Next Article in Journal
Between a Rock and a Hard Place: Governing Unconventional Natural Gas at the Local Level in the United States
Next Article in Special Issue
A Genetic Algorithm for Integrated Scheduling of Container Handing Systems at Container Terminals from a Low-Carbon Operations Perspective
Previous Article in Journal
Effect of Ultra-Fine Cement on the Strength and Microstructure of Humic Acid Containing Cemented Soil
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Market-Incentive Environmental Regulation and the Quality of Corporate Innovation

1
Research Institute of Economics and Management, Southwestern University of Finance and Economics, Chengdu 610074, China
2
School of Business, Macau University of Science and Technology, Macau 00853, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2023, 15(7), 5924; https://doi.org/10.3390/su15075924
Submission received: 9 February 2023 / Revised: 17 March 2023 / Accepted: 20 March 2023 / Published: 29 March 2023

Abstract

:
Environmental issues have received worldwide attention in recent years, and a large body of literature has focused on environmental regulations and business innovation. However, very few studies examine the effects of market-incentive-based environmental regulation policies on the quality of corporate innovation. Thus, this paper uses China’s A-share listed enterprises in 2010–2020 and China’s carbon trading policy (CCTP) to conduct a quasi-natural experiment. The results show that the CCTP significantly increases the quality of innovation but does not affect the quantity of firm innovation. Furthermore, according to the result of heterogeneity analysis, the effect of CCTP on high-quality innovation occurs mainly in low-financialization and non-state enterprises.

1. Introduction

In recent years, massive emissions of greenhouse gases have had a serious effect on the ecosystem. The Global State of the Climate report by the World Meteorological Organization (WMO) confirms that 2015–2019 were the hottest five years in history. As the world’s industries continue to grow, industrial enterprises develop and operate, consuming fossil energy, which causes a continued rise in atmospheric CO2 [1]. In the face of rising global temperatures and environmental degradation, energy saving and emission reduction have also become a responsibility that all countries and regions in the world must undertake [2,3].
With the start of the third technological revolution and the growing prominence of environmental issues, the relationship between environmental policy and innovation has also attracted the attention of scholars around the world [4]. Some scholars have divided environmental regulation into order-controlled and market-incentive types [5,6]. Carbon trading policies (CTPs) are regarded as an effective market-incentive environmental regulation (MER) to combat climate change and control greenhouse gas emissions [7,8]. At the same time, there is an increasing trend toward differentiated innovation quality in recent years [9]. High-quality innovation can contribute to technological progress and environmental protection. However, low-quality innovation is often considered ineffective and a waste of resources [10]. In response to this phenomenon, it is important to analyze the drivers of different quality innovations. To this end, we attempt to respond to the following question: can MERs improve the quality of corporate innovation?
As a major carbon emitter and the world’s largest developing country, China has taken the initiative to take responsibility and actively participate in energy-saving and emission-reduction initiatives [11,12]. At the Paris Conference in 2015, China pledged to reduce its carbon emission intensity by 60–65% by 2030 [12,13]. In the 11th Five-Year Plan, the Chinese government established the goal of energy saving and emission reduction by increasing efforts to reduce emissions and promoting energy-saving policies. Since 2013, China has launched eight pilot carbon-trading markets including Beijing, Shanghai, Shenzhen, Guangdong, Tianjin, Chongqing, Hubei, and Fujian [14,15]. With the EU’s restrictions on certified emission reductions (CERs) in the international market for emerging countries such as China and the improvement of the domestic carbon trading market, Chinese companies are slowly turning to the domestic carbon trading market. By 22 December 2022, the cumulative turnover of the national carbon market exceeded RMB10 billion.
Porter (1991) pointed out that appropriate environmental regulations stimulate firms to innovate technologically, and that technological innovation leads to productivity gains that offset environmental protection costs, ultimately increasing the enterprises’ competitiveness; this is the so-called “Porter Effect” [16]. However, the subsequent literature on the “Porter Effect” has not reached a uniform conclusion. Some research has respectively examined that the “Porter Effect” does exist under environmental regulation [17,18]. Lanoie et al. revealed that the Lagging effect of environmental regulation on productivity is positive [17]. Berman et al. found that US air pollution regulations can improve the productivity of refineries [18]. However, according to Dean and Brown, environmental regulations have a negative effect on technological innovation because it increases the cost of environmental management and crowds out corporate investment in R&D [19].
In response to the two contradictory views, some scholars have classified environmental regulation based on their functioning mechanisms into order-controlled and market-incentive types [5,6]. Order-controlled environmental regulation (OER) uses administrative orders to intervene directly with highly polluting enterprises to force them to meet energy efficiency and emission reduction standards [20]. It has strong administrative aspects and is classified as direct control. For example, OERs could consist of setting strict emission and technical standards and forcibly closing down highly polluting and outdated production enterprises. MERs are based on Coase’s theorem, which establishes a market for emission rights by defining property rights over environmental resources [21]. Significant spatial differences exist in the policy effects of different environmental policy instruments [22]. An increasing number of studies suggest MERs have more long-term incentives than order-controlled regulations [5,23]. According to Dong and Feng [23], a flexible MER may trigger positive productivity effects in the new energy sector. Milliman and Prince point out that the impact on technological innovation is stronger under an MER than under an OER [24].
At the same time, some scholars distinguish among corporate innovation types. Some researchers have addressed the relationship between environmental regulation and low-carbon innovation. Laing et al. found that the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EUETS) has a limited effect on low-carbon innovation [25]. Eikeland and Skjærseth pointed out that the power sector has been more proactive than the oil sector with regard to low carbon innovation in EUETS [26]. Additionally, Qi et al. found that China’s carbon trading policy (CCTP) can promote corporate low-carbon innovation [27]. Some scholars have revealed the effect of environmental regulation on green innovation. For example, Zhang et al. revealed the positive impact of CCTP on the green innovation of listed companies [28]. Additionally, some of the literature wanted to find the innovation performance of environmental regulation. Jiang et al. discovered that regional environmental regulation in China promoted innovation performance [29]. Furthermore, according to Mo, the Korean Emission Trading Scheme (KETS) has a positive effect on innovation and thus reduce carbon emissions [30]. These studies have analyzed the impact of market-incentive environmental regulation policies on innovation from different perspectives. However, few studies have analyzed the heterogeneous effects of CCTP on the quality of corporate innovation.
Certainly, the above research has inspired us to analyze the heterogeneous impact of CCTP on corporate innovation with different qualities. At the same time, this analysis is necessary. The variations in the quality of innovation affect the technological variations of companies and reflect the variations in the level of environmental protection. According to Thoma, low-quality innovations are usually invalid patents filed for strategic competition and contribute little to overall corporate innovation capability [31]. These low-quality innovation patents are a waste of resources and can even lead companies to lose their market competitiveness [10]. According to Dang and Motohashi, China’s innovation subsidy policies promote more low-quality innovation and have less impact on high-quality innovation [32].
Previous studies focused more on the impact of environmental regulation on low-carbon innovation, green innovation, or on a single indicator of technological innovation [27,28,29]. At the same time, CCTP may affect innovation that is not green innovation, but this impact may be different from green innovation [33]. On the one hand, the implementation of the CCTP may increase the demand for low-carbon technologies, which in turn will boost the development of relevant technologies. On the other hand, the implementation of the CCTP may put companies under greater economic pressure to seek new production methods, products, or services to reduce carbon emissions and improve efficiency. How then can companies improve the quality of their patents while ensuring quantity? Can CCTP, which involves market-based incentives for environmental regulation, reduce low-quality innovation and increase high-quality innovation, thereby reducing resource waste? The existing literature does not provide a precise answer to this question.
To fill this gap, we used China’s A-share listed enterprises in 2010–2020 and CCTP to conduct a quasi-natural experiment. Market-incentive environmental regulations can significantly increase high-quality corporate innovations and reduce corporate low-quality innovations. This result is robust after a serious robust test, such as a test on parallel trend assumption that excludes the impact of the national carbon trading market and considers Fujian’s carbon emissions trading policy and substitution of dependent variables. Our heterogeneity analysis results suggest the financialization level of firms and whether they are SOEs affect the effectiveness of CCTP.
The main contributions are as follows: First, we expand the literature on the impact of CTP on enterprises. Previous studies focused on the impact of CTP on carbon emission reduction effects, low-carbon innovation, green innovation, and innovation performance. Nevertheless, we focused more on the heterogeneous impact of CTP on different qualities of corporate innovation. Second, we examined the incentives for innovation of listed corporations under environmental regulation policies. High-quality innovation is an indication of the pursuit of technological breakthroughs, while low-quality innovation may favor ineffective innovation that appeals to policy. We focus on whether CTP can increase high-quality innovation and at the same time reduce low-quality innovation. Third, we use CCTP to conduct a quasi-natural experiment to test the impact of CCTP on corporate innovation, which provides a reference to investigate the question of sustainability from emerging markets.
The rest of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 shows the development of our hypothesis. Section 3 presents the research design of this paper, including background, key variables, data and model. Section 4 shows the main result and robust test. Section 5 details the heterogeneity analysis based on the financialization level and the nature of the enterprise. Section 7 provides the conclusions.

2. Hypothesis Development

According to Porter and Linde (1995), appropriate environmental regulations will provide an impetus for firms’ innovative activities [34]. Thus, as a type of environmental regulation, the CCTP may produce a “Porter effect” and promote innovation in corporates. In the face of environmental pressure from CCTP, companies may purchase carbon emission quotas directly on the market to meet their emission reduction constraints or engage in innovative activities to save energy and reduce emissions. Different quality innovations may be produced in the process of corporate innovation because of the different motivations for innovation. Recent studies have often classified the quality of innovation according to the type of patent [35,36,37].
We first hypothesize that CCTP will incentivize firms to engage in high-quality innovation. As a market-incentivized environmental regulation tool in China, the CCTP aims to internalize the negative externality costs of environmental pollution through the market price mechanism. Theoretically, the carbon emission trading policy makes carbon emission rights a commodity property, i.e., the allocation of resources is achieved through the market trading behavior of carbon emission rights. In this context, high-quality innovation by companies can not only improve their technology and reduce carbon emissions but also trade their excess carbon emission rights on the market for a profit. Hence, companies have an intrinsic incentive and motivation to engage in high-quality, substantial technological innovation [38]. From the above analysis, we develop the following hypothesis.
H1. 
CCTP has a positive impact on high-quality innovation in enterprises.
Second, we further consider the impact of CCTP on low-quality innovation by corporates. According to Tong et al., strategic innovation for “other benefits” is common among Chinese enterprises [39]. The “quantity over quality” strategic innovation is a significant burden on firms’ profitability, and low-quality innovation is merely a response by corporates to seek support in the face of regulatory policies, without any increase in their real innovation capacity [38]. The CCTP is an environmental regulatory policy based on market regulation to achieve its objectives, which makes it difficult for companies to benefit from low-quality innovation. At the same time, CCTP will signal to enterprises that high-quality innovation is the only way to achieve sustainable development. In turn, it reduces low-quality innovation activities of enterprises. Thus, we propose the following hypothesis:
H2. 
CCTP has a negative impact on low-quality innovation in enterprises.

3. Research Design

3.1. Background

Before 2013, Chinese companies participated in carbon trading on the international carbon trading market through the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) of the Kyoto Protocol. Since 2013, the EU has also stopped accepting CER emission reduction targets from countries such as China and India, and thus, Chinese companies have turned to domestic CCER trading. From 2013 to 2017, China launched seven carbon emission trading pilot projects, including Fujian, Beijing, Shenzhen, Chongqing, and Hubei. Therefore, this paper takes the start time of the CCTP in each region as the quasi-natural experiment [33,40]. Using a multi-period difference-in-difference (DID) research method, we collect data on Chinese A-share listed companies to study the impact of CCTP on corporate innovation. Companies in the pilot carbon trading region are the experimental group while companies outside the pilot region are the control group.

3.2. Key Variables

3.2.1. Dependent Variables

Corporate Innovation: The existing literature on firm innovation has two directions: innovation inputs and innovation outputs. Corporate R&D expenditure is the major indicator of corporate innovation inputs [41,42]. The corporate patent acquisition is the major indicator of corporate innovation outputs [43,44]. However, the process of converting R&D into innovation involves opportunity costs and is influenced by the market environment. Therefore, this paper selects the number of patents acquired as an indicator of corporate innovation [45].
According to the China National Intellectual Property Administration (CNIPA), patents can be categorized into three types: invention, utility model, and design patents. Invention patents have a high technical content and have the most stringent examination procedure [9,46]. Therefore, invention patents are usually considered high-quality technological innovation projects [47]. Utility patents are granted for new technical solutions relating to an object’s shape or structure. Design patents are granted for original designs relating to an object’s shape, design, or color. Utility model and design patents have a low technical threshold and are easy to obtain, and thus, are often seen as low-quality innovations. At the same time, some scholars use design patents and utility patents to measure low-quality innovation. For example, Hou (2018) used patents for inventions that are recognized as high-quality patents, and non-invention patents, such as utility model and design patents, are recognized as low-quality patents [48]. This paper further divides the number of patents using the number of invention patents to represent high-quality innovation and the number of utility model and design patents to represent low-quality innovation.

3.2.2. Independent Variable

CCTP dummy variables: The data are grouped according to whether the enterprise is in a pilot region for carbon trading [49]. If the enterprise is in a region where carbon trading policy has been implemented, CCTP = 1, DID = 1; otherwise, it equals 0.

3.2.3. Control Variables

To exclude other factors that could interfere with the results, this paper controls for a set of variables that may influence firms’ innovation decisions [46,50,51]. Including earnings per share (EPS), management fee (Mfee), corporate size (Size), leverage (Lev), cash flow ratio (Cashflow), stock proportion restriction (Balance), business growth (Growth), total assets turnover (ATO), corporate Tobin’s Q value (TobinQ), and number of the board of directors (Board). The specific measures of all variables are shown in Table 1.

3.3. Data

This paper takes the Chinese A-share listed companies as the research object. We establish panel data of Chinese A-share listed companies from 2010–2020. The data on the characteristics of listed companies are obtained from the China Stock Market and Accounting Research Database (CSMAR) and details of corporate patents from the China Research Data Services (CNRDS). We performed the following steps to clean the data: (1) the financial sector is removed, (2) ST corporate and samples with only one period are removed, and (3) all continuous variables are winsorized at the 1–99% levels. Finally, an unbalanced panel is created through 28,269 observations of 3654 A-share listed companies. Additionally, it consists of 1523 state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and 2131 non-state-owned enterprises (N-SOEs) details of descriptive statistics are provided in Table 2).

3.4. Model

3.4.1. Baseline Model

This study constructs the following DID model to test the impact of CCTP on firms’ innovation:
I n v i , t = β 1 + β 2 C C T P i , t + C o n t r o l s i , t + I n d u s t r y F E + Y e a r F E + ε i , t
where I n v is the dependent variable, which represents firm innovation in this study. CCTP is the CCTP dummy variable, which is an independent variable in this paper. The sign and significance of β 2 measure the net effect of CCTP on corporate innovation. C o n t r o l represents the other control variables involved in this study, and finally, this paper controls for year-fixed and industry-fixed effects.

3.4.2. Model for Parallel Trend Testing

A necessary precondition for the DID model is the parallel trend assumption. That is, no significant difference in the firm’s innovation level between the treated and control groups existed before the occurrence of the CCTP. Therefore, based on the previous literature, the following model is developed in this paper [52,53]:
I n v i , t = β 1 + τ = 3 7 β τ C C T P i × I t t = τ + C o n t r o l s i , t + I n d u s t r y F E + Y e a r F E + ε i , t
where C C T P i × I t is a series of dummy variables indicating the τth year of the start of the CCTP. Specifically, I 1 denotes the first year of CCTP, and we cover three years before the implementation and seven years after the start. The other variables are defined and set consistent with model (1). This paper focuses on the variable β τ , which represents the difference in corporate innovation between the treated group and the control group in the τth year of the CCTP. We select the fourth year before the policy occurs as the base year.

4. Result

4.1. Main Result

In this section, we conduct an empirical analysis of model 1. In the analysis process, this paper sequentially adds industry-fixed and year-fixed effects to test the robustness of the results [54]. The main regression results are shown in Table 3. Columns (1)–(3) show the results with the inclusion of control variables and year-fixed effects, and columns (4)–(6) include control variables, industry-fixed and year-fixed effects. The dependent variables in columns (1) and (4) are the total number of patents obtained in the year under observation. The results in columns (1) and (4) indicate that the CCTP does not significantly affect the total number of patents obtained by firms.
The dependent variables in columns (2) and (5) are the number of invention patents obtained in the year, i.e., the degree of high-quality innovation of the firm. According to the results in columns (2) and (4), CCTP positively and significantly impacts firms’ high-quality innovation. Meanwhile, column (5) of Table 3 shows that enacting the CCTP will raise the number of corporate invention patents in the pilot region by 9.5%. This result is consistent with hypothesis 1.
The dependent variables in columns (3) and (6) are the total number of utility model and design patents obtained in the year, i.e., the degree of low-quality innovation generated by the firm. The results in columns (3) and (6) show that CCTP significantly reduces the number of utility model and design patents obtained by firms and that the enactment of the CCTP will result in a 3.3% decrease in the number of utility model and design patents obtained in the year. These results are consistent with hypothesis 2.

4.2. Robust Test

4.2.1. Test on Parallel Trend Assumption

The DID model must satisfy the parallel trend assumption, which ensures that the treated and control groups have the same trend before the occurrence of the carbon trading policy [55,56]. Figure 1 reports the results of model (2), where the dependent variables are, in order, the total number of patents, the number of invention patents, and the number of design and utility model patents. The figure shows that no significant difference in firm innovation between pilot and non-pilot cities could be observed before the CCTP was launched. This finding shows that the treated and control groups selected under the CCTP satisfy the parallel trend assumption.

4.2.2. Excluding the Impact of the National Carbon Trading Market

In December 2017, with the consent of People’s Republic of China State Council (PRCSC), the National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC) issued the national carbon emissions trading market construction program for the electricity sector [23,35]. However, the start of online trading in the national carbon emissions trading market was scheduled for 16 July 2021 [36]. Therefore, the data were not restricted to 2017 in the previous regressions. However, enacting a national carbon trading policy may impact firms’ expectations and influence their innovation decisions. Therefore, in this section, we build a regression of the panel data from 2010–2017 to exclude the effect of the national carbon trading policy. According to the results in columns (1)–(3) of Table 4, the significance and sign of the regression results are consistent with Table 2 after restricting the sample period.

4.2.3. Consider Fujian’s CTP

The CTP in Fujian Province was officially launched on 22 December 2016, while other carbon trading pilots were launched around 2013. Thus, Fujian’s CTP was implemented four years later than other regions. Compared to other pilot regions, Fujian’s carbon trading market has accumulated considerable experience and involved preliminary preparations. Considering the specificity of Fujian’s CTP pilot, we removed Fujian area enterprises for robustness testing. The results shown in columns (4)–(6) of Table 4 indicate that our results are robust after considering Fujian’s carbon emissions trading policy.

4.2.4. Substitution of Dependent Variables

In the above analysis, we chose the number of patents granted as the dependent variable. However, some scholars point out that granting patents takes some time, and thus, using the number of patents granted as the firm’s substantial innovation level in the current year may be biased [57]. Therefore, we chose the number of patent applications as the dependent variable for robustness testing. We followed Griffin et al. in order to choose the total number of patents applied by corporates as a proxy variable for innovation [58], and the number of invention patents applied by corporates in the current year as a proxy variable for high-quality innovation. We then used the sum of utility model patents and foreign design patents applied by enterprises in that year to represent low-quality innovation.
As shown in column (2) of Table 5, the CCTP has a positive effect on the application of invention patents, which passes the 10% significance test. This finding suggests that CCTP significantly improves the application of high-quality innovation patents, which is consistent with the above analysis and results. According to the results in column (3) of Table 5, the CCTP has a negative effect on the application of invention patents, and this result passes the 1% significance test. Thus, CCTP also reduces the application of low-quality patents, in line with the above research findings.
We further introduce dependent variables from the perspective of innovation inputs to boost the robustness of the results. The existing literature considers R&D expenditures an important indicator of firms’ innovation input [59,60,61]. Therefore, we introduce three indicators of R&D investment as proxy variables for firms’ innovation investment to conduct robustness tests: R&D expenditure divided by total assets (R&D_ass), R&D expenditure divided by operating revenue (R&D_ret), and R&D expenditure divided by total profit (R&D_pro). According to columns (4)–(6) of Table 5, the coefficients of CCTP are positive and pass the 5% significance test, which indicates that CCTP significantly enhances firms’ innovation input.

5. Heterogeneity Analysis

In our previous analysis, we examined the role of CCTP in promoting firms’ high-quality innovation. At the same time, CCTP can significantly reduce low-quality innovation. However, certain differences, such as individual firms, may affect the incentive effect of CCTP on high-quality innovation. Therefore, this paper performs subgroup regression analysis according to the differences in the degree of financialization and the nature of corporate ownership.

5.1. Heterogeneity of Financialization

We first analyze the impact of carbon emissions trading policies on firm innovation from a firm financialization perspective. According to Su and Liu, whether or not a corporate is in financialization affects a corporate’s current innovation decisions [62]. Hence, to verify whether corporate financialization has a heterogeneous impact on corporate innovation, we divide the corporates into two groups according to the proportion of financial assets they hold. Firms are in the High-Fin group if the degree of financialization is greater than or equal to the medium value; otherwise, they are in the Low-Fin group.
Columns (1) and (2) of Table 6 show that the coefficient of DID in column (1) is positive but not significant, while the coefficient of DID in column (2) is positive and passes the 1% significance test.
The coefficients of DID in columns (3) and (4) of Table 6 are positive and pass the 1% significance test, suggesting that CCTP increases the number of invention patents for high-financialized and low-financialized firms. Considering that the coefficient differences in columns (3) and (4) cannot be compared directly, we follow Qi et al. to build a triple difference model based on the financialization of the corporate for analysis [49]. We first generate dummy variables for the financialization of the firm, i.e., if the degree of financialization is greater than or equal to the medium value Fin = 1, otherwise Fin = 0. Then, we further analyze the interaction term of CCTP and Fin.
The result in column (5) of Table 6 reported that the coefficient on CCTP*Fin is negative and passes the 10% significance test, thereby suggesting that increased financialization of firms can decrease the incentive effect of CCTP on invention patents.
In columns (6) and (7) of Table 6, we further analyze the heterogeneous impact of corporate financialization on low-quality innovation. For the more financialized corporates, the coefficient of DID is negative and passes the 5% significance test. However, for less financialized corporates, the coefficient of CCTP is almost equal to zero and insignificant.

5.2. Heterogeneity of Corporate Ownership

In China, SOEs play a leading position in the economy, while N-SOEs also hold a highly significant status [63]. Corporate innovation activities have technology spillover effects and strong externalities [64]. At the same time, technological innovation in firms requires long-term and continuous capital investment and involves relatively high risks [65]. Due to the differences in business objectives and corporate governance between SOEs and N-SOEs, the environmental objectives and innovation decisions of enterprises with different corporate ownerships also differ significantly [66]. According to Laffont and Tirole, technological innovation activities often conflict with the goal of profit maximization for non-SOEs [67]. As a market-incentive environmental regulation policy, carbon trading can convert the external effects of technological innovation activities into internal benefits for enterprises, which may affect the decision-making of both SOEs and non-SOEs regarding technological innovation activities. This section provides an empirical test of this issue.
We first investigate the impact of CCTP on the total innovation of SOEs and non-SOEs. As reported in columns (1) and (2) of Table 7, the coefficient of CCTP in SOE is negative and statistically significant at the 1% level. In contrast, the coefficient of CCTP in N-SOE is positive and statistically significant at the 1% level. As a result, CCTP significantly reduced the total amount of technological innovation in SOEs and increased the total amount of technological innovation in non-SOEs.
Columns (3) and (4) of Table 7 present the results of the heterogeneous impact of CCTP on firms’ high-quality innovation. We can observe that the coefficient of CCTP in N-SOE is positive and statistically significant at the 1% level, whereas the coefficient in SOE is not significant.
Finally, we compare the impact of CCTP on low-quality innovation in SOEs and non-SOEs. According to the result of columns (5) and (6) of Table 7, the coefficient of CCTP in SOE is negative and statistically significant at the 1% level. In contrast, the coefficient of CCTP in N-SOE is positive and statistically significant at the 1% level. Thus, our results show that the CCTP significantly increased the technological innovation activities of non-state enterprises while reducing the low-quality technological innovation behavior of SOEs.

6. Discussion

According to the results in Table 3, the CCTP has a positive impact on corporate high-quality innovation and this result is consistent with H1. This may be because the CCTP imposes higher technological requirements on enterprises, making them seek more innovative and advanced technologies to reduce carbon emissions. This finding validates Porter’s hypothesis [16,34]. It is also consistent with the conclusions of the literature on CTP and corporate innovation [33,38]. We further find that CCTP has a negative impact on corporate low-quality innovation. In the process of improving energy efficiency and reducing carbon emissions, corporate may facilitate the transformation from low-quality innovation to high-quality innovation.
Columns (1) and (2) of Table 6 indicate that the CCTP significantly increases the total number of patents of low-financialized firms and has no effect on high-financialized firms. Column (5) of Table 6 reveals that increased financialization of firms can decrease the incentive effect of CCTP on invention patents. The main reason is that a high level of corporate financialization may lead companies to focus more on return on investment rather than environmental benefits. CCTP aims to reduce carbon emissions through price incentives, but if companies are more concerned with return on investment, they may see carbon trading as an investment and thus focus more on its return rather than its environmental result when buying carbon emission quotas. Thus, higher financialization of corporations may diminish the incentives of CCTP for high-quality innovation.
As is revealed in Columns (3) and (4) of Table 7, the impact of CCTP on high-quality corporate innovation occurs mainly in non-SOEs. This may be because SOEs hold a critical position in the Chinese economy and often receive policy assistance and other favorable policies [63]. These policies may mitigate the impact of CCTP on their business behavior. In contrast, non-SOEs tend to face more competition and market risks and, as a result, need to pay more attention to carbon emissions [66]; therefore, they need to be more sensitive to carbon emission issues. Furthermore, according to the results of Columns (5) and (6) of Table 7, CCTP significantly reduces low-quality innovation in SOEs and increases low-quality innovation in non-SOEs. This may result from the fact that for SOEs, their propensity for low-quality innovation may be relatively low due to the preferential treatment and greater resource support they enjoy in terms of policy. For non-SOEs, on the other hand, their propensity to engage in low-quality innovation may be greater due to their lack of resources and policy support.

7. Conclusions

7.1. Findings

China’s national carbon trading market was launched in 2021. While innovation-driven development is a matter of sustainable economic development, the impact of carbon emissions trading policies on innovation is worth exploring. The quality of a firm’s innovation not only affects its technology but is also related to the performance of its environment. However, the literature analyzing the impact of CCTP on the quality of corporate innovation is scarce. Hence, this paper used China’s A-share listed enterprises in 2010–2020 and CCTP to conduct a quasi-natural experiment. The relevant conclusions are as follows:
First, CCTP significantly improved the quality of innovation, increasing the granting of patents for high-quality innovations while reducing the granting of patents for low-quality innovations.
Second, the level of corporate financialization affects the effectiveness of CCTP. When firms are highly financialized, it can suppress the positive impact of corporate CCTP on high-quality innovation. At the same time, highly financialized firms can enhance the negative impact of CCTP on low-quality innovation.
Finally, the CCTP has different impacts based on the various natures of enterprises. The positive impact of CCTP on high-quality innovation occurs mainly among N-SOEs. In contrast, the negative impact of CCTP on low-quality innovation occurs mainly among N-SOEs.

7.2. Policy Recommendations

Based on the findings of this paper, we offer the following policy recommendations:
First, China should continue to promote the development of a national carbon emissions trading market. Currently, China’s national carbon trading only covers the power sector, which has been an important part of the regional carbon trading market. As an energy conversion sector, improvements in the power sector can effectively reduce the proportion of primary energy consumed by coal and promote technological innovation in other energy-intensive enterprises.
Second, focus should also be given to the development of the real economy. According to the empirical results in Section 5, corporate innovation behavior is limited by corporate financialization. Hence, it is necessary to perfect the financial market system to provide financial support to real enterprises in technology innovation.
Finally, the supervision of innovation investment in SOEs should be strengthened and these enterprises should be guided toward improving innovation quality. In China, SOEs play a leading position in the economy. Hence, the improved innovation quality of SOEs would be of real significance for the sustainable development of China’s economy.

7.3. Research Limitations

First, we have considered all the pilot region enterprises to be affected by the CCTP. This may not be consistent with the facts. In the next study, we will further match the specific list of firms in the CCTP to more accurately measure the policy effects of the CCTP.
Second, we have only examined the heterogeneous impact of CCTP on corporate innovation and have not investigated its specific transmission mechanisms in depth. In our future work, we will continue to deeply explore the internal motivations of corporate innovation and the internal mechanisms of CCTP that influence innovation.
Finally, while we have excluded the effect of a national carbon trading market from our robustness tests, we did not develop an analysis of the effect of a national carbon trading market in the electricity sector. This issue will be an important topic as the national carbon trading market develops.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, C.T. and Y.S.; methodology, C.T.; software, C.T.; validation, Y.S.; formal analysis, Y.S.; investigation, C.T.; resources, Y.S.; data curation, Y.S.; writing—original draft preparation, Y.S.; writing—review and editing, C.T.; visualization, C.T.; supervision, Y.S.; project administration, Y.S.; funding acquisition, Y.S. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

This study does not involve any ethical issues.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The data of this research are publicly available.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Richnák, P.; Fidlerová, H. Impact and Potential of Sustainable Development Goals in Dimension of the Technological Revolution Industry 4.0 within the Analysis of Industrial Enterprises. Energies 2022, 15, 3697. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Olabi, A.; Abdelkareem, M.A. Renewable energy and climate change. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2022, 158, 112111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Perea-Moreno, A.-J. Renewable Energy and Energy Saving: Worldwide Research Trends; MDPI: Basel, Switzerland, 2021; Volume 13, p. 13261. [Google Scholar]
  4. Aggeri, F. Environmental policies and innovation: A knowledge-based perspective on cooperative approaches. Res. Policy 1999, 28, 699–717. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Pan, X.; Ai, B.; Li, C.; Pan, X.; Yan, Y. Dynamic relationship among environmental regulation, technological innovation and energy efficiency based on large scale provincial panel data in China. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2019, 144, 428–435. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Shi, Y.; Li, Y. An evolutionary game analysis on green technological innovation of new energy enterprises under the heterogeneous environmental regulation perspective. Sustainability 2022, 14, 6340. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Li, W.; Lu, C. The research on setting a unified interval of carbon price benchmark in the national carbon trading market of China. Appl. Energy 2015, 155, 728–739. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Calel, R.; Dechezleprêtre, A. Environmental policy and directed technological change: Evidence from the European carbon market. Rev. Econ. Stat. 2016, 98, 173–191. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Huang, H.; Qi, B.; Chen, L. Innovation and High-Quality Development of Enterprises—Also on the Effect of Innovation Driving the Transformation of China’s Economic Development Model. Sustainability 2022, 14, 8440. [Google Scholar]
  10. Hu, J.; Pan, X.; Huang, Q. Quantity or quality? The impacts of environmental regulation on firms’ innovation–Quasi-natural experiment based on China’s carbon emissions trading pilot. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2020, 158, 120122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Xu, T.; Kang, C.; Zhang, H. China’s efforts towards carbon neutrality: Does energy-saving and emission-reduction policy mitigate carbon emissions? J. Environ. Manag. 2022, 316, 115286. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Feng, Z.; Wu, X.; Chen, H.; Qin, Y.; Zhang, L.; Skibniewski, M.J. An energy performance contracting parameter optimization method based on the response surface method: A case study of a metro in China. Energy 2022, 248, 123612. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Zhang, P.; Wang, H. Do provincial energy policies and energy intensity targets help reduce CO2 emissions? Evidence from China. Energy 2022, 245, 123275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Jia, Z.; Lin, B. Rethinking the choice of carbon tax and carbon trading in China. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2020, 159, 120187. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Weng, Q.; Xu, H. A review of China’s carbon trading market. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2018, 91, 613–619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Porter, M. America’s green strategy. Scientific the Netherlands: University Utrecht. Sci. Am. 1991, 168, 45. [Google Scholar]
  17. Lanoie, P.; Patry, M.; Lajeunesse, R. Environmental regulation and productivity: Testing the porter hypothesis. J. Productiv. Anal. 2008, 30, 121–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Berman, E.; Bui, L.T. Environmental regulation and productivity: Evidence from oil refineries. Rev. Econ. Stat. 2001, 83, 498–510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  19. Dean, T.J.; Brown, R.L. Pollution regulation as a barrier to new firm entry: Initial evidence and implications for future research. Acad. Manag. J. 1995, 38, 288–303. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Qu, X. Double effects of heterogeneous environmental regulation on haze pollution. Mod. Econ. Sci. 2018, 40, 26–37. [Google Scholar]
  21. Shen, C.; Li, S.; Huang, L. Different types of environmental regulation and the green transformation of Chinese industry: Path selection and mechanism analysis. Nankai Econ. Stud. 2018, 5, 95–114. [Google Scholar]
  22. Yi, M.; Fang, X.; Wen, L.; Guang, F.; Zhang, Y. The heterogeneous effects of different environmental policy instruments on green technology innovation. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2019, 16, 4660. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  23. Dong, F.; Zheng, L. The impact of market-incentive environmental regulation on the development of the new energy vehicle industry: A quasi-natural experiment based on China’s dual-credit policy. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2022, 29, 5863–5880. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  24. Milliman, S.R.; Prince, R. Firm incentives to promote technological change in pollution control. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 1989, 17, 247–265. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Laing, T.; Sato, M.; Grubb, M.; Comberti, C. The effects and side-effects of the EU emissions trading scheme. Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Clim. Chang. 2014, 5, 509–519. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Eikeland, P.O.; Skjærseth, J.B. Oil and power industries’ responses to EU emissions trading: Laggards or low-carbon leaders? Environ. Politics 2019, 28, 104–124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Qi, S.-Z.; Zhou, C.-B.; Li, K.; Tang, S.-Y. Influence of a pilot carbon trading policy on enterprises’ low-carbon innovation in China. Clim. Policy 2021, 21, 318–336. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Zhang, L.; Cao, C.; Tang, F.; He, J.; Li, D. Does China’s emissions trading system foster corporate green innovation? Evidence from regulating listed companies. Technol. Anal. Strateg. Manag. 2019, 31, 199–212. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Jiang, Z.; Wang, Z.; Li, Z. The effect of mandatory environmental regulation on innovation performance: Evidence from China. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 203, 482–491. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Mo, J.Y. Technological innovation and its impact on carbon emissions: Evidence from Korea manufacturing firms participating emission trading scheme. Technol. Anal. Strateg. Manag. 2022, 34, 47–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Thoma, G. Quality and value of Chinese patenting: An international perspective. Seoul J. Econ. 2013, 26, 33–72. [Google Scholar]
  32. Dang, J.; Motohashi, K. Patent statistics: A good indicator for innovation in China? Patent subsidy program impacts on patent quality. China Econ. Rev. 2015, 35, 137–155. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Lv, M.; Bai, M. Evaluation of China’s carbon emission trading policy from corporate innovation. Financ. Res. Lett. 2021, 39, 101565. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Porter, M.E.; van der Linde, C. Toward a new conception of the environment-competitiveness relationship. J. Econ. Perspect. 1995, 9, 97–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Yuan, R.; Wen, W. Managerial foreign experience and corporate innovation. J. Corp. Financ. 2018, 48, 752–770. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Li, Z.; Liao, G.; Albitar, K. Does corporate environmental responsibility engagement affect firm value? The mediating role of corporate innovation. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2020, 29, 1045–1055. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Tan, Z.; Yan, L. Does air pollution impede corporate innovation? Int. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2021, 76, 937–951. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Zhang, Y.; Yuan, B.; Zheng, J.; Deng, Y. Strategic Response or Substantive Response? The Effect of China’s Carbon Emissions Trading Policy on Enterprise Green Innovation. Nankai Bus. Rev. 2022, 1, 1–24. [Google Scholar]
  39. Tong, T.W.; He, W.; He, Z.-L.; Lu, J. Patent Regime Shift and Firm Innovation: Evidence from the Second Amendment to China’s Patent Law. Acad. Manag. Annu. Meet. Proc. 2014, 2014, 14174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Zhao, X.-G.; Wu, L.; Li, A. Research on the efficiency of carbon trading market in China. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 79, 1–8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Sharma, P.; Davcik, N.S.; Pillai, K.G. Product innovation as a mediator in the impact of R&D expenditure and brand equity on marketing performance. J. Bus. Res. 2016, 69, 5662–5669. [Google Scholar]
  42. Chen, C.; Gu, J.; Luo, R. Corporate innovation and R&D expenditure disclosures. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 2022, 174, 121230. [Google Scholar]
  43. Xu, Z. Economic policy uncertainty, cost of capital, and corporate innovation. J. Bank. Financ. 2020, 111, 105698. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Lin, C.; Liu, S.; Manso, G. Shareholder litigation and corporate innovation. Manag. Sci. 2021, 67, 3346–3367. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Boubakri, N.; Chkir, I.; Saadi, S.; Zhu, H. Does national culture affect corporate innovation? International evidence. J. Corp. Financ. 2021, 66, 101847. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Fang, L.H.; Lerner, J.; Wu, C. Intellectual property rights protection, ownership, and innovation: Evidence from China. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2017, 30, 2446–2477. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  47. Tan, Y.; Liu, X.; Sun, H.; Zeng, C.C. Population ageing, labour market rigidity and corporate innovation: Evidence from China. Res. Policy 2022, 51, 104428. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Hou, J. Does the pay gap in the top management team incent enterprise innovation?—Based on property rights and financing constraints. Am. J. Ind. Bus. Manag. 2018, 8, 1290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  49. Qi, S.-Z.; Zhou, C.-B.; Li, K.; Tang, S.-Y. The impact of a carbon trading pilot policy on the low-carbon international competitiveness of industry in China: An empirical analysis based on a DDD model. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 281, 125361. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Tian, X.; Wang, T.Y. Tolerance for failure and corporate innovation. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2014, 27, 211–255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Wen, H.; Zhong, Q.; Lee, C.-C. Digitalization, competition strategy and corporate innovation: Evidence from Chinese manufacturing listed companies. Int. Rev. Finan. Anal. 2022, 82, 102166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Xu, X.; Liu, C. Research on the Impact of Expressway on the County Economy Based on a Spatial DID Model: The Case of Three Provinces of China. Math. Probl. Eng. 2021, 2021, 4028236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Zhou, G.; Liu, C.; Luo, S. Resource allocation effect of green credit policy: Based on DID model. Mathematics 2021, 9, 159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Wang, W.; Sun, Z.; Wang, W.; Hua, Q.; Wu, F. The impact of environmental uncertainty on ESG performance: Emotional vs. rational. J. Clean. Prod. 2023, 136528. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Zhou, J.; Huo, X.; Jin, B.; Yu, X. The efficiency of carbon trading market in China: Evidence from variance ratio tests. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2019, 26, 14362–14372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Yu, Z.; Geng, Y.; Calzadilla, A.; Bleischwitz, R. China’s unconventional carbon emissions trading market: The impact of a rate-based cap in the power generation sector. Energy 2022, 255, 124581. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Hong, M.; Li, Z.; Drakeford, B. Do the green credit guidelines affect corporate green technology innovation? Empirical research from China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public. Health 2021, 18, 1682. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  58. Griffin, D.; Li, K.; Xu, T. Board gender diversity and corporate innovation: International evidence. J. Finan. Quant. Anal. 2021, 56, 123–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Chen, Y.; Podolski, E.J.; Veeraraghavan, M. National culture and corporate innovation. Pacific-Basin Financ. J. 2017, 43, 173–187. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. He, J.; Tian, X. Finance and corporate innovation: A survey. Asia-Pacific J. Financ. Stud. 2018, 47, 165–212. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  61. Lu, J.; Wang, W. Managerial conservatism, board independence and corporate innovation. J. Corp. Financ. 2018, 48, 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Su, K.; Liu, H. Financialization of manufacturing companies and corporate innovation: Lessons from an emerging economy. Manag. Dec. Econ. 2021, 42, 863–875. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Xie, Z.; Li, J. Selective imitation of compatriot firms: Entry mode decisions of emerging market multinationals in cross-border acquisitions. Asia Pac. J. Manag. 2017, 34, 47–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Takalo, S.K.; Tooranloo, H.S. Green innovation: A systematic literature review. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 279, 122474. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Rennings, K. Redefining innovation—Eco-innovation research and the contribution from ecological economics. Ecol. Econ. 2000, 32, 319–332. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Yu, Z.; Shen, Y.; Jiang, S. The effects of corporate governance uncertainty on state-owned enterprises’ green innovation in China: Perspective from the participation of non-state-owned shareholders. Energy Econ. 2022, 115, 106402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Laffont, J.-J.; Tirole, J. A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1993. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Parallel trend test, for each coefficient, the 95% confidence interval is reported.
Figure 1. Parallel trend test, for each coefficient, the 95% confidence interval is reported.
Sustainability 15 05924 g001
Table 1. Variable measures.
Table 1. Variable measures.
VariableVariable Measure
Inv_allLn(number of patents granted +1)
Inv_highLn(number of invention patents granted +1)
Inv_lowLn(number of utility model patents + design patents granted +1)
EPSNet profit/Total number of shares
MfeeAdministrative expenses/operating income
SizeNatural logarithm of total assets at the end of the year
LevTotal debt divided by total assets
CashflowNet cash flows from operating activities divided by total assets
BalanceThe sum of top2-top5 shareholding divided by top1 shareholder shareholding
GrowthOperating income for the year divided by operating income for the previous year −1
ATOOperating income divided by average total assets
TobinQ(Market value of shares outstanding + number of non-marketable shares x net assets per share + book value of liabilities)/total assets
BoardBoard size in natural logarithms
Table 2. Statistical description.
Table 2. Statistical description.
All SampleControl GroupTreated Group
VariableNMeanSDNMeanSDNMeanSD
Inv_all28,2691.4881.52619,2161.4511.49290531.5671.592
Inv_high28,2690.7301.03419,2160.6760.97290530.8441.145
Inv_low28,2691.2101.46119,2161.1951.44090531.2421.504
EPS28,2690.3600.59819,2160.3510.58390530.3810.626
Mfee28,2690.0960.08919,2160.0950.08890530.0990.091
Size28,26922.171.30519,21622.101.252905322.321.401
Lev28,2690.4360.21119,2160.4390.21290530.4300.206
ROE28,2690.0590.14519,2160.0590.14490530.0590.146
Cashflow28,2690.0440.072019,2160.0440.07290530.0440.070
Balance28,2690.7180.60719,2160.6870.59190530.7830.634
Growth28,2690.1850.51019,2160.1880.51790530.1780.495
ATO28,2690.6400.44519,2160.6440.44290530.6300.452
TobinQ28,2692.0961.46119,2162.0511.42490532.1921.531
Board28,2692.1320.19919,2162.1410.19490532.1130.208
Table 3. Main results.
Table 3. Main results.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Inv_allInv_highInv_lowInv_allInv_highInv_low
CCTP−0.0080.091 ***−0.059 ***0.0240.095 ***−0.033 *
(−0.402)(6.299)(−2.961)(1.315)(7.135)(−1.919)
EPS0.130 ***0.0170.135 ***0.067 ***0.0120.068 ***
(4.979)(0.997)(5.395)(3.076)(0.798)(3.227)
Mfee−0.490 ***0.451 ***−0.714 ***0.0490.560 ***−0.189 **
(−4.646)(5.942)(−7.737)(0.534)(8.187)(−2.249)
Size0.169 ***0.204 ***0.134 ***0.303 ***0.272 ***0.249 ***
(15.066)(25.327)(12.473)(31.797)(37.173)(27.110)
Lev−0.891 ***−0.634 ***−0.579 ***−0.527 ***−0.331 ***−0.384 ***
(−17.853)(−19.522)(−12.258)(−11.977)(−10.665)(−9.117)
ROE−0.113−0.021−0.0770.135*0.0850.127*
(−1.227)(−0.362)(−0.887)(1.693)(1.584)(1.681)
Cashflow0.511 ***0.319 ***0.357 ***0.895 ***0.445 ***0.805 ***
(4.009)(3.938)(2.975)(8.356)(5.967)(7.822)
Balance0.084 ***0.043 ***0.056 ***−0.015−0.013−0.028 **
(5.701)(4.303)(3.924)(−1.220)(−1.431)(−2.337)
Growth−0.119 ***−0.057 ***−0.115 ***−0.123 ***−0.070 ***−0.115 ***
(−7.747)(−5.933)(−8.147)(−8.958)(−7.641)(−8.762)
ATO0.224 ***0.172 ***0.183 ***0.210 ***0.131 ***0.195 ***
(9.156)(11.207)(8.102)(9.764)(8.885)(9.416)
TobinQ−0.019 ***0.027 ***−0.031 ***−0.0000.026 ***−0.003
(−2.859)(5.690)(−4.717)(−0.072)(5.952)(−0.594)
Board−0.074−0.003−0.091 **0.171 ***0.136 ***0.128 ***
(−1.511)(−0.085)(−1.979)(4.196)(4.522)(3.287)
_cons−1.866 ***−3.787 ***−1.349 ***−5.551 ***−5.679 ***−4.540 ***
(−7.558)(−21.407)(−5.689)(−26.215)(−34.833)(−22.081)
IndNoNoNoYESYESYES
YearYESYESYESYESYESYES
N28,26928,26928,26928,26928,26928,269
r20.0490.0650.0420.3700.2680.352
Note: ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. Standard errors clustered at the firm level.
Table 4. Excluding the impact of the national carbon trading market and Fujian’s CTP.
Table 4. Excluding the impact of the national carbon trading market and Fujian’s CTP.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Inv_allInv_highInv_lowInv_allInv_highInv_low
CCTP0.0060.077 ***−0.044 *0.0230.095 ***−0.033 *
(0.248)(4.295)(−1.955)(1.231)(6.926)(−1.840)
EPS0.084 ***0.0310.083 ***0.068 ***0.0130.068 ***
(2.714)(1.430)(2.789)(3.000)(0.838)(3.104)
Mfee0.590 ***0.957 ***0.202 **0.0450.557 ***−0.197 **
(5.263)(11.029)(2.007)(0.482)(7.975)(−2.298)
Size0.312 ***0.260 ***0.266 ***0.307 ***0.274 ***0.254 ***
(25.573)(27.541)(22.588)(31.602)(36.703)(27.099)
Lev−0.595 ***−0.303 ***−0.445 ***−0.529 ***−0.340 ***−0.383 ***
(−11.223)(−7.965)(−8.767)(−11.829)(−10.723)(−8.935)
ROE0.0220.114−0.0270.137 *0.0750.137 *
(0.200)(1.525)(−0.264)(1.684)(1.370)(1.763)
Cashflow0.770 ***0.513 ***0.680 ***0.872 ***0.421 ***0.789 ***
(6.074)(5.757)(5.590)(7.940)(5.510)(7.483)
Balance−0.029 *−0.024 **−0.033 **−0.015−0.017 *−0.027 **
(−1.917)(−2.133)(−2.230)(−1.230)(−1.804)(−2.210)
Growth−0.125 ***−0.068 ***−0.115 ***−0.131 ***−0.076 ***−0.122 ***
(−7.915)(−6.365)(−7.877)(−9.319)(−8.149)(−9.076)
ATO0.258 ***0.164 ***0.224 ***0.230 ***0.149 ***0.210 ***
(10.132)(9.210)(9.163)(10.354)(9.739)(9.813)
TobinQ−0.017 **0.007−0.011−0.0010.026 ***−0.003
(−2.344)(1.307)(−1.637)(−0.088)(5.663)(−0.488)
Board0.144 ***0.140 ***0.0780.158 ***0.126 ***0.119 ***
(2.871)(3.712)(1.622)(3.783)(4.069)(2.977)
_cons−5.741 ***−5.418 ***−4.851 ***−5.618 ***−5.699 ***−4.633 ***
(−21.270)(−26.064)(−18.538)(−25.992)(−34.224)(−22.079)
IndYESYESYESYESYESYES
YearYESYESYESYESYESYES
N18,08118,08118,08127,19427,19427,194
r20.3850.2840.3610.3720.2710.354
Note: ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. Standard errors clustered at the firm level.
Table 5. Robust test with Substitution of dependent variables.
Table 5. Robust test with Substitution of dependent variables.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Inv_all_aInv_high_aInv_low_aR&D_assR&D_reR&D_pro
CCTP−0.0030.031 *−0.051 ***0.003 ***0.048 **0.501 ***
(−0.173)(1.847)(−2.810)(11.427)(2.492)(9.152)
EPS0.107 ***0.069 ***0.089 ***0.001 ***−0.349 ***0.024
(4.375)(3.424)(4.023)(3.049)(−23.295)(0.331)
Mfee−0.0110.453 ***−0.310 ***0.047 ***1.036 ***25.601 ***
(−0.102)(5.201)(−3.590)(17.236)(5.942)(28.593)
Size0.313 ***0.317 ***0.245 ***−0.000 ***0.0030.201 ***
(29.785)(34.960)(25.749)(−3.300)(0.290)(7.078)
Lev−0.613 ***−0.404 ***−0.421 ***−0.007 ***0.494 ***−2.928 ***
(−12.432)(−9.982)(−9.615)(−10.989)(9.349)(−16.733)
ROE0.363 ***0.361 ***0.231 ***0.004 ***1.636 ***0.558
(4.124)(5.162)(2.968)(2.666)(27.511)(1.574)
Cashflow0.986 ***0.687 ***0.890 ***0.021 ***−0.821 ***1.546 ***
(8.183)(6.954)(8.307)(12.330)(−6.397)(3.694)
Balance−0.0030.009−0.029 **0.001 ***−0.0100.302 ***
(−0.219)(0.749)(−2.327)(5.809)(−0.766)(7.166)
Growth−0.143 ***−0.102 ***−0.125 ***−0.001 ***−0.111 ***−0.015
(−9.085)(−8.143)(−9.045)(−2.929)(−6.636)(−0.280)
ATO0.243 ***0.198 ***0.201 ***0.013 ***0.153 ***−0.752 ***
(10.230)(10.231)(9.365)(32.091)(6.433)(−10.607)
TobinQ−0.0050.023 ***−0.0040.001 ***−0.039 ***0.197 ***
(−0.672)(4.013)(−0.652)(8.854)(−5.993)(6.322)
Board0.220 ***0.190 ***0.157 ***0.001 **0.0100.013
(4.849)(4.933)(3.858)(2.265)(0.224)(0.097)
_cons−5.670 ***−6.383 ***−4.437 ***0.013 ***0.291−1.492 **
(−24.130)(−31.415)(−20.817)(4.490)(1.346)(−2.245)
IndYESYESYESYESYESYES
YearYESYESYESYESYESYES
N28,26928,26928,26922,95722,95718,981
r20.3640.3120.3550.4320.0900.536
Note: ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. Standard errors clustered at the firm level.
Table 6. Heterogeneity analysis with Financialization.
Table 6. Heterogeneity analysis with Financialization.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
High-FinLow-FinHigh-FinLow-FinDiffHigh-FinLow-Fin
Inv_allInv_highInv_low
CCTP0.0030.073 ***0.075 ***0.135 ***0.138 ***−0.046 **−0.000
(0.133)(2.599)(4.368)(6.362)(6.633)(−2.040)(−0.009)
CCTP*Fin −0.047 *
(−1.834)
Fin −0.002
(−0.165)
EPS−0.0040.153 ***−0.036 *0.072 ***0.0010.0170.117 ***
(−0.130)(4.519)(−1.688)(3.097)(0.126)(0.615)(3.573)
Mfee0.0020.1840.542 ***0.633 ***0.013−0.214 **−0.107
(0.016)(1.238)(6.440)(5.462)(1.347)(−1.986)(−0.786)
Size0.318 ***0.293 ***0.291 ***0.256 ***0.280 ***0.262 ***0.237 ***
(25.048)(19.809)(29.771)(22.936)(36.825)(21.436)(16.527)
Lev−0.423 ***−0.592 ***−0.299 ***−0.358 ***−0.377 ***−0.278 ***−0.445 ***
(−6.768)(−9.241)(−6.813)(−7.948)(−12.222)(−4.654)(−7.207)
ROE0.325 ***−0.0800.212 ***−0.069−0.0020.284***−0.023
(2.865)(−0.712)(2.831)(−0.898)(−0.533)(2.626)(−0.212)
Cashflow1.281 ***0.416 ***0.646 ***0.204 *0.410 ***1.144 ***0.392 **
(8.822)(2.599)(6.342)(1.847)(5.877)(8.232)(2.533)
Balance0.011−0.050 ***0.006−0.036 ***−0.011−0.012−0.051 ***
(0.664)(−2.825)(0.440)(−2.708)(−1.176)(−0.739)(−2.936)
Growth−0.088 ***−0.171 ***−0.055 ***−0.092 ***0.000−0.088 ***−0.150 ***
(−4.721)(−8.556)(−4.409)(−6.850)(0.369)(−4.803)(−8.003)
ATO0.179 ***0.258 ***0.129 ***0.133 ***0.044 ***0.166 ***0.246 ***
(6.585)(7.470)(6.978)(5.553)(4.436)(6.340)(7.314)
TobinQ0.031 ***−0.035 ***0.044 ***0.0070.011 ***0.024 ***−0.035 ***
(3.673)(−3.964)(6.888)(1.178)(4.430)(3.038)(−4.037)
Board0.167 ***0.215 ***0.109 ***0.196 ***0.160 ***0.129 **0.168 ***
(2.964)(3.618)(2.639)(4.420)(4.911)(2.407)(2.906)
_cons−6.109 ***−5.194 ***−6.174 ***−5.307 ***−5.745 ***−5.033 ***−4.158 ***
(−21.289)(−16.115)(−27.934)(−21.708)(−34.198)(−17.982)(−13.321)
IndYESYESYESYESYESYESYES
YearYESYESYESYESYESYESYES
N14,86013,40714,86013,40728,26914,86013,407
r20.4110.3250.3130.2260.2720.3840.320
Note: ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. Standard errors clustered at the firm level.
Table 7. Heterogeneity analysis with corporate ownership.
Table 7. Heterogeneity analysis with corporate ownership.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
SOEN-SOESOEN-SOESOEN-SOE
Inv_allInv_highInv_low
CCTP−0.206 ***0.139 ***−0.0220.149 ***−0.244 ***0.071 ***
(−6.483)(6.474)(−0.918)(9.288)(−8.005)(3.350)
EPS−0.0040.123 ***−0.0200.052 ***−0.0040.119 ***
(−0.094)(4.714)(−0.730)(2.805)(−0.116)(4.696)
Mfee−0.1070.215 *0.344 ***0.657 ***−0.346 **−0.025
(−0.668)(1.897)(2.850)(7.805)(−2.272)(−0.239)
Size0.357 ***0.289 ***0.292 ***0.252 ***0.305 ***0.234 ***
(23.116)(23.029)(25.210)(25.436)(20.529)(19.371)
Lev−0.675 ***−0.416 ***−0.496 ***−0.227 ***−0.597 ***−0.255 ***
(−8.951)(−7.540)(−9.111)(−5.899)(−8.252)(−4.827)
ROE−0.1260.213 **−0.0330.100−0.0700.191* *
(−0.909)(2.234)(−0.348)(1.567)(−0.516)(2.119)
Cashflow0.518 ***1.069 ***0.342 ***0.540 ***0.431 **0.966 ***
(2.844)(8.156)(2.653)(5.930)(2.473)(7.657)
Balance−0.068 ***−0.014−0.046 **0.001−0.069 ***−0.027 *
(−2.711)(−0.996)(−2.554)(0.091)(−2.847)(−1.937)
Growth−0.109 ***−0.136 ***−0.070 ***−0.071 ***−0.104 ***−0.124 ***
(−4.594)(−7.918)(−4.399)(−6.299)(−4.615)(−7.550)
ATO0.128 ***0.238 ***0.063 ***0.144 ***0.112 ***0.225 ***
(4.275)(8.054)(2.817)(7.361)(3.879)(7.938)
TobinQ0.020−0.0110.022 **0.022 ***0.024 *−0.017 **
(1.568)(−1.622)(2.446)(4.094)(1.930)(−2.485)
Board0.252 ***0.138 ***0.145 ***0.112 ***0.219 ***0.088 *
(3.510)(2.766)(2.735)(3.018)(3.239)(1.823)
_cons−7.030 ***−5.092 ***−6.083 ***−5.190 ***−6.018 ***−4.085 ***
(−19.376)(−18.595)(−22.491)(−23.760)(−17.185)(−15.379)
IndYESYESYESYESYESYES
YearYESYESYESYESYESYES
N10,27217,99710,27217,99710,27217,997
r20.4400.3460.3650.2240.4080.343
Note: ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. Standard errors clustered at the firm level.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Tu, C.; Shi, Y. Market-Incentive Environmental Regulation and the Quality of Corporate Innovation. Sustainability 2023, 15, 5924. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15075924

AMA Style

Tu C, Shi Y. Market-Incentive Environmental Regulation and the Quality of Corporate Innovation. Sustainability. 2023; 15(7):5924. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15075924

Chicago/Turabian Style

Tu, Chao, and Yingfang Shi. 2023. "Market-Incentive Environmental Regulation and the Quality of Corporate Innovation" Sustainability 15, no. 7: 5924. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15075924

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop