Next Article in Journal
Green and Compact: A Spatial Planning Model for Knowledge-Based Urban Development in Peri-Urban Areas
Next Article in Special Issue
Current Status and Future Directions of Deep Learning Applications for Safety Management in Construction
Previous Article in Journal
Inspection and Assessment of Masonry Arch Bridges: Ivanjica Case Study
Previous Article in Special Issue
Relationships among Perceived Control, Safety Attitude, and Safety Performance: A Case Study on Wastewater Treatment Plant Workers
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Developing a Construction Safety Standard System to Enhance Safety Supervision Efficiency in China: A Theoretical Simulation of the Evolutionary Game Process

School of Economics and Management, Tongji University, Shanghai 200092, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2021, 13(23), 13364; https://doi.org/10.3390/su132313364
Submission received: 26 August 2021 / Revised: 16 November 2021 / Accepted: 17 November 2021 / Published: 2 December 2021
(This article belongs to the Collection Advances in Construction Safety Management Practices)

Abstract

:
Labor safety is one of the most fundamental indicators to improve contractors’ sustainability. Safety supervision plays a crucial role in affecting the safety performance of infrastructure projects. However, studies of standards development to enhance safety supervision efficiency are far from complete. Safety standards define safe behaviors for construction workers and hazard control processes in the workplace, and they are usually considered as an important part of safety control. In addition, the systematic reform of construction safety standards in China provides an innovative perspective to enhance safety supervision efficiency by linking standards to supervision. For this purpose, this paper proposes the concept and framework of the “Construction Safety Standard System (CSSS)” through expert interviews. CSSS hierarchically classifies safety standards and integrates similar standards. Its implementation will significantly influence the behavioral decisions of safety supervision stakeholders. Evolutionary game (EG) theory is applied to demonstrate the decision-making procedure in CSSS establishment and application. Furthermore, system dynamics (SD) is utilized to model and analyze equilibrium states under different supervision strategies. Meanwhile, case studies are implemented to assess the CSSS’s effectiveness in reality. The numerical results indicate that through CSSS implementation, the strategy choice fluctuation of supervisors and contractors is suppressed and a more desirable stable equilibrium is reached. The government tends to supervise and contractors tend to obey safety standards consciously. The findings reveal that CSSS can enhance safety supervision efficiency and have meaningful implications for theoretical study on safety supervision and construction safety management practice.

1. Introduction

The construction industry is regarded as one of the riskiest fields, mainly since laborers are exposed to a changeable workplace that contains heavy equipment, noise, and other serious hazards [1]. It employs approximately 7% of global workforce, nevertheless, about 100,000 workers die on construction sites each year, which accounts for approximately 35% of global professional fatalities [2,3,4]. In South Korea, the United Kingdom, and the USA, fatalities related to construction account for 27.6%, 27.2%, and 20% of all professional fatalities, respectively [5,6]. In China, the proportion of fatalities in the construction industry is far above other industries [7,8]. When a safety accident occurs, it attracts the attention of the whole society since the construction industry is intimately associated with the lives of the general public. Fatalities have a detrimental influence on contractors’ competitiveness since they cause not only financial loss but also loss of life [9,10]. The lack development of contractor safety standards will seriously hinder the healthy development of the whole industry. As a result, it is crucial to improve the safety performance of infrastructure projects [11]. Previous research has demonstrated that safety standards play a major role in defining the safe behavior of workers, controlling hazards in the workplace, diminishing the number of fatalities, and improving the safety performance of infrastructure projects [12].
Additionally, there are growing appeals for improving safety supervision [13,14,15,16]. Theories of construction safety supervision are, however, focused on explaining how to regularly inspect and evaluate the safety condition of the contractors’ construction sites [14]. In studies of other industries, penalties have been widely considered to be a good way to enhance safety supervision efficiency [15,16,17,18,19].
Only a few studies focus on the role of standards in safety supervision [20,21,22]. A standard is a normative instrument that is jointly developed by the people or representatives, adopted by consensus, and observed by all members of the group together. Safety standards are often seen as a vital part of security control [23]. However, the role of safety standards in safety supervision is still not complete in China.
There are two fundamental issues with the application of safety standards in China. First, many standards are not adequately implemented [24]. Second, some standards have fallen behind the development of the industry [25]. Safety standards define safe behaviors and safe control strategies to control workplace hazards, yet governmental supervision authorities (GSA) often focus on major items, such as scaffolding, construction elevators, and crane operations [26]. Other items that may cause safety hazards are rarely listed in regulation content. In addition, inconsistent regulatory guidelines in different regions have led to different construction safety standards (CSS) and inefficient management of construction contractors. More seriously, some standards are not operational. Nevertheless, self-regulation of contractors cannot control safety risks. As contractors pursue profit maximization, they place a greater emphasis on the final value of construction products and pay insufficient attention to safety issues. Therefore, contractors are motivated to take chances and disregard the application of CSS to keep the construction project on schedule [27,28].
Therefore, it is important to solve the problems of CSS application. Although previous studies have suggested the concept of a “construction standard system” [29,30], a safety-related standard system has rarely been studied directly. Some studies suggested enhancing construction safety supervision efficiency from the perspective of the government or made recommendations for standardizing safety production management from the standpoint of contractors [31,32]. Nevertheless, CSS application issues are the interaction of multiple factors rather than one type of standard or standard-related party, such as the government or contractors, unilaterally. One approach to address this issue involves evolutionary game (EG) theory, which has been generally accepted in the area of construction safety supervision by modeling decision-making procedures. However, existing studies have mostly concentrated on modeling the game procedure between two players [33] and rarely have focused on multiplayer game situations.
This research seeks to solve two problems: (1) how to unify the CSS of supervision and safety production to improve CSS integration and operability; and (2) how to analyze standard stakeholders’ decision-making interactions and identify behavioral characteristics to theoretically verify the effectiveness of CSSS for safety supervision. Given this, this study proposes a “Construction Safety Standards System (CSSS)” and designs a prototype of a “Construction Safety Standards System Table (CSSST)” to achieve the unification of CSS. A multiplayer EG model is constructed and system dynamics (SD) simulation is used to validate the role of CSSS in enhancing safety supervision efficiency. To assess the CSSS’s effectiveness in real-world scenarios, we implemented case studies.
The main outcomes of this research are as follows: (1) the prototype of CSSST has been established and its critical role in enhancing the safety supervision efficiency has been validated; (2) the introduction of CSSST has resulted in a tripartite game of standard management authorities (SMA), GSA, and contractors. The collaboration of EG and SD simulation resolves the problem of multiplayer interrelation, which has seldom been implemented in existing research.

2. Literature Review

Studies have shown that safety supervision is a game procedure, so we can adopt game theory to investigate safety supervision issues [34,35,36,37]. With the rapid development of game theory, EG theory has increasingly developed into a practical method for analyzing decision-making behavior [34,35,36,37,38].
The core thought of EG theory is that the stakeholders play repetitive games in a system [34]. EG theory is premised on the hypothesis of limited rational players, which means each player cannot achieve the ideal solution in every game, and they will change strategy dynamically [39]. To further research the game equilibrium state, replicator dynamics was proposed to describe the strategy’s probability in a system [35]. The game equilibrium state is reached when the increased proportion of the replication dynamics is zero [35]. Additionally, to describe a stable game equilibrium state, Evolutionary Stable Strategy (ESS) was proposed [39]. If ESS exists, the probability of a particular strategy will remain constant [39]. In the process of reaching ESS, each player’s behavior is influenced by other players’ current strategies [39]. Therefore, it is important to identify participants and available strategies. EG considers the limited reasonability of players and players can adjust their strategies, which is more in agreement with real management situations. Supervisors and contractors create conflicts of interest due to the different requirements and goals [16]. They behave as limited rational stakeholders due to the difficulty of problems or cognitive limitations [40]. They regulate strategies dynamically to optimize their income by observing and comparing payoffs. Therefore, interactions between supervisors and contractors can be seen as a dynamic game process [40].
Most of the existing research focuses on the dual supervision game. For example, Hausken and Zhuang [41,42] utilized game theory to model the game process between enterprise and governmental supervisors. Chen et al. [43] adopted the EG model to investigate the game process between developers and governmental supervisors. Analogous studies have been implemented by Zhou et al. [44], Liu et al. [45], Cheng and Chen [40], Cao and Wang [46], Liu et al. [47], Shan et al. [48], Yu et al. [49], and Feng et al. [50]. In addition, the game equilibrium state of the dual supervision game will be affected by a few factors such as contractors’ safety efforts, penalties for failing to comply with standards, benefits of safety measure adoption to society and contractors, GSA investments and benefits, and penalties for GSA when the supervision is not performed [47,48,49,50]. The cyclical fluctuation phenomenon appears in safety supervision [47,48,49,50]. The initial state of game players and the income of various strategies are the two principal factors of the fluctuation occurrence [47,48,49,50].
However, with the introduction of CSSST, SMA joined the evolutionary game process between GSA and contractors. Compared to the two-party evolutionary game, the game equilibrium state of the three-party evolutionary game is more complex [51]. In addition, EG theory has its limits when it comes to showing the way to equilibrium [52]. Some scholars pointed out SD can be adapted to analyze the equilibrium solutions of the multiplayer evolutionary games [53]. SD combines qualitative and quantitative analysis to study the interactions and behavior of complex systems through simulation [54]. It does not pursue the “best solution” but rather looks for solutions to improve system behavior by observing the overall situation [50]. Existing studies have utilized SD to analyze multiplayers’ equilibrium points, such as safety regulation [53], railroad supervision [50], and construction behavior safety [55].
In sum, there are two central gaps in previous studies. First, standards play an important role in safety supervision. However, how to formulate a unified safety standard and implement it mostly stay at the level of opinions and suggestions, and no new tools have been introduced to maximize the role of safety standards. Second, previous research mostly concentrates on the interaction between GSA and contractors in the evolutionary game, while there is less research considering the participation of SMA. Therefore, this paper proposes a new tool for enhancing safety supervision efficiency: CSSST. The concept of CSSST will be introduced in detail in the next section. Under the guidance of CSSST, contractors will have a better understanding of what should and should not be done on construction sites at lower costs, and governmental supervisors will be less burdened with work. As for the research method, this study appropriately adopts EG theory to study the stable strategy among SMA, GSA, and contractors. SD is used to model EG procedure of supervision. The collaboration of these two approaches helps to explain the different outcomes of each strategy and to identify the key factors in the implementation of CSSST.

3. Methodology

3.1. Overall Research Framework

We adopt a four-step research methodology as follows: (1) presenting the concept of CSSS and designing the prototype of CSSST and the CSSS feedback platform, (2) designing a multiplayer evolutionary game model and using system dynamics simulation, (3) conducting numerical experiments and the related analysis to validate the important role of CSSS in improving safety performance, and (4) verifying the effectiveness of CSSS in a real-world by conducting case studies. Figure 1 depicts the overall research framework.

3.2. CSSS and the CSSS Feedback Platform

CSSS is an innovative method that has not been widely used in safety supervision, expert group interviews are employed to discuss the concept of CSSS, the prototype of CSSST, and the CSSS feedback platform, as this is a good way to propose innovative ideas by utilizing the wisdom of the expert group [56], We had brainstorming meetings with an expert panel of twenty-five construction safety experts. Moreover, the expert group consisted of eight security professionals, ten safety managers of contracted projects, four experts from the China Construction Safety Association, and three scholars from diverse and geographically dispersed organizations in China. The team members had over ten years of safety management experience. The certificates of these experts agree with the previous research [1].
The research team formed two subcommittees to conduct research: (1) the concept of CSSS and the prototype of CSSST; (2) the CSSS feedback platform and the implementation flow of the CSSS feedback platform. To ensure the consistency of the results, two subcommittees reported weekly to the entire research group. The following two subsections present the results of the expert group interviews.

3.2.1. The Concept of CSSS and the Prototype of CSSST

Previous studies have suggested the “construction standard system” and highlighted its importance in ensuring the sustainable development of the construction industry [29,30]. CSSS will also improve the safety performance of infrastructure projects, reduce safety supervision costs, enhance safety supervision efficiency, and promote the sustainability of the construction industry [57]. CSSS is defined as a scientific and organic system of documents formed by CSS according to their internal links. CSSST refers to a set of well-organized content tables of CSS. Other countries can utilize the same guidelines and methods to establish a system of CSS suitable for their national conditions. Through this work, we aim to accomplish systematic management of CSS.
CSSS is divided into three levels, which are Basic Standards (BS), General Standards (GS), and Specialized Standards (SS). BS are the basis for the development of the other standards in CSSS. According to the content, BS are divided into terminology standards, classification standards, and logo standards. BS strive to cover and unify the definitions and concepts that GS and SS may involve. GS refer to unified standards applicable to a certain stage or certain matter of construction, such as risk identification and electricity use. SS refer to management or technical standards applicable to specific objects, entities, and processes. SS and GS have a uniform structure. The structure of CSSS is shown in Figure 2.

3.2.2. The CSSS Feedback Platform and the Implementation Flow of the CSSS Feedback Platform

Based on the framework of CSSS, we designed a CSSS feedback platform. The platform provides structured forms to collect contractors’ feedback information on CSS usage. Thus, GSA and SMA have timely access to related information of CSS errors, questions about CSS, and contractors’ comments on CSS. This platform combines CSSS development and safety supervision. Given this, GSA can adjust their supervision strategies to control safety in the construction industry, and SMA can update their standard development plan to meet the needs of contractors. The implementation flow schematic of the CSSS Feedback Platform is illustrated in Figure 3.
As shown in Figure 3, the implementation flow of the CSSS feedback platform includes four steps: (1) CSS formulation; this process mainly involves the participation of SMA and GSA. SMA focus on the development and management of the entire process of CSS, while GSA focus on standard operability. SMA are responsible for the CSS project approval. GSA and SMA need to form a joint force to cultivate a sustainable standard development team with professional capabilities. In addition, GSA and SMA are responsible for CSS publicity and training. The CSS project approval, compilation, review, publicity, and training should be based on a unified CSSS framework. (2) CSS application; this process involves the participation of GSA and contractors. CSSS also serves as a prerequisite in CSS application. Specifically, contractors should strengthen daily supervision of CSS implementation in compliance with the contract. GSA implement hierarchical supervision according to CSSS. (3) CSS application feedback; this process involves the participation of contractors. The CSSS feedback platform provides a structured standard usage feedback form to facilitate the collection of standard errors and questions. Thus, GSA and SMA have timely access to related information for CSSS updates. This process further strengthens CSSS operability. (4) Government response; when GSA receive comments and suggestions from contractors, they should act quickly to respond, alter their regulatory strategy, and report to SMA to amend CSSS and CSS.

3.3. Evolutionary Game Theory

As described in Section 2, EG theory concentrates on strategy adjustments [15]. As stakeholders, SMA, GSA, and contractors dynamically adjust strategies to maximize their benefits. Therefore, EG theory is adopted to analyze the behavior between stakeholders.

3.3.1. Evolutionary Game Relationship Description and Strategy Choices

As described in Section 2, we can analyze the game equilibrium state based on replicator dynamic equations [34,39]. The replicator dynamics equation uses a form of dynamic differential equation to describe the probability of a strategy in a group [35]. The game equilibrium state is reached when the increased proportion of the replication dynamics is zero [35]. ESS is the stable equilibrium state that players may eventually reach [39]. If ESS exists, the probability of a particular strategy will remain constant [39]. In the process of reaching ESS, each player’s behavior is influenced by other players’ current strategies [39]. Therefore, it is important to identify participants and available strategies.
According to the description of CSSS in Section 3.2, the behavior of SMA also has an impact on supervision. Thus, SMA should be considered in the evolutionary game of GSA and contractors. Given this, this paper will establish a multiplayer evolutionary game model that includes SMA, GSA, and contractors. The relationship between stakeholders is shown in Figure 4.
GSA supervise contractors concerning CSS. Considering supervision costs and construction safety requests, GSA’s strategy space is {supervision, not supervision}. Contractors are regulated and they should comply with CSSS. Considering safety investments and penalties, contractors’ strategy space is {obeying CSS, not obeying CSS}. Considering social benefits obtained by CSSST application and costs of CSSST construction, SMA’s strategy space is {making CSSS, not making CSSS}.

3.3.2. Parameters and Payoff Matrix

After discussing with the expert panel of twenty-five construction safety experts mentioned in Section 3.2, We propose the following parameters of three stakeholders.
1.
Each player only has two pure strategy choices at time t. Assume that GSA supervises the contractors with a probability x (0 ≤ x ≤ 1). x = 1 implies that GSA supervise the contractors in realtime, then x = 0 implies that GSA choose not to supervise contractors’ security operations.
(1)
B g denotes the expected loss of social benefits as a result of not obeying CSS, including public economic loss and distrust of the society towards the government.
(2)
C g denotes GSA’s supervision costs.
(3)
F denotes the probability of construction accidents.
(4)
N denotes GSA’s penalties as a result of negative supervision when accidents occur.
(5)
S g denotes supervision costs saved due to GSA’s CSSST application, including the reduction in personnel and material costs.
2.
Assume that the contractors obey CSS with a probability y (0 ≤ y ≤ 1). Therefore, the probability of contractors not obeying CSS is (1 − y).
(1)
π denotes normal revenue from regular safety production.
(2)
C e represents contractors’ safety investments.
(3)
L denotes the expected loss of contractors in case of an accident.
(4)
S e denotes investments saved due to contractors’ CSSS application.
(5)
MP 1 and MP denote contractors’ penalties as a result of not obeying CSS when accidents occur. Considering the possibility of supervision errors, P is supervision accuracy without CSSST application, and P 1 is supervision accuracy with CSSST application ( 0 < p < p 1 < 1 ) . M represents contractor’s penalties as a result of not obeying CSS. MP 1 and MP will be received by GSA.
3.
Assume that SMA make CSSST with a probability z (0 ≤ z ≤ 1). Therefore, the probability of SMA not making CSSST is (1 − z).
(1)
C s represents making CSSST costs, including research and participant coordination costs.
(2)
U s represents social benefits obtained by CSSST application, which refers to the enhancement of safety performance in infrastructure projects, the reduction in supervision costs of the whole industry, and the improvement of supervision efficiency brought by the recognition and wide use of CSSST.
The variables are listed in Table 1 and the payment matrix between GSA, contractors, and SMA is exemplified in Table 2.

3.4. System Dynamics Simulation and Validation

As we mentioned in Section 2, multiplayer evolutionary game analysis cannot show the path to the equilibrium state [52], while SD can intuitively reflect strategy changes and help us to observe the game state from a global perspective [50]. Hence, this research adopts SD simulation to verify the EG process and analyze the application effect.
To validate the effectiveness of CSSST, we enter the practical data of safety supervision in China into the SD model. According to the China Statistical Yearbook on Construction [58], the average contractors’ income ( π ) is 6.3% of the overall expense of projects. According to the Shanghai safety input regulation, contractors’ safety investments ( C e ) are 3% of the overall project expense. Contractors’ safety investments account for 0.727% of GDP, and the loss caused by accidents (L) is 2.5% of GDP. According to the Administrative Regulations on the Work Safety of Construction Projects [59], contractors’ penalties (M) account for 20–50% of the misappropriated safety investment. The misappropriated safety investment is equal to the safety cost that should be invested minus the actual safety investment. Assuming that the actual safety investment is 2.5% of the overall project expense, we obtain the range of contractors’ penalties (M). The ratio of other parameters to the total cost of the construction project was determined after expert seminars. The original estimates of variables are as in Table 3 after pretreatment.

3.5. Case Studies

We investigated six cases in different regions of China to evaluate the effectiveness of CSSS. Case projects were selected through connection with member companies of the China Construction Safety Industry Association. CSSS has been only carried out on a pilot basis in relatively developed areas of China, such as Beijing and Shanghai. The research team selected signature projects of relatively large contractors, because these projects have basic information systems and the highest potential for the implementation of innovative security methods [60]. Previous research suggests at least four to ten cases when examining complicated correlations [61]. The case study information comes from the Research Report of the Ministry of Housing and Urban-Rural Development on the Safety Standard System of Construction. The summary of the case study information is provided in Table 4.
In particular, all cases included on-site inspections, interviews with the project manager, and the collection of supporting documentation. We also conducted face-to-face interviews with governmental safety supervisors in Beijing, Shanghai, Shandong, and Hubei.
Our interview questionnaire was mainly separated into two components. One was the situation of CSS usage before CSSS application. The purpose of designing this component was to verify the necessity of CSSS. We specifically included the following four questions: (1) Before the application of CSSS, were there any unclear expressions in the provisions of individual construction safety standards? (2) Before the application of CSSS, were there contradictory provisions of individual construction safety standards and codes? (3) Before the application of CSSS, were there a lack of individual key standards? (4) Before the application of CSSS, were individual standards falling behind the industry and technology development? The purpose of this part was only to reflect the problems existing in the CSS application before the CSSS application, these four questions were structured to solicit a yes or no response. The other component was to directly verify the effectiveness of CSSS, and the interview questions for the project manager and governmental safety supervisors were slightly different. For the project manager, it mainly included the following three questions: (1) If the government no longer carries out strong supervision, will the project still be produced according to the standards? (2) Has the efficiency of project safety management been improved after the application of CSSS and with the government’s preference for safety supervision? What are the specific aspects? (3) After CSSS application, and with the government’s preference for safety supervision, is the motivation for project safety management improved? What are the specific aspects? For the governmental safety supervisors, it mainly included the following two questions: (1) After the application of CSSS, has the efficiency of government safety supervision been improved? What are the specific aspects? (2) Has the enthusiasm for government safety supervision been improved after the application of CSSS? What are the specific aspects? The questionnaires are shown in Appendix A and Appendix B.
The questionnaires needed to guarantee internal and external effectiveness [62]. For this reason, the research team did not clarify the definition of safety supervision efficiency in the interview, but explained it with questions like “Do you think your work efficiency and enthusiasm have been improved after CSSS application? In what areas?”. Furthermore, we researched different types of projects from four different regions in China to ensure external effectiveness.

4. Results

4.1. Results of The Multiplayer EG and SD Simulation

4.1.1. Replicator Dynamics

As mentioned in Section 2, replicator dynamics was used to describe the probability of a strategy in a system [35]. In the supervision procedure, we can adapt the replication dynamics to demonstrate the strategy adjustment procedure of players. Hence, the replicator dynamic equations of GSA, F(x); Contractors, F(x), and GSA, F(z), are calculated as Equations (1)–(3). The details are presented in Appendix C.
F x = dx dt = x   ×   ( 1 x )   ×   [ ( MP MP 1 )   ×   y   ×   z + ( MP 1 MP + S g )   ×   z ( MP + FN )   ×   y + ( MP + FN C g ) ]
F ( y ) = dy dt = y   ×   ( 1 y )   ×   [ ( MP 1 MP )   ×   x   ×   z + S e   ×   z + MP   ×   x + ( FL C e ) ]
F ( z ) = dz dt = z   ×   ( 1 z )   ×   ( U s   ×   y C s )

4.1.2. SD Flow Chart

According to Section 3.3, Section 3.4 and Section 4.1, we developed a multiplayer evolutionary game SD model by using Vensim PLE (Personal Learning Edition). Vensim is simulation software for visualizing and analyzing dynamic systems, which allows for model veracity checking. The SD flow chart is shown in Figure 5.
The model contains horizontal variables, rate variables, auxiliary variables, and external variables. The relationship between these variables is premised on Equations (1)–(3). Specifically, horizontal variables involve the probability of supervision x, the probability of obeying CSS y, and the probability of making CSSST z, which characterize the accumulation of the system. Rate variables involve the adjustment rate of supervision F x , the change rate of obeying CSS F y , and the change rate of making CSSST F z , which characterize the decision-making procedure. Auxiliary variables refer to transition variables in the calculation. External variables are in line with the original estimates in Table 3. We used different colored lines to demonstrate the GSA supervision submodule, the contractors obeying CSS submodule, and the SMA making CSSST submodule. Detailed SD model equations can be found in Appendix D.

4.1.3. Result Analysis of SD Simulation

(1) Impact Analysis of CSSS Implementation

To validate the effectiveness of CSSS, we first compared results under the strategy of making CSSS and not making CSSS. Without loss of generality, let GSA’s initial strategy x 0 = y 0 = 0.5 and z 0 = 0 . This represents the case where CSSS is not implemented, which is marked as “CSSS not implemented”. When CSSS is implemented, let x 0 = y 0 = 0.5 and z 0 = 0.1 . This case is marked as “CSSS implemented”.
The simulation result of GSA is shown in Figure 6. Dmnl is the unit of variables x, y, and z, indicating that their unit is 1. The result illustrates that GSA’s strategy selections fluctuate periodically when CSSS is not in use, however, after CSSS is implemented, the fluctuation of GSA’s strategy selection could be effectively suppressed.
The simulation result of contractors is shown in Figure 7. Dmnl is the unit of variables x, y, and z, indicating that their unit is 1. The result illustrates that the strategic choices of contractors also fluctuate when CSSS is not in use. After the implementation of CSSS, the fluctuation of contractors’ strategy selection could be effectively suppressed, thereby stabilizing the game.

(2) ESS Analysis

ESS is the equilibrium state [39]. If ESS exists, the probability of stakeholders’ strategy will eventually remain constant [39]. To analyze whether the evolutionary game system has an ESS, we have the stakeholders start with varied initial strategies. The system has an ESS if the stakeholders’ strategy choices eventually evolve to the same steady state. Given this, we set four different groups of initial strategies:
  • Group 1. current 5: x 0 , y 0 , z 0   =   0.7 ,   0.7 ,   0 , current 6:   x 0 , y 0 , z 0   =   0.8 ,   0.8 ,   0
  • Group 2. current 7: x 0 , y 0 , z 0   =   0.7 ,   0.7 ,   0.1 , current 8:   x 0 , y 0 , z 0   =   0.8 ,   0.8 ,   0.1
The initial value z 0 = 0 in Group 1 represents the case where CSSS is not implemented. The initial value z 0 = 0.1 in Group 2 represents the case where CSSS is implemented.
The result is demonstrated in Figure 8 and Figure 9. Dmnl is the unit of variables x, y, and z, indicating that their unit is 1. According to the result, GSA do not have an ESS when CSSS is not implemented. However, after the CSSS application, the probability of GSA choosing a certain strategy eventually remains stable, which demonstrates that GSA have an ESS. Similarly, contractors do not have an ESS before CSSS is implemented. However, the strategy of contractors eventually remains stable after CSSS implementation, which demonstrates that contractors have an ESS.
More importantly, we find that after CSSS implementation, the stable value of the supervision probability x < 1 and the stable value of contractors’ strategy y = 1 . This indicates that even if GSA do not supervise every moment, contractors will always comply with CSS. In other words, CSSS implementation is beneficial for contractors to carry out safety production consciously, which will reduce the input of GSA’s safety supervision.

(3) Impact of U s on The Equilibrium State

U s indicates the social benefits of CSSST application on safety supervision. It refers to the enhancement of safety performance in infrastructure projects, the reduction in supervision costs of the whole industry, and the improvement of supervision efficiency brought by the recognition and wide use of CSSST. The increase in U s illustrates the importance of CSSS implementation and the social expectation of CSSS, which can be demonstrated by the widespread use of CSSS.
To validate the effect of increasing U s on the equilibrium state, we set different initial strategies:
  • current 9: x 0 , y 0 , z 0   =   0.5 ,   0.5 ,   0.1 , U s   =   2
  • current 10: x 0 , y 0 , z 0   =   0.5 ,   0.5 ,   0.1 , U s   =   2.2
The result is demonstrated in Figure 10 and Figure 11. Dmnl is the unit of variables x, y, and z, indicating that their unit is 1. According to the result, when U s grows, GSA’s strategy selection and contractor strategy selection probability quickly reaches a stable optimal state. It can be demonstrated that improving social benefits of CSSS implementation is an efficient measure to optimize construction safety supervision. Therefore, the government should comply with the following request.
(1)
When we develop CSSS, the content of CSSS should meet the actual needs of the market.
(2)
When we promote CSSS, the measures should be as diverse as possible.
Figure 10. Impact of Us on the equilibrium state of GSA.
Figure 10. Impact of Us on the equilibrium state of GSA.
Sustainability 13 13364 g010
Figure 11. Impact of Us on the equilibrium state of contractors.
Figure 11. Impact of Us on the equilibrium state of contractors.
Sustainability 13 13364 g011

4.2. Results of Case Studies

As we mentioned in Section 3.5, our interview questionnaire evaluated the effectiveness of CSSS in the real world. It was mainly separated into two components. One was the situation of CSS usage before CSSS application. The purpose of designing this part was to verify the necessity of the CSSS. The other was to directly verify the effectiveness of CSSS, and the interview questions for the project manager and governmental safety supervisors were slightly different. The following three subsections analyze the results of the first and second parts in detail.

4.2.1. The Situation of CSS Usage before CSSS Application

This part was to verify the necessity proposed by CSSS. Project managers of six different projects and government supervisors of four different regions believe that before CSSS application, individual CSSs had unclear expressions and contradictory requirements, and there was a lack of individual key CSSs. In addition, individual CSSs fell behind the industry and technology development. For instance, “Wire Rope Clamp” specifies that the diameter of wire rope is less than or equal to 9 mm, and rope card may not include less than 3 groups, while “Safe Use and Maintenance of Wire Rope”, “Construction Machinery Use Safety Technical Regulations”, “Construction Tower Crane Installation, Use, Dismantling Safety Technical Regulations” require the diameter of wire rope less than or equal to 18 mm, and rope card may not include less than 3 groups. This is consistent with the current status of CSS application mentioned in the introduction. Given this, CSSS can unify government supervision and contractors’ safety production standards, improve the integration and operability of CSS, and maximize the role of CSS in the process of safety supervision.

4.2.2. The Impact of CSSS Application on Contractors

This part was to identify project security management changes after CSSS application. If the efficiency and enthusiasm of safety management in contractors had improved, the effectiveness of CSSS for contractors was verified.
For the first question, after CSSS implementation, assuming that the government will no longer supervise, two project managers said that safety is crucial to the sustainability of the project and they will obey CSS as usual. However, the remaining four project managers did not give a positive answer about obeying CSS. One of them said, “Nowadays, the competition in the Chinese construction market is very fierce. Especially under the influence of COVID-19, the productivity of contractors has been affected, and contractors will pay more attention to the short-term income to obtain survival.” This shows that CSSS application will not significantly improve the status quo of contractors obeying CSS without the involvement of GSA.
GSA involved in CSSS implementation is the actual situation faced by the six selected projects. All six project managers reported improvement in the efficiency and motivation of project safety management. Specifically, CSSS integrates a large number of standards and presents them in the form of CSSST, which alleviates the issues of contradictory individual provisions. The CSSS feedback platform deepens construction workers’ understanding of CSS and allows timely communication in the platform on problems encountered at construction sites to obtain safer construction solutions, effectively reducing construction workers’ unsafe behavior, and greatly reducing the workload of project managers. In this way, managers can carry out fewer safety corrections, increase the efficiency of safety management, spend more time and energy on CSSS application improvement, and their work motivation is promoted.
It has been noted that a decrease in unsafe behavior, i.e., a decrease in the number of project safety corrections, is associated with an improvement in project safety performance [63,64,65,66,67]. After observing weekly site meetings, we found that all six projects did enhance their safety performance at a different level. Project 1 reduced the number of weekly safety corrections from 10 to 5. Project 2 reduced the number of weekly safety corrections from 10 to 8. Project 3 reduced the number of weekly safety corrections from 12 to 9. Project 4 reduced the number of weekly safety corrections from 8 to 5. Project 5 reduced the number of weekly safety corrections from 10 to 7. Project 6 reduced the number of weekly safety corrections from 10 to 5 after three months of CSSS implementation.
In summary, CSSS application has improved the efficiency and enthusiasm of safety management in contractors under government-imposed safety supervision.

4.2.3. The Impact of CSSS Application on GSA

This part was to identify changes in government safety supervision after CSSS application. If the efficiency and enthusiasm of governmental safety supervision had improved, the effectiveness of CSSS for GSA was verified.
After CSSS application, four governmental supervisors from different regions of China reported a reduction in the number of safety corrections. However, the reduction in supervision costs was not significant because CSSS was piloted in the region, and it was only applied to major projects, due to the different completeness of information systems and other infrastructure of each contractor.
Nevertheless, four governmental supervisors all expressed their optimism about the future of CSSS. They suggested that the content of CSSS should meet the actual needs of the market, and the standard management should widely adopt suggestions from regulators and contractors to achieve a better CSSS application. In addition, when promoting CSSS, the measures should be diverse, which is still a difficult task.

5. Discussion

In line with previous studies, Figure 6 and Figure 7 illustrate that the stakeholders’ strategy choices show period fluctuations [68]. This is reflected in the fact that when GSA conduct positive supervision, contractors will choose to obey CSS because of heavy penalties. Therefore, the construction safety atmosphere improves and GSA’s supervision strategy gradually slackens. However, when contractors perceive that GSA tend to conduct negative supervision, they will gradually evade the responsibility of safety control. Thus, the probability of accidents increases and GSA strengthen supervision. Given this, there is a time lag in maintaining construction safety through supervision because the government cannot adjust its supervision strategy in time to respond to changes in contractor decisions. Contractors are usually forced to obey CSS due to external supervision pressure, which reduces the enthusiasm for safety production.
Different from previous studies [69], this paper has two new findings as follows.
(1)
Through CSSS implementation, the strategy choice fluctuation of GSA and contractors is suppressed and a more desirable stable equilibrium is reached. GSA tend to supervise and contractors tend to obey CSS. More importantly, we find that after CSSS implementation, the probability of supervision (x) has a stable value of less than 1, while the probability of obeying CSS (y) eventually remains stable at 1. This indicates that even if GSA do not supervise every moment, contractors will comply with CSS. Therefore, CSSS implementation is beneficial for contractors to obey CSS consciously, which will reduce the cost of GSA’s safety supervision.
(2)
Solely improving the social benefit of CSSS implementation is an efficient measure to optimize construction safety supervision. Therefore, the government should meet the request: (1) When we develop CSSS, the content of CSSS should meet the actual needs of the market. (2) When we promote CSSS, the ways should be as diverse as possible.
According to the research results, we put forward the following recommendations.
(1)
SMA should appropriately decentralize their management responsibilities and allow GSA to participate in CSS creation, revision, and planning. In addition, in the process of CSSS formulation, SMA should adopt professional opinions of GSA and contractors on issues such as CSS classification and catalog determination, so that CSSS can better meet market requirements.
(2)
GSA should strengthen its cooperation and communication with SMA to help establish CSSS, reach an agreement with contractors on CSSS application, reduce unnecessary coordination in supervision, save supervision costs, and improve the social benefits of CSSS. Meanwhile, it is helpful to improve GSA’s supervision accuracy.
(3)
Contractors should actively participate in the development and improvement of CSSS. They should also update CSS in conjunction with new processes and materials that have been applied maturely on-site to occupy a leading position in the industry. In addition, they should actively put them into production following the requirements of the local GSA.

6. Conclusions

CSS and safety supervision are of vital importance to labor safety and the sustainable development of the construction industry. Few studies have combined CSS and safety supervision. In this study, CSSS was constructed and provided for supervision parties to establish the link between CSS and safety supervision. In terms of research methodology, this paper described and analyzed the impact of CSSS implementation on the strategic choices of safety supervision parties by using EG theory and SD simulation. The findings are as follows.
(1)
CSSS integrates standards effectively, so CSSS implementation accommodates SMA, GSA, and contractors into an evolutionary system that facilitates overall system analysis.
(2)
CSSS formulation and implementation can suppress the fluctuation of GSA and contractors’ strategy choices. The probability of GSA’s supervision and contractors’ safety production can reach an ideal stable state, which verifies the effectiveness of CSSS in safety supervision.
(3)
After CSSS implementation, GSA’s supervision efficiency increases. In addition, CSSS application has improved the efficiency and enthusiasm of safety management in contractors under government-imposed safety supervision.
(4)
Improving the social benefits of CSSS application ( U s ) will enable GSA and contractors’ strategy selections to quickly reach a steady state. Given this, improving the social benefits of CSSS application is an efficient measure to optimize the effectiveness of construction safety supervision.
This paper has theoretical and practical implications. From the theoretical aspects, (1) the positive effect of CSSS on construction safety supervision was verified theoretically. (2) Evolutionary game theory and SD simulation were combined to quantitatively analyze the safety supervision behavior under the participation of SMA, which also provided an effective method to study system behavior. From the practical aspects, (1) the CSSS proposed in this paper unified standards, improved the operability of CSS, and maximized the role of standards in safety supervision. (2) We established and implemented CSSS in the construction industry in China, and other countries could establish their own CSSS based on the principles and methods proposed in this paper. In addition, CSSS can also be extended to other industries to help sustainable development.
However, there are some limitations to this paper. SMA, GSA, and contractors were regarded as stakeholders. The influence of other stakeholders such as owners was not considered. In addition, because CSSS is an innovative method that has not been widely adopted, we could not explain the deeper impact of CSSS on government regulatory agencies and contractors. This is desirable for future work.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, Y.J., W.S. and X.G.; methodology, Y.J. and X.G.; software, Y.J.; formal analysis, W.S. and Y.J.; resources, X.G.; writing—original draft preparation, Y.J.; writing—review and editing, Y.J. and J.L.; supervision, X.G. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by the National Natural Science Foundation of China, grant number 72174146.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Data sharing not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Interview Questions for Project Manager
1. The situation of CSS usage before the CSSS application.
  (1) Before the application of CSSS, were there any unclear expressions in the provisions of individual construction safety standards?
□Yes □No
(If yes, please give examples)
  (2) Before the application of CSSS, were there contradictory provisions of individual construction safety standards and codes?
□Yes □No
(If yes, please give examples)
  (3) Before the application of CSSS, was there a lack of individual key standards?
□Yes □No
(If yes, please provide examples)
  (4) Before the application of CSSS, were individual standards falling behind the industry and technology development?
□Yes □No
(If yes, please give examples)
2. Project security management changes after CSSS application.
  (1) If the government no longer carries out strong supervision, will the project still be produced according to the standards?
  (2) Has the efficiency of project safety management been improved after the application of CSSS and with the government’s preference for safety supervision? What are the specific aspects?
  (3) After CSSS application, and with the government’s preference for safety supervision, is the motivation of project safety management improved? What are the specific aspects?

Appendix B

Interview Questions for Government Supervision Authorities
1. The situation of CSS usage before CSSS application.
  (1) Before the application of CSSS, were there unclear expressions in the provisions of individual construction safety standards?
□Yes □No
(If yes, please give examples)
  (2) Before the application of CSSS, were there contradictory provisions of individual construction safety standards and codes?
□Yes □No
(If yes, please give examples)
  (3) Before the application of CSSS, was there a lack of individual key standards?
□Yes □No
(If yes, please provide examples)
  (4) Before the application of CSSS, were individual standards falling behind the industry and technology development?
□ Yes □ No
(If yes, please give examples)
2. Changes in government safety supervision after CSSS application.
  (1) After the application of CSSS, has the efficiency of government safety supervision been improved? What are the specific aspects?
  (2) Has the enthusiasm for government safety supervision been improved after the application of CSSS? What are the specific aspects?

Appendix C

In Section 4.1, the details to obtain the replicated dynamic equations are as follows:
(1)
Replicated dynamic equation of GSA
It is supposed that the profit when the government supervises is U x , and the payoff when supervision is not conducted is U 1 x , and the average expected fitness is denoted by U x ¯ . The representative equations are as follows:
U x   = ( S g C g ) yz + ( S g + MP 1 C g B g ) ( 1 y ) z + ( C g ) ( 1 z ) y + ( MP C g B g ) ( 1 y ) ( 1 z )
U 1 x   = ( B g FN ) ( 1 y ) z + ( B g FN ) ( 1 y ) ( 1 z )
U x ¯   = xU x + ( 1 x ) U 1 x
According to EG theory, the replicated dynamic equation of the supervision sector is as follows:
F x = dx dt = x U x U x ¯ = x 1 x U x U 1 x = x ( 1 x ) [ ( MP MP 1 ) yz + ( MP 1 MP + S g ) z ( MP + FN ) y + ( MP + FN C g ) ]
(2)
Replicated dynamic equation of contractors
Similarly, the expected payoffs when contractors choose to obey CSS and not obey CSS are symbolized as U y and U 1 y respectively, and the average expected fitness is denoted by U y ¯ . The representative equations are as follows:
U y =   ( π C e + S e ) xz + ( π C e ) ( 1 z ) x + ( π C e + S e ) ( 1 x ) z + ( π C e ) ( 1 x ) ( 1 z )
U 1 y =   ( π FL MP 1 ) xz + ( π FL MP ) ( 1 z ) x + ( π FL ) ( 1 x ) z + ( π FL ) ( 1 x ) ( 1 z )
U y ¯ =   yU y + ( 1 y ) U 1 y
Further, the dynamic replication equation of contractors is shown as follows:
F ( y ) =   dy dt   =   y ( 1 y ) [ ( MP 1 MP ) xz + S e z + MPx + ( FL C e ) ]
(3)
Replicated dynamic equation of SMA
The expected payoffs when SMA select to establish CSSST and not to establish CSSST are symbolized as U z and U 1 z , and the total fitness is denoted by U z ¯ . The representative equations are as follows:
U z   =   ( U s C s ) xy + ( C s ) ( 1 y ) x + ( U s C s ) ( 1 x ) y + ( C s ) 1 x 1 y
U 1 z = 0
U z ¯   =   zU z + 1 z U 1 z
The dynamic replicated equation of SMA is calculated as follows:
F ( z )   =   dz dt   =   z ( 1 z ) ( U s y C s )

Appendix D

The model equations of Figure 5.
Main equations of GSA’s strategy:
(1)
“GSA’s payoffs of supervision ( U x )” = “The ratio of safety production (y)” * “The ratio of making CSSST (z)” * (“Contractors’ penalty as a result of not obeying CSS (M)” * “Supervision accuracy without CSSST application (P)” − “Contractors’ penalty as a result of not obeying CSS (M)” * “Supervision accuracy with CSSST application (P1)”) + (“Expected loss of social benefit as a result of not obeying CSS ( B g )” − “Contractors’ penalty as a result of not obeying CSS (M)” * “Supervision accuracy without CSSST application (P)”) * “The ratio of safety production (y)” + (“Supervision costs saved due to GSA’s CSSST application ( S g )” + “Contractors’ penalty as a result of not obeying CSS (M)” * “Supervision accuracy with CSSST application ( P 1 )” − “Contractors’ penalty as a result of not obeying CSS (M)” * “Supervision accuracy without CSSST application (P)”) * “The ratio of making CSSST (z)” + “Contractors’ penalty as a result of not obeying CSS (M)” * “Supervision accuracy without CSSST application (P)” − “Expected loss of social benefit as a result of not obeying CSS ( B g )”
(2)
“GSA’s payoffs of non-supervision ( U 1 x )” = (“Expected loss of social benefit as a result of not obeying CSS ( B g )” + “The probability of construction safety accidents (F)” * “GSA’s penalty when accidents occur (N)”) * “The ratio of safety production (y)” + “Costs of safety supervision ( C g )” − “The probability of construction safety accidents (F)” * “GSA’s penalty when accidents occur (N)”
(3)
“Change rate of supervision (F(x))” = “The ratio of supervision (x)” * (1 − “The ratio of supervision (x)”) * (“GSA’s payoffs of supervision U x ” − “GSA’s payoffs of non-supervision U 1 x ”)
Main equations of contractors’ strategy:
(1)
“Contractors’ payoffs of obeying CSS ( U y )” = “Investments saved due to contractors’ CSSS application ( S e )” * “The ratio of making CSSST (z)” + “Contractors’ normal revenue from regular production (π)” − “Contractors’ safety investments ( C e )”
(2)
“Contractors’ payoffs of not obeying CSS ( U 1 y )” = (“Contractors’ penalty as a result of not obeying CSS (M)” * “Supervision accuracy without CSSST application (P)” − “Contractors’ penalty as a result of not obeying CSS (M)” * “Supervision accuracy with CSSST application ( P 1 )”) * “The ratio of making CSSST (z)” * “The ratio of supervision-Contractors’ penalty as a result of not obeying CSS (M)” * “Supervision accuracy without CSSST application (P)” * “The ratio of supervision (x)” + “Contractors’ normal revenue from regular production (π)” − “The probability of construction safety accidents (F)” * “Contractors’ expected loss in case of an accident (L)”
(3)
“Change rate of obeying CSS (F(y))” = “The ratio of safety production (y)” * (1 − “The ratio of safety production (y)”) * (“Contractors’ payoffs of obeying CSS ( U y )” − “Contractors’ payoffs of not obeying CSS ( U 1 y )”)
Main equations of SMA’s strategy:
(1)
“SMA’s payoffs of making CSSST ( U z )” = “−The social benefit as a result of making CSSST ( U s ) ” * “The ratio of supervision (x)” * “The ratio of safety production (y)” + “The social benefit as a result of making CSSST ( U s )” * “The ratio of supervision (x)” + “The social benefit as a result of making CSSST ( U s )” * “The ratio of safety production (y)” − “The cost CSSST construction ( C s )”
(2)
“SMA’s payoffs of not making CSSST ( U 1 z )” = 0
(3)
“Change rate of making CSSST (F(z))” = “The ratio of making CSSST (z)” * (1 − “The ratio of making CSSST (z)”) * (“SMA’s payoffs of making CSSST ( U z )” − “SMA’s payoffs of not making CSSST ( U 1 z )”)
Note: “*” stands for multiplying

References

  1. Hallowell, M.R.; Gambatese, J.A. Construction Safety Risk Mitigation. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2009, 135, 1316–1323. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Dong, X.W.; Ringen, K.; Men, Y.R.; Fujimoto, A. Medical costs and sources of payment for work-related injuries among Hispanic construction workers. J. Occup. Environ. Med. 2007, 49, 1367–1375. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  3. Sunindijo, R.Y.; Zou, P. CHPT construct: Essential skills for construction project managers. Int. J. Proj. Organ. Manag. 2011, 3, 139–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Sunindijo, R.Y.; Zou, P.X.W. Political Skill for Developing Construction Safety Climate. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2012, 138, 605–612. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Center, C.D.; Dong, X.S.; Wang, X.; Largay, J. The Construction Chart Book: The US Construction Industry and Its Workers; The Center for Construction Research and Training: Silver Spring, GA, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  6. Guo, S.Y.; Zhou, X.Y.; Tang, B.; Gong, P.S. Exploring the behavioral risk chains of accidents using complex network theory in the construction industry. Physica A 2020, 560, 12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. National Coal Mine Safety Administration. The Statistical Data of Accidents and Injuries in Coal Mine. 2021. Available online: http://www.chinacoal-safety.gov.cn (accessed on 21 August 2021).
  8. National Bureau of Statistics. Statistical Bulletin of National Economic and Social Development of the People’s Republic of China. 2021. Available online: http://www.stats.gov.cn/tjsj/zxfb/202102/t20210227_1814154.html (accessed on 16 August 2021).
  9. Chen, Q.; Jin, R.Y. Safety4Site Commitment to Enhance Jobsite Safety Management and Performance. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2012, 138, 509–519. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Khalafallah, A.; Kartam, N.; Razeq, R.A. Bilevel Standards-Compliant Platform for Evaluating Building Contractor Safety. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2019, 145, 04019054. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Zheng, X.Z.; Tong, L.Y.; Chen, G.L. Spatial-temporal evolution characteristics and influencing factors of work safety level in construction industry. China Saf. Sci. J. 2020, 30, 27–34. [Google Scholar]
  12. Wang, W.; Zhang, S.J.; King, A.P. Research on the adoption barriers of the engineering construction standards in China. Struct. Surv. 2016, 34, 367–378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Abrahamsen, E.B.; Asche, F. The insurance market’s influence on investments in safety measures. Saf. Sci. 2010, 48, 1279–1285. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Ma, Y.; Zhao, Q.; Xi, M. Decision-makings in safety investment: An opportunity cost perspective. Saf. Sci. 2016, 83, 31–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Liu, Q.L.; Li, X.C.; Hassall, M. Evolutionary game analysis and stability control scenarios of coal mine safety inspection system in China based on system dynamics. Saf. Sci. 2015, 80, 13–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Qla, B.; Xl, A.; Xm, A. Effectiveness research on the multi-player evolutionary game of coal-mine safety regulation in China based on system dynamics-ScienceDirect. Saf. Sci. 2019, 111, 224–233. [Google Scholar]
  17. Zhu, K.; Li, S. Study on the Long Effective Mechanism of Construction Safety Supervision Management. In Proceedings of the IEEE Computer Society, Anchorage, AK, USA, 23–28 June 2008. [Google Scholar]
  18. Ma, Y.H.; Zhao, Q.H. Decision-making in safety efforts: Role of the government in reducing the probability of workplace accidents in China. Saf. Sci. 2018, 104, 81–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Wang, Q.L.; Peng, X.Y.; Li, Z.J. Determining Strategies for Constructing the Safety Supervision System by Considering Both Internal and External Safety Environments: A Case Study of X Group Corporation, China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2020, 17, 9486. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Choi, B.; Ahn, S.; Lee, S.H. Construction Workers’ Group Norms and Personal Standards Regarding Safety Behavior: Social Identity Theory Perspective. J. Manag. Eng. 2017, 33, 04017001. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Dahl, O. Safety compliance in a highly regulated environment: A case study of workers’ knowledge of rules and procedures within the petroleum industry. Saf. Sci. 2013, 60, 185–195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Hinze, J.; Hallowell, M.; Baud, K. Construction-Safety Best Practices and Relationships to Safety Performance. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2013, 139, 04013006. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Hale, A.; Borys, D. Working to rule, or working safely? Part 1: A state of the art review. Saf. Sci. 2013, 55, 207–221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Gao, J. Analysis on the current situation of engineering construction safety standard system in China. Low Temp. Build. Technol. 2013, 35, 145–146. [Google Scholar]
  25. Liao, L.; Cheng, H.; Liu, Y. United States Standardization System and Its References Giving for China. Chin. J. Manag. 2013, 10, 1805–1809. [Google Scholar]
  26. Kadiri, Z.O.; Nden, T.; Avre, G.K.; Oladipo, T.O.; Ananso, G.N. Causes and Effects of Accidents on Construction Sites (A Case Study of Some Selected Construction Firms in Abuja F.C.T Nigeria). IOSR J. Mech. Civ. Eng. 2014, 11, 66–72. [Google Scholar]
  27. Zhang, S.L.; Wang, Y.X. Research on the impact of construction safety regulation on industrial production efficiency. Chin. J. Saf. Sci. 2017, 27, 139–144. [Google Scholar]
  28. Wang, J.L. Empirical Study on the impact of safety culture on safety performance in construction enterprises. China Saf. Prod. Sci. Technol. 2014, 10, 125–129. [Google Scholar]
  29. Kang, Y.L.; You, R.C.; Tang, W.Z.; Wang, Y.H.; Liu, Y. Study on Differences of Construction Standard Systems between China and Foreign Countries and Development Strategies on Chinese Standard System. Constr. Econ. 2020, 41, 10–13. [Google Scholar]
  30. Sun, Z.; Zhang, S.J. Research on the complexity of construction standard system. China Civil. Eng. J. 2012, 45, 277–283. [Google Scholar]
  31. Choi, J.; Gu, B.; Chin, S.; Lee, J.S. Machine learning predictive model based on national data for fatal accidents of construction workers. Autom. Constr. 2020, 110, 102974. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Okonkwo, P.N.; Wium, J. Health and Safety Management Systems within Construction Contractor Organizations: Case Study of South Africa. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2020, 146, 05020003. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Pi, Z.J.; Gao, X.; Chen, L.Y.; Liu, J.H. The New Path to Improve Construction Safety Performance in China: An Evolutionary Game Theoretic Approach. Int. J. Env. Res. Public Health 2019, 16, 2443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  34. Smith, J.M.; Price, G.R. The Logic of Animal Conflict. Nature 1973, 246, 15–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Taylor, P.D.; Jonker, L.B. Evolutionarily Stable Strategies and Game Dynamics. Math. Biosci. 1978, 40, 145–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Binmore, K. Modeling Rational Players: Part I. Econ. Philos. 1987, 3, 179–214. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Friedman, D. Evolutionary Game in Economics. Econometrica 1991, 59, 637–666. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  38. Nash, J. Non-cooperative games. Ann. Math. 1951, 54, 286–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Smith, J.M. The theory of games and the evolution of animal conflicts. J. Theor. Biol. 1974, 47, 209–221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  40. Min, C.; Hui, C. Research on Construction Safety Supervision Based on Evolu-tionary Game Theory. Oper. Res. Manag. Sci. 2011, 20, 210–215. [Google Scholar]
  41. Hausken, K.; Zhuang, J. The impact of disaster on the strategic interaction between company and government. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2013, 225, 363–376. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Hausken, K.; Zhuang, J. The strategic interaction between a company and the government surrounding disasters. Ann. Oper. Res. 2016, 237, 27–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Chen, Y.; Zhu, D.; Zhou, L. A game theory analysis of promoting the spongy city construction at the building and community scale. Habitat Int. 2019, 86, 91–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Zhou, J.; Tong, R.; Chen, D. Assessment of Safety Policies in China’s Construction Industry and Its Improvement. China Saf. Sci. J. 2010, 20, 146–151. [Google Scholar]
  45. Liu, X.X.; Huang, G.X.; Huang, H.Q.; Wang, S.Y.; Xiao, Y.; Chen, W.Q. Safety climate, safety behavior, and worker injuries in the Chinese manufacturing industry. Saf. Sci. 2015, 78, 173–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Cao, D.; Wang, G. Game Analysis and Policy Suggestion on Safety Supervising in China’s Construction Industry. Constr. Econ. 2007, 11, 52. [Google Scholar]
  47. Liu, D.; Xiao, X.; Li, H.; Wang, W. Historical evolution and benefit–cost explanation of periodical fluctuation in coal mine safety supervision: An evolutionary game analysis framework. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2015, 243, 974–984. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Shan, H.; Yang, J.; Wei, G. Industrial Symbiosis Systems: Promoting Carbon Emission Reduction Activities. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2019, 16, 1093. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  49. Yu, K.; Zhou, L.; Cao, Q.; Li, Z. Evolutionary Game Research on Symmetry of Workers’ Behavior in Coal Mine Enterprises. Symmetry 2019, 11, 156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  50. Feng, F.L.; Liu, C.G.; Zhang, J.Q. China’s Railway Transportation Safety Regulation System Based on Evolutionary Game Theory and System Dynamics. Risk Anal. 2020, 40, 1944–1966. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Zhu, G.; Liu, H.; Feng, M. An Evolutionary Game-Theoretic Approach for Assessing Privacy Protection in mHealth Systems. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2018, 15, 2196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  52. Kim, D.H.; Kim, D.H. A system dynamics model for a mixed-strategy game between police and driver. Syst. Dyn. Rev. 1997, 13, 33–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. You, M.; Li, S.; Li, D.; Cao, Q.; Xu, F. Evolutionary game analysis of coal-mine enterprise internal safety inspection system in China based on system dynamics. Resour. Policy 2020, 67, 101673. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Zhong, Y. System Dynamics; Science Press: Beijing, China, 2009; pp. 14–19, 25–33. [Google Scholar]
  55. Guo, B.; Goh, Y.M.; Wong, K.X. A system dynamics view of a behavior-based safety program in the construction industry. Saf. Sci. 2018, 104, 202–215. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Geoffrey, J.R. Creative Thinking and Brainstorming; Routledge: London, UK, 1981. [Google Scholar]
  57. Chan, A.; Kwok, W.Y.; Duffy, V.G. Using AHP for determining priority in a safety management system. Ind. Manag. Data Syst. 2004, 104, 430–445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Department of Fixed Assets Investment statistics, National Bureau of Statistics. China Statistical Yearbook on Construction; China Statistics Press: Beijing, China, 2020.
  59. State Council of the People’s Republic of China. The Administrative Regulations on the Work Safety of Construction Projects. Available online: http://www.mohurd.gov.cn/fgjs/xzfg/200611/t20061101_158967.html (accessed on 12 December 2020).
  60. Eisenhardt, K.M. Building Theories from Case Study Research. Acad. Manag. Rev. 1989, 14, 532–550. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Yin, R.K. Case Study Research: Design and Methods; John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2010; p. 108. [Google Scholar]
  62. Taylor, J.E.; Dossick, C.S.; Garvin, M.J. Constructing Research with Case Studies. In Proceedings of the Construction Research Congress, Seattle, WA, USA, 5–7 April 2009. [Google Scholar]
  63. Alruqi, W.M.; Hallowell, M.R. Critical Success Factors for Construction Safety: Review and Meta-Analysis of Safety Leading Indicators. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2019, 145, 04019005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Pereira, E.; Hermann, U.; Han, S.; AbouRizk, S. Case-Based Reasoning Approach for Assessing Safety Performance Using Safety-Related Measures. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2018, 144, 04018088. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Awolusi, I.G.; Marks, E.D. Safety Activity Analysis Framework to Evaluate Safety Performance in Construction. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2017, 143, 05016022. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  66. Gunduz, M.; Birgonul, M.T.; Ozdemir, M. Fuzzy Structural Equation Model to Assess Construction Site Safety Performance. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2017, 143, 04016112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Hallowell, M.R.; Hinze, J.W.; Baud, K.C.; Wehle, A. Proactive Construction Safety Control: Measuring, Monitoring, and Responding to Safety Leading Indicators. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2013, 139, 04013010. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Li, K.; Zhang, Y.; Guo, J.; Ge, X.; Su, Y. System dynamics model for high-speed railway operation safety supervision system based on evolutionary game theory. Concurr. Comput. Pract. Exp. 2019, 31, e4743. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Zhang, R.P.; Lingard, H.; Oswald, D. Impact of Supervisory Safety Communication on Safety Climate and Behavior in Construction Workgroups. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2020, 146, 04020089. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Overall research framework.
Figure 1. Overall research framework.
Sustainability 13 13364 g001
Figure 2. Structure of CSSS.
Figure 2. Structure of CSSS.
Sustainability 13 13364 g002
Figure 3. The implementation flow of CSSS Feedback Platform.
Figure 3. The implementation flow of CSSS Feedback Platform.
Sustainability 13 13364 g003
Figure 4. The relationship between stakeholders.
Figure 4. The relationship between stakeholders.
Sustainability 13 13364 g004
Figure 5. SD flow chart.
Figure 5. SD flow chart.
Sustainability 13 13364 g005
Figure 6. CSSS implementation impact on GSA.
Figure 6. CSSS implementation impact on GSA.
Sustainability 13 13364 g006
Figure 7. CSSS implementation impact on contractors.
Figure 7. CSSS implementation impact on contractors.
Sustainability 13 13364 g007
Figure 8. CSSS implementation impact on GSA’s ESS.
Figure 8. CSSS implementation impact on GSA’s ESS.
Sustainability 13 13364 g008
Figure 9. CSSS implementation impact on contractors’ ESS.
Figure 9. CSSS implementation impact on contractors’ ESS.
Sustainability 13 13364 g009
Table 1. Meanings of the variables in the multiplayer evolutionary game.
Table 1. Meanings of the variables in the multiplayer evolutionary game.
VariablesMeaning of the VariablesNotes
xProbability of governmental supervision 0 x 1
yProbability of contractors obeying CSS 0 y 1
zProbability of SMA making CSSST 0 z 1
U s Social benefits of CSSST application U s > 0
C s Costs of CSSST construction C s > 0
B g The expected loss of social benefits as a result of not obeying CSS B g > 0
C g Costs of safety supervision C g > 0
F Probability of construction safety accidents F > 0
N GSA’s penalties when accidents occur N > 0
S g Supervision costs saved due to GSA’s CSSST application S g > 0
M Contractors’ penalties as a result of not obeying CSS M > 0
P 1 Supervision accuracy with CSSST application 0 < P 1 < 1
P Supervision accuracy without CSSST application 0 < P < 1
π Contractors’ normal revenue from regular production π > 0
C e Contractors’ safety investments C e > 0
LContractors’ expected loss in case of an accidentL > 0
S e Investments saved due to contractors’ CSSS application S e > 0
Table 2. Payoff matrix between GSA, contractors, and SMA.
Table 2. Payoff matrix between GSA, contractors, and SMA.
GovernmentContractor
Obey CSS (y)Not Obey CSS (1 − y)
GSA supervises and SMA makes CSSS, (x, z) S g C g
π C e + S e
U s C s
S g + MP 1 C g B g
π FL MP 1
C s
GSA supervises and SMA does not make CSSS, (x, 1 − z) C g
π C e
0
MP C g B g
π FL MP
0
GSA does not supervise and SMA makes CSSS, (1 − x, z) 0
π C e + S e
U s C s
B g FN
π FL
C s
GSA does not supervise and SMA does not make CSSS, (1 − x, 1 − z)0
π C e
0
B g FN
π FL
0
Table 3. Original Estimates of Variables in the SD model.
Table 3. Original Estimates of Variables in the SD model.
Variables U s C s B g C g FN S g M P 1 P π C e L S e
Initial values2110.60.20.70.210.980.952010502
Table 4. Case Study Information.
Table 4. Case Study Information.
No.LocationProject TypeScope (RMB)ContractorsAverage Annual Operating Revenue of Contractors from 2017–2020 (RMB)
1ShanghaiCivil building505 millionShanghai Construction Group23.13 billion
2ShanghaiHospital898 millionChina Construction eighth engineering division corp., LTD26.63 billion
3ShandongSchool1.715 billionChina Construction eighth engineering division corp., LTD26.63 billion
4BeijingSubway2.785 billionChina Construction eighth engineering division corp., LTD26.63 billion
5HubeiAirport1.094 billionChina Construction third engineering division corp., LTD27 billion
6BeijingSubway977 millionChina Construction seventh engineering division corp., LTD20.63 billion
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Su, W.; Gao, X.; Jiang, Y.; Li, J. Developing a Construction Safety Standard System to Enhance Safety Supervision Efficiency in China: A Theoretical Simulation of the Evolutionary Game Process. Sustainability 2021, 13, 13364. https://doi.org/10.3390/su132313364

AMA Style

Su W, Gao X, Jiang Y, Li J. Developing a Construction Safety Standard System to Enhance Safety Supervision Efficiency in China: A Theoretical Simulation of the Evolutionary Game Process. Sustainability. 2021; 13(23):13364. https://doi.org/10.3390/su132313364

Chicago/Turabian Style

Su, Wenxin, Xin Gao, Yukun Jiang, and Jinrong Li. 2021. "Developing a Construction Safety Standard System to Enhance Safety Supervision Efficiency in China: A Theoretical Simulation of the Evolutionary Game Process" Sustainability 13, no. 23: 13364. https://doi.org/10.3390/su132313364

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop