 2 + 8 X 0 2 Y 2 9 Y + 8 X 0 Y i f   2 Y 2 9 Y + 8 X > 0
Below we determine the global optimal solution by comparing the above three local optimal solutions.
(1) when 4 X < Y 2 , we have A 1 = A 2 = 4 X , and 6 A 1 2 ( 1 X ) + A 1 2 = 48 X ( 1 X ) + 1 > 0 in Equation (A6) is always true. Therefore, the optimal solution of the first piece (Equation (A6)) is simplified to Q 1 = Q 1 * . Similarly, the optimal solutions of the second and third pieces (Equations (A7) and (A8)) can be simplified to Q 2 = A 1 = 4 X and Q 2 = A 2 = 4 X , respectively. Since Q = 4 X is the feasible but non-optimal solution of the first piece, the local optimal solution Q 1 = Q 1 * of the first piece is the global optimal solution, namely
Q * = Q 1 * , X < Y 2 / 4
(2) When Y 2 4 X < Y , we have A 1 = Y 2 and A 2 = 4 X . In this case, 6 A 1 2 ( 1 X ) + A 1 2 X 0 in Equation (A6) is equivalent to X X 1 , where X 1 ( 6 Y 2 + 1 ) Y 2 / [ 2 ( 3 Y 4 + 1 ) ] . It is easy to verify that X 1 > Y 2 / 4 , but X 1 can be either larger or smaller than Y / 4 , so the optimal solution (Equation (A20)) of the first piece is
Q 1 = Q 1 * X ( Y 2 / 4 , min { Y / 4 , X 1 } ] Y 2 X ( min { Y / 4 , X 1 } , Y / 4 ]
Similarly, 6 A 1 4 ( 1 X ) + A 1 2 Y 2 2 X Y 4 > 0 in Equation (A7) is equivalent to X < X 1 , and 6 A 2 4 ( 1 X ) + A 2 2 Y 2 2 X Y 4 > 0 is always true, so Equation (A7) is converted to
Q 2 = Y 2 X ( Y 2 / 4 , min { Y / 4 , X 1 } ] Q 2 * X ( min { Y / 4 , X 1 } , Y / 4 ]
2 A 2 2 9 A 2 + 8 X < 0 in Equation (A8) is equivalent to X < 7 / 8 , which obviously holds, and 2 Y 2 9 Y + 8 X 0 also always holds. Therefore, Equation (A8) can be simplified to Q 3 = 4 X . Since 4 X is a feasible but non-optimal solution of the second piece, Equation (A8) cannot be a global optimal solution. Comparing Equations (A10) (A11), we can see that the global optimal solution for Y 2 4 X < Y is
Q * = Q 1 * X ( Y 2 / 4 , min { Y / 4 , X 1 } ] Q 2 * X ( min { Y / 4 , X 1 } , Y / 4 ]
(3) When Y 4 X < 4 , we have A 1 = Y 2 and A 2 = Y . In this case, 6 A 1 2 ( 1 X ) + A 1 2 X 0 in Equation (A6) is equivalent to X X 1 , while X 1 can be either larger or smaller than Y / 4 ; therefore, Equation (A6) becomes
Q 1 = Q 1 * X ( Y / 4 , max { Y / 4 , X 1 } ] Y 2 X ( max { Y / 4 , X 1 } , 1 )
In Equation (A7), 6 A 1 4 ( 1 X ) + A 1 2 Y 2 2 X Y 4 > 0 is equivalent to X < X 1 , 6 A 2 4 ( 1 X ) + A 2 2 Y 2 2 X Y 4 > 0 is equivalent to X < 7 / 8 , and X 1 < 7 / 8 ; therefore, Equation (A7) becomes
Q 2 = Y 2 X ( Y / 4 , max { Y / 4 , X 1 } ] Q 2 * X ( max { Y / 4 , X 1 } , 7 / 8 ] Y X ( 7 / 8 , 1 )
In Equation (A8), letting A 2 = Y yields Q 3 = Y . Since Y is a feasible but non-optimal solution to the second piece, Equation (A8) cannot be a globally optimal solution. By comparing Equations (A13) and (A14), the global optimal solution for Y 4 X < 4 can be obtained as follows:
Q * = Q 1 * X ( Y / 4 , max { Y / 4 , X 1 } ] Q 2 * X ( max { Y / 4 , X 1 } , 7 / 8 ] Y X ( 7 / 8 , 1 )
By combining Equations (A9), (A12) and (A15), the complete global optimal solution can be obtained as follows:
Q * = Q 1 * = κ X ( 0 , X 1 ] Q 2 * = Y κ X ( X 1 , 7 / 8 ] Q 3 * = Y X ( 7 / 8 , 1 )
Substituting Equation (A30) into q * = q ¯ μ ( Q * ) 2 , the optimal reserve quantity is obtained as shown in Equation (11). Then, substituting Equation (A16) back to Equation (10) obtains the maximized social welfare as shown in Equation (12). □
Proof of Proposition 5. 
By Equation (11), q * is increasing in q ¯ and decreasing in μ , so parts (d)–(e) are immediately proved. As (i) q * is decreasing in κ , (ii) κ is increasing in X , and (iii) X = 1 b r G / a is decreasing in b and r G and increasing in a , respectively, one can verify that q * is increasing in b and r G and decreasing in a ; hence, parts (a)–(c) are proved. □
Proof of Proposition 6. 
Since S W (Equation (12)) is a piecewise function of Y , below we first find the local optimal solution in each piece, and then determine the global optimal solution through comparison.
(1) Case r G [ t / 8 , 1 ) and q ¯ μ κ (i.e., Y 2 κ ). Since Π S W 1 * / Y = 2 μ ( r G c ) Y , Π S W 1 * is increasing in Y when r G c . Thus, the local optimal solution is Y = 1 , and the corresponding expected social welfare is Π S W 1 * * , as given by Equation (14); when r G < c , Π S W 1 * is decreasing in Y . Thus, the local optimal solution is Y = κ , and the corresponding expected social welfare is Π S W B * * = Π S W 1 * * μ ( 1 κ ) ( r G c ) .
(2) Case r G [ t / 8 , 1 ) and q ¯ μ κ (i.e., Y 2 κ ). The following KT conditions are necessary for finding the local optimal solution of Y :
Π S W 2 * / Y λ = 0 ,   λ ( κ Y ) = 0 ,   κ Y ,   λ 0
Solving the above K-T conditions yields: if r G < c , then Y = Y 2 * , and the corresponding expected social welfare is Π S W 2 * * , as given in Equation (14); if r G c , then Y = κ , and the corresponding expected social welfare is Π S W B * * .
(3) Case r G ( 0 , t / 8 ) . Solving Π S W 3 * / Y = μ Y ( 2 t Y 2 9 t Y 8 c + 8 t ) / 4 = 0 yields the optimal solution Y = Y 3 * , and the corresponding expected social welfare is Π S W 3 * * .
Comparing the above three cases, one can verify that the global optimal solution is as shown in Equation (13), and the corresponding expected social welfare is as shown in Equation (14). □

References

  1. Hau, L.; Zhu, H.; Yu, Y.; Yu, D. Time-frequency coherence and quantile causality between trade policy uncertainty and rare earth prices: Evidence from China and the US. Resour. Policy 2022, 75, 1–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Trench, A.; Sykes, J.P. Rare Earth Permanent Magnets and Their Place in the Future Economy. Engineering 2020, 6, 115–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Balaram, V. Rare earth elements: A review of applications, occurrence, exploration, analysis, recycling, and environmental impact. Geosci. Front. 2019, 10, 68–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Several Opinions of the State Council on Promoting Sustainable and Healthy Development of the Rare Earth Industry [2011] No.12. Available online: http://www.gov.cn/zhengce/content/2011-05/18/content_2425.htm?isappinstalled=0 (accessed on 28 September 2022).
  5. Notice of the Ministry of Industry and Information Technology on Printing and Distributing the Development Plan of Rare Earth Industry (2016-2020). Available online: http://www.gov.cn/xinwen/2016-10/18/content_5120998.htm (accessed on 28 September 2022).
  6. Public Solicitation of Opinions on the Rare Earth Management Regulations (Draft). Available online: https://www.miit.gov.cn/jgsj/zfs/gzdt/art/2021/art_0994492127994695baf1139a0d80dfc9.html (accessed on 28 September 2022).
  7. Notice of the Ministry of Natural Resources of the Ministry of Industry and Information Technology on Issuing Total Control Targets for Rare Earth Mining, Smelting and Separation in 2021 (Lian-yuan [2021] No.123 of the Ministry of Industry and Information Technology). Available online: https://www.miit.gov.cn/jgsj/ycls/wjfb/art/2021/art_4df211c3f5a547848d7f48ac406bce8f.html (accessed on 28 September 2022).
  8. Zheng, B.; Zhang, Y.; Chen, Y. Asymmetric connectedness and dynamic spillovers between renewable energy and rare earth markets in China: Evidence from firms’ high-frequency data. Resour. Policy 2021, 71, 101996. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Wang, J.; Guo, M.; Liu, M.; Wei, X. Long-term outlook for global rare earth production. Resour. Policy 2020, 65, 101569. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Ilankoon, I.M.; Dushyantha, N.P.; Mancheri, N.; Edirisinghe, P.M.; Neethling, S.J.; Ratnayake, N.P.; Rohitha, L.P.; Dissanayake, D.M.; Premasiri, H.M.; Abeysinghe, A.M.; et al. Constraints to rare earth elements supply diversification: Evidence from an industry survey. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 331, 129932. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Sprecher, B.; Daigo, I.; Murakami, S.; Kleijn, R.; Vos, M.; Kramer, G.J. Framework for resilience in material supply chains, with a case study from the 2010 rare earth crisis. Environ. Sci. Technol. 2015, 49, 6740–6750. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Mancheri, N.A.; Sprecher, B.; Bailey, G.; Ge, J.; Tukker, A. Effect of Chinese policies on rare earth supply chain resilience. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2019, 142, 101–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Zhou, L.; Ge, J. Estimating the environmental cost of mixed rare earth production with willingness to pay: A case study in Baotou, China. Extrac. Indus. Soc. 2021, 8, 340–354. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Liang, X.; Ye, M.; Li, Y.; Fu, W.; Li, Z. Evaluation and Policy Research on the Sustainable Development of China’s Rare Earth Resources. Sustainability 2018, 10, 3792. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Wübbeke, J. Rare earth elements in China: Policies and narratives of reinventing an industry. Resour. Policy 2013, 38, 384–394. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Han, A.; Ge, J.; Lei, Y. An adjustment in regulation policies and its effects on market supply: Game analysis for China’s rare earths. Res. Policy 2015, 46, 30–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Brown, M.; Eggert, R. Simulating producer responses to selected chinese rare earth policies. Resour. Policy 2018, 55, 31–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Lee, H.H.; Nunez, M.; Cruz, J. Competition for limited critical resources and the adoption of environmentally sustainable strategies. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2018, 264, 1130–1143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Wu, G.; Wei, Y.M.; Nielsen, C.; Lu, X.; McElroy, M.B. A dynamic pro-gramming model of China’s strategic petroleum reserve: General strategy and the effect of emergencies. Energy Econom. 2012, 34, 1234–1243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Cui, H.; Wei, P. Analysis of thermal coal pricing and the coal price distortion in China from the perspective of market forces. Energy Polcyi. 2017, 106, 148–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Rademeyer, M.; Minnitt, R.; Falcon, R. Multi-product coal distribution and price discovery for the domestic market via mathematical optimisation. Min. Econom. 2021, 34, 113–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Hu, Z.; Tian, J.; Feng, G. A relief supplies purchasing model based on a put option contract. Comp. Ind. Eng. 2019, 127, 253–262. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Hu, S.; Dong, Z.S. Supplier selection and pre-positioning strategy in humanitarian relief. Omega 2019, 83, 287–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Liang, L.; Wang, X.; Cao, J. An option contract pricing model of relief material supply chain. Omega 2012, 40, 594–600. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Notice on the Issuance of Interim Measures for the Administration of Mandatory Production Plans for Rare Earth. Available online: https://www.miit.gov.cn/zwgk/zcwj/wjfb/yclgy/art/2020/art_b70b7ffd48ea485d979d4f31d2b6e5ee.html (accessed on 28 September 2022).
  26. Xue, W.; Demirag, O.C.; Niu, B. Supply chain performance and consumer surplus under alternative structures of channel dominance. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2014, 239, 130–145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Li, Y.; Youhua, F.C.; Houmin, Y. The newsvendor problem with pricing: Extensions, Inter. J. Manag. Sci. Enge. Manag. 2006, 1, 3–16. [Google Scholar]
  28. Federgruen, A.; Heching, A. Multilocation Combined Pricing and Inventory Control. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2002, 4, 275–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Luo, C.; Tian, X. Operational Strategy of Supply Chain with Price-dependent Stochastic Demand under the CVaR Criterion. Manag. Rev. 2015, 27, 167–176. [Google Scholar]
  30. Banciu, M.; Mirchandani, P. Technical Note—New Results Concerning Probability Distributions with Increasing Generalized Failure Rates. Oper. Res. 2013, 61, 925–931. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Bish, E.K.; Liu, J.; Bish, D.R. A note on “resource flexibility with responsive pricing”. Naval Res. Log. 2010, 57, 119–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Sarhan, A.M.; Kundu, D. Generalized Linear Failure Rate Distribution. Theory Methods 2009, 38, 642–660. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  33. Han, A.; Ge, J.; Lei, Y. Vertical vs. horizontal integration: Game analysis for the rare earth industrial integration in China. Res. Policy 2016, 50, 149–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Dobson, P.W.; Waterson, M. Countervailing power and consumer prices. Econom. J. 1997, 107, 418–430. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Chen, Z.; Su, S.I.I. Dual competing photovoltaic supply chains: A social welfare maximization perspective. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2017, 14, 1416. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  36. Sinayi, M.; Rasti-Barzoki, M. A game theoretic approach for pricing, greening, and social welfare policies in a supply chain with government intervention. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 196, 1443–1458. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Carter, C.R.; Rogers, D.S. A framework of sustainable supply chain management: Moving toward new theory. Int. J. Phys. Distr. Log. 2008, 38, 360–387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Petruzzi, N.; Dada, M. Pricing and the News Vendor Problem: A Review with Extensions. Oper. Res. 2011, 47, 183–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Model structure and sequence of events.
Figure 1. Model structure and sequence of events.
Sustainability 14 14883 g001
Figure 2. The government’s reserve strategies.
Figure 2. The government’s reserve strategies.
Sustainability 14 14883 g002
Figure 3. The total quota index q ¯ * , reserve quantity q * and expected unreleased reserve q * E [ q ^ * ] change with parameters.
Figure 3. The total quota index q ¯ * , reserve quantity q * and expected unreleased reserve q * E [ q ^ * ] change with parameters.
Sustainability 14 14883 g003
Figure 4. Equilibrium price p * changes with parameters.
Figure 4. Equilibrium price p * changes with parameters.
Sustainability 14 14883 g004
Figure 5. Impacts of parameters on the expected social welfare and the firm’s expected profit. In the left and middle plots, the solid curve is the benchmark curve, and all other curves involve a parameter (marked in red font) different from the benchmark curve.
Figure 5. Impacts of parameters on the expected social welfare and the firm’s expected profit. In the left and middle plots, the solid curve is the benchmark curve, and all other curves involve a parameter (marked in red font) different from the benchmark curve.
Sustainability 14 14883 g005
Table 1. Summary of notations.
Table 1. Summary of notations.
NotationDescription
q ¯ Government’s total quota index;
q Government s   reserve   quantity ,   q [ 0 , q ¯ ] ;
q ^ Government’s reserve-release quantity, q ^ [ 0 , q ] ;
p Market price of rare-earth products;
w Government’s purchasing price for reserve;
c Firm’s unit production cost;
c G Government’s unit reserve cost;
v G / v F Government’s/firm’s unit salvage value;
t G / t F Government’s/firm’s unit loss of shortage;
r G Expected net present value (NPV) of the unreleased reserve;
ε Size   of   potential   consumers ,   with   cdf   F ( ) , pdf f ( ) and mean μ;
y ( p ) Demand ratio at price p , y ( p ) = ( a b p ) / a ;
D Demand at price p , D = y ( p ) ε ;
π G / Π G Government s   profit / expected   profit ,   Π G = E ε [ π G ] ;
π F / Π F Firm’s profit/expected profit, Π F = E ε [ π F ] ;
π C / Π C Consumer’s surplus/expected surplus, Π C = E ε [ π C ] ;
π S W / Π S W Social welfare/expected social welfare, π S W = π G + π F + π C , Π S W = E ε [ π S W ] .
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Chen, J.; Zhu, W.; Luo, X. Government Reserve of Rare Earths under Total Quota Management: An Interactive Game between Government and Rare-Earth Firms. Sustainability 2022, 14, 14883. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142214883

AMA Style

Chen J, Zhu W, Luo X. Government Reserve of Rare Earths under Total Quota Management: An Interactive Game between Government and Rare-Earth Firms. Sustainability. 2022; 14(22):14883. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142214883

Chicago/Turabian Style

Chen, Jianyun, Wenxing Zhu, and Xianping Luo. 2022. "Government Reserve of Rare Earths under Total Quota Management: An Interactive Game between Government and Rare-Earth Firms" Sustainability 14, no. 22: 14883. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142214883

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop