Next Article in Journal
Solar Energy Resource Analysis and Evaluation of Photovoltaic System Performance in Various Regions of Saudi Arabia
Next Article in Special Issue
Risk Profile Indicators and Spanish Banks’ Probability of Default from a Regulatory Approach
Previous Article in Journal
Hyperspectral Estimation of the Chlorophyll Content in Short-Term and Long-Term Restorations of Mangrove in Quanzhou Bay Estuary, China
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Study of Utility Valuation of Single-Name Credit Derivatives with the Fast-Scale Stochastic Volatility Correction
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Maslow Portfolio Selection for Individuals with Low Financial Sustainability

1
School of Mathematics and Statistics, Xi’an Jiaotong University, Xi’an 710049, China
2
Department of Finance, Fintech Center, and Big Data Research Center, Asia University, Taichung City 413, Taiwan
3
Department of Economics and Finance, Hang Seng Management College, Hong Kong, China
4
Department of Economics, Lingnan University, Hong Kong, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2018, 10(4), 1128; https://doi.org/10.3390/su10041128
Submission received: 18 February 2018 / Revised: 22 March 2018 / Accepted: 27 March 2018 / Published: 9 April 2018
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Risk Measures with Applications in Finance and Economics)

Abstract

:
In this paper, we extend Maslow’s need hierarchy theory and the two-level optimization approach by developing the framework of the Maslow portfolio selection model (MPSM) by solving the two optimization problems to meet the need of individuals with low financial sustainability who prefer to satisfy their lower-level (safety) need first, and, thereafter, look for higher-level (self-actualization) need to maximize the optimal return. We illustrate our proposed model with real American stock data from the S&P index and conduct the out-of-sample analysis to compare the performance of our proposed Variance-CVaR (conditional value-at-risk) MPSM with both traditional mean-variance and mean-CVaR models. Our empirical analysis shows that our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSM is not only sustainable, but also obtains the best out-of-sample performance in the sense that the optimal portfolios obtained by using our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSM obtain the highest cumulative returns in the out-of-sample period among the models used in our paper. We note that our proposed model is not only suitable to individuals with low financial sustainability, but also suitable to institutions or investors with high financial sustainability.

1. Introduction

There is an increasing number of organizations, especially governments, who take financial sustainability into account. Traditionally, financial sustainability can be defined as the ability of government to finance the provision of public services at present without compromising the ability to do so in the future [1,2,3]. In the latest decade, empirical research has been conducted on the financial sustainability of Microfinance institutions [4,5,6]. Nurmakhanova et al. [7] claim that sustainable Microfinance institutions are the ones that operate profitably and do not require subsidies to succeed. They show that focusing on financial sustainability does not necessarily hurt the depth and breadth of outreach (social mission).
However, financial sustainability is ignored by conventional portfolio selection models. The mean-risk model is the most widely used framework in the portfolio selection. In the pioneer work of the mean-variance (MV) model, Markowitz [8] uses the variance of a portfolio return as risk function. As a measure of dispersion about the expected mean, variance is desirable risk measure for investors to evaluate their risk, especially for individuals with low financial sustainability. However, variance has a serious shortcoming that it equally penalizes returns on both sides of the distribution, limiting its application to jointly elliptical distributions [9]. To circumvent the limitation, Artzner et al. [10] introduce the coherent risk measure via an axiomatic method and discuss that a good risk measure should satisfy monotonicity, translation invariance, positive homogeneity, and subadditivity.
Recently, the seemingly large daily price movements in high-tech stocks have further generated investigation into the market risk. Extreme price movements in the financial markets are rare, but extraordinarily important for investors and financial institutions with both high and low financial sustainability. Value-at-Risk (VaR) [11] is one well-known tool to take care of the left tails of distributions (extremely unfavorable outcomes). Nonetheless, VaR is not a coherent risk measure. To overcome this limitation, conditional VaR (CVaR) becomes popular because CVaR possesses some attractive theoretical properties including being coherent, consistent with second-order stochastic dominance [12], and easy to operate [13]. Dobrovolskiene and Tamosiuniene [14] develop a sustainability-oriented model of financial resource allocation in a project portfolio by integrating a composite sustainability index of a project into Markowitz’s classical mean-variance model.
Investors could consider different kinds of risk in the portfolio selection according to different sustainability. This idea is consistent with the need hierarchy theory proposed in [15]. De Brouwer [16] offers an alternative formulation of the behavioural portfolio theory via the theory of needs, and Colson et al. [17] develop the approach for the two-level optimization estimation. In this paper, we extend their theories by developing the framework of the Maslow portfolio selection model (MPSM) and solving the two optimization problems to meet the need of individuals with low financial sustainability who prefer to satisfy their lower-level (safety) need first, and thereafter, look for higher-level (self-actualization) need to maximize the optimal return. In addition, we develop a special MPSM call Variance-CVaR MPSM.
In order to check whether our proposed model is superior to the traditional MV model in [8] and the mean-CVaR (M-CVaR) model in [13], we illustrate our proposed model with real American stock data from the S&P index and conduct the out-of-sample analysis to compare the performance of our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSM with both MV and M-CVaR models. Our empirical analysis shows that our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSM is not only sustainable, but also obtains the best out-of-sample performance in the sense that the optimal portfolios obtained by using our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSM obtain the highest cumulative returns in the out-of-sample period among the models used in our paper.
Our findings support our conjecture that individuals with low financial sustainability who prefer to satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs first, and, thereafter, look for higher-level (self-actualization) needs do prefer our proposed models to both MV and M-CVaR models. We also find that institutions or investors with high financial sustainability who prefer to look for higher-level (self-actualization) needs first, and, thereafter, satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs also prefer our proposed models to both MV and M-CVaR models in our illustration.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we do a quick review on the coherent risk measure. The Variance-Coherent Maslow portfolio selection model are proposed in Section 3. Empirical study on the American stock market is carried out in Section 4. Section 5 draws inferences and conclusions from the findings in this paper.

2. Coherent Risk Measures

Artzner et al. [10] define the coherent risk measure as follows:
Definition 1.
A risk measure ρ : L R is called coherent if it satisfies the following four axioms:
1. 
Monotonicity: for all X , Y L with X Y , ρ ( Y ) ρ ( X ) ;
2. 
Translation invariance: for all X L and α R , ρ ( X + α ) = ρ ( X ) α ;
3. 
Positive homogeneity: for all X L and λ 0 , ρ ( λ X ) = λ ρ ( X ) ; and
4. 
Subadditivity: for all X , Y L , ρ ( X + Y ) ρ ( X ) + ρ ( Y ) .
Applying the Separation Theorem for convex sets, we obtain the following general representation for all coherent risk measures in “generalized scenarios”:
Proposition 1.
A risk measure ρ : L R is called coherent if and only if there exists a family P of probability measures on the set of states of nature such that
ρ ( X ) = sup P P E P ( X ) .
Using Definition 1 for the coherent risk measure, some specific risk measures have been proposed [18,19]. One of the popular measures is the conditional value-at-risk (CVaR) developed in [13,20]. To be specific, for any α ( 0 , 1 ] , we have
C V a R α ( X ) = inf t R { t + 1 1 α E [ X t ] + } .
This coherent risk measure not only has a clear interpretation, but also obtains some good properties. For example, the ranking of assets by using the mean return and CVaR is equivalent to that by using the second-order stochastic dominance [12]. Furthermore, CVaR is the best convex approximation to VaR [21]. In this paper, in order to describe investors’ subjective risk preference better, we propose to use the spectral risk measure, which is defined as follows:
Definition 2.
A spectral risk measure ρ ϕ : L R is defined as
ρ ϕ ( X ) = 0 1 ϕ ( p ) F X 1 ( p ) d p ,
in which ϕ : [ 0 , 1 ] [ 0 , 1 ] is called a spectral function satisfying
1. 
ϕ ( p ) 0 for all p ( 0 , 1 ] ;
2. 
ϕ ( p 1 ) ϕ ( p 2 ) for all p 1 , p 2 ( 0 , 1 ] with p 1 < p 2 ; and
3. 
0 1 ϕ ( p ) d p = 1 .

3. Variance-Coherent Maslow Portfolio Selection Model

In this section, we first recall the framework of the Maslow portfolio selection model, and, thereafter, set the specific model with coherent risk measures. Assume that there are n risky assets S = ( s 1 , ; s n ) whose random returns are denoted by R = ( R 1 , ; R n ) with mean μ = ( μ 1 , ; μ n ) and covariance matrix Σ = ( σ i j ) n × n . Denote the portfolio held by an investor as x = ( x 1 , ; x n ) with i = 1 n x i = 1 , and the random return rate of her/his portfolio is i = 1 n R i x i with mean i = 1 n μ i x i and variance x Σ x .

3.1. Framework of MPSM

According to the hierarchy theory proposed in [15], the safety and self-actualization needed are closely related to investment activity such that investors would like to ensure the safety of their initial wealth first, and, thereafter, gain as much profit as possible. Maslow suggests that the safety needs (lower-level needs) must be fulfilled before the individuals desire for self-actualization needs (higher-level needs). This hierarchy can be modelled by using the two-level optimization in [17], in which one optimization problem is embedded within another optimization problem.
In this paper, we extend the theory developed in [15] and the two-level optimization approach developed in [17] to obtain the framework of MPSM by solving the following two optimization problems to meet the need of individuals with low financial sustainability who prefer to satisfy their lower-level (safety) need first, and, thereafter, look for higher-level (self-actualization) need:
upper-level : max i = 1 n μ i x i ,
s . t . r u ( x ) L ,
r l ( x ) f * + δ ,
i = 1 n x i = 1 ,
x i 0 , i = 1 , , n ,
where f * is the optimal value obtained from solving the following optimization problem:
lower-level : min r l ( y ) ,
s . t . i = 1 n μ i y i G ,
i = 1 n y i = 1 ,
y i 0 , i = 1 , , n .
Here, two risk measures, r l ( x ) and r u ( x ) , depend on portfolio composition x and describe the risks corresponding to the lower-level (safety) needs and higher-level (self-actualization) needs, and the two preset parameters, G and L, are the minimum return and maximum loss investors could accept, respectively. Short-selling is restricted in the MPSM to stabilize the portfolio problem [22].
Constraint (6) links the lower-level (safety) needs to the higher-level (self-actualization) needs by f * . δ is viewed as a tolerance parameter for the safety requirement. The greater the δ , the lower the requirement for safety. Constraint (6) is designed to fit the needs of individuals with low financial sustainability who prefer to satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs first, and thereafter, look for higher-level (self-actualization) needs.
Remark 1.
The two-level optimization problem stated in (4)–(12) can be viewed as the δ constraint method for solving bi-objective programming [23].
Remark 2.
Since Equations in (4)–(12) do not give any restriction on the forms of both r l ( x ) and r u ( x ) , investors have all the freedom and flexibility to construct different MPSMs.

3.2. Variance-Coherent MPSM

Since our proposed model allows investors to have all the freedom and flexibility to construct different MPSMs, in this section, we propose the following particular MPSM: when setting r l ( x ) and r u ( x ) as variance and coherent risk measures, respectively, we obtain the concrete portfolio selection model, which is called Variance-Coherent MPSM under the framework of MPSM as stated in the following:
higher-level : max i = 1 n μ i x i ,
s . t . ρ ( x ) L ,
x Σ x f * + δ ,
i = 1 n x i = 1 ,
x i 0 , i = 1 , , n ,
where f * is the optimal value obtained from solving the following optimization problem:
lower-level : min y Σ y ,
s . t . i = 1 n μ i y i G ,
i = 1 n y i = 1 ,
y i 0 , i = 1 , , n .
There are several reasons we set the two risk functions in the above. Firstly, when pursuing higher-level needs, investors would like to use more advanced risk control methods or financial instruments as shown from Equations (13) to (17). Secondly, variance and coherent risk measures are good alternatives for investors to meet different levels of needs. On one hand, variance measures the overall volatility, and, thus, it helps to ensure the safety of the initial wealth. On the other hand, coherent risk measures depict the tail risks so as to provide investors more chance to obtain high payoffs. Thirdly, from the viewpoint of empirical comparability, setting r l ( x ) and r u ( x ) as variance and coherent risk measures makes it easier for academics and practitioners to compare our proposed model with the classical models in [8,13] through empirical analyses since they are closely related. To some extent, this chronological order provides us a criterion for choosing risk functions corresponding to different levels of needs.

4. Empirical Analyses

To illustrate the effectiveness of our proposed model stated in Equations (13)–(21) of Section 3.2, we investigate the superiority of using our proposed Variance-Coherent MPSM empirically. Here, we take the coherent risk measure as CVaR; that is to say, the spectral function is taken as ϕ ( p ) = 1 1 α 1 { 0 p 1 α } . This investigation is based on the historical data of stocks from all components of the S&P 500 Index in the American stock market.
For comparison purposes, we also analyse the performance of a few other closely related models, including the classical MV and M-CVaR models in [8,13]. In essence, they depict both investors’ safety needs and self-actualization needs. For convenience, we use “MV”, “M-CVaR”, “Maslow (0.008)”, and “Maslow (0.010)” to stand for the optimal portfolios obtained under the classical MV model, M-CVaR model and our proposed model (13)–(21) with δ = 0.008 and δ = 0.010 , respectively.

4.1. Data

To ensure decentralization, we choose 30 stocks classified into different industries from the components of the S&P 500 Index. The stocks shown in Table 1 are chosen because they have either the 30 highest market capitalizations or the 30 largest trading volumes, and, thus, they are the leading stocks in the corresponding industries.
Historical weekly returns of the aforementioned 30 stocks in six years, from 6 October 2011 to 5 October 2017, are downloaded from the Yahoo Finance (http://finance.yahoo.com/) to form the data set. Moreover, the data from 6 October 2011 to October 5 2016 are used to obtain the optimal portfolios, and the remaining data are used for evaluating the out-of-sample performance.

4.2. The Characteristics of the Optimal Portfolios

In this section, we look into the characteristics of the optimal portfolios obtained by using different portfolio selection models. In this experiment, we set α = 0.95 . According to the features of historical data, we set G = 0.001 and L = 0.05 . The optimal portfolios under the Variance-CVaR MPSM are obtained by following the steps described in Section 3. We summarize the characteristics of individual stocks in Table 2, including the sample mean and risk (variance and CVaR 0.95 ).
One can easily observe from the fifth column of Table 2 that the optimal portfolios obtained under the MV (safety needs) model are of the most diversification while the optimal portfolios displayed in the last column that are obtained under the M-CVaR (self-actualization needs) model are of the most concentration because there is only one asset in each portfolio under this category. Nonetheless, the optimal portfolios corresponding to our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSM (13)–(21) strike a balance between the most diversification and the most concentration that the optimal portfolios are diversified but not the most diversified and not the most concentrated. In addition, with the increase of the tolerance parameter δ for the safety requirement, the optimal portfolio derived from our proposed model becomes more concentrated.
All the above empirical results are in agreement with the motivations of the portfolio selection models. The well-diversified portfolios are robust with respect to the collapse of any stock, and, thus, being safe to some extent. The concentrated portfolios (Column 8) including only stocks with the largest means gain the higher returns during the formation period. The compromising portfolios derived from our new Variance-CVaR MPSM not only contain the assets with larger means to get higher returns at one hand, but also allocate the wealth to several other stocks to enhance the diversification and robustness of the portfolios on the other hand.

4.3. Out-of-Sample Performance

During the formation period, one could conclude that the optimal portfolios obtained under the MV (safety needs) model are of the most diversification while the optimal portfolios obtained under the M-CVaR (self-actualization needs) model are of the most concentration. However, the optimal portfolios obtained from our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSMs are neither of the most diversification nor of the most concentration. Could this be used to infer that the performance of our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSMs is not good? We say that this is not true. Whether the performance of the optimal portfolios is good or not does not depend on their performance of the portfolios in the formation period (since one cannot make any cent from the formation period) but depends on their performance on the testing period (that one can make profit in the testing period). This argument is consistent with DeMiguel et al. [24], who suggest that the out-of-sample performance is one of the most optimal ways to compare different investment strategies.
Thus, in this section, we carry out the out-of-sample analysis to evaluate the practical usefulness of different portfolio selection models. To do so, we investigate the payoffs of different optimal portfolios by using their cumulative returns and exhibit the results in Figure 1, which enable us to examine the evolution of the actual out-of-sample returns over time. Obviously, for a given time, the higher the cumulative return, the better the optimal portfolio or the corresponding portfolio selection model.
From Figure 1, one can tell that the cumulative returns of the safety strategy are always the lowest. On the other hand, the out-of-sample performance of the “most promising” strategy (M-CVaR) is barely satisfactory because this strategy suffers from the maximum losses at the very beginning, and thus, obtains the minimum gains during the final period. Nonetheless, the two optimal portfolios determined by our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSM outperform the two strategies above significantly, which can be easily observed from the curves in Figure 1 corresponding to Maslow (0.008) and Maslow (0.010). This shows that our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSM is not only sustainable, but also obtains the best performance among the four models in our analysis.

4.4. Further Discussion on the Results and Methods

To examine whether our proposed model outperforms the most commonly-used classical MV (safety needs) model developed in [8] and the M-CVaR (self-actualization needs) model developed in [13], we illustrate our proposed model with real American stock data from the S&P index and conduct the out-of-sample analysis to compare the performance of our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSM with both MV and M-CVaR models. Our empirical analysis shows that our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSM is not only sustainable, but also obtains the best out-of-sample performance in the sense that the optimal portfolios obtained by using our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSM obtain the highest cumulative returns in the out-of-sample period among the models used in our paper.
We note that our proposed model is mainly designed for individuals with low financial sustainability who prefer to satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs first, and, thereafter, look for higher-level (self-actualization) needs. One may believe that our proposed model is not suitable for investors with high financial sustainability. We argue that this is not true. Firstly, there are still some institutions or investors with high financial sustainability who still prefer to satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs first, and, thereafter, look for higher-level (self-actualization) needs. Our models are still suitable for these types of institutions or investors with high financial sustainability. Secondly, even for institutions or investors with high financial sustainability who prefer to look for higher-level (self-actualization) needs first, and, thereafter, satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs, our proposed models could still be suitable for them because our empirical study does find that our proposed Variance-CVaR MPSM obtains the highest cumulative returns in the out-of-sample period among the models used in our paper. Thus, we can claim that our proposed model is not only suitable for institutions or investors with high financial sustainability who still prefer to satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs first, and, thereafter, look for higher-level (self-actualization) needs, but is also suitable for institutions or investors with high financial sustainability who prefer to look for higher-level (self-actualization) needs first, and thereafter, satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs.
Nonetheless, our proposed model is designed for individuals with low financial sustainability who prefer to satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs first, and, thereafter, look for higher-level (self-actualization) needs, not for institutions or investors with high financial sustainability who prefer to look for higher-level (self-actualization) needs first, and, thereafter, satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs. One could easily modify our proposed model to obtain the model suitable for institutions or investors with high financial sustainability who prefer to look for higher-level (self-actualization) needs first, and, thereafter, satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs.
Many studies, for example, Michaud [25], have found the traditional estimation of the MV-optimized model in [8] does more harm than good for high dimensional big data. To circumvent the limitation, Bai et al. [26] develop the bootstrap-corrected estimation that could analytically circumvent the limitation and is proportionally consistent with the theoretical return parameter. Leung et al. [27] derive explicit formulas for the estimator of the optimal portfolio return. Bai et al. [28] prove that the traditional estimate for the optimal return of self-financing portfolios always over-estimates from its theoretic value. To circumvent the problem, they develop a bootstrap estimate for the optimal return of self-financing portfolios and prove that this estimate is consistent with its counterpart parameter. Bai et al. [28] further develop the spectrally-corrected estimation to improve the estimation further. Extension of our paper could incorporate both the MPSM approach developed in our paper and the bootstrap-corrected estimation or the spectrally-corrected estimation to meet the needs of individuals with low financial sustainability who prefer to satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs first, and, thereafter, look for higher-level (self-actualization) need for high-dimensional big data.
Investigating whether international diversification and home bias inertia are substitutes or complements for Americans, Abid et al. [29,30] conclude that the US investors have a ‘home bias’ if they prefer less risk and to be ’internationally diversified’ if they prefer higher risk. Hoang et al. [31] conclude that gold is good for the diversification of stock portfolios but not for bond portfolios in the Paris gold market. On the other hand, studying the role of gold quoted on the Shanghai Gold Exchange in the diversification of Chinese portfolios, Hoang et al. [32] show that, in general, risk-averse investors prefer not to include gold while risk-seeking investors prefer to include it in their stock-bond portfolios, especially in crisis periods. They also find that risk-seekers prefer including gold in an equal-weighted portfolio while risk-averters prefer including gold in efficient portfolios. Studying the performance in the Hong Kong residential property market, Qiao and Wong [33] conclude that risk averters prefer to invest in smaller property while Tsang et al. [34] conclude that, regardless of whether the buyers eschew risk, embrace risk or are indifferent to it, they prefer to invest in smaller property. On the other hand, to study the performance of a portfolio of US/UK equities, bonds, gold, and housing, Bouri et al. [35] conclude that wine is the best investment among all individual assets under their study, and, in general, investors prefer to invest in with-wine portfolios than without-wine portfolios to gain higher expected utility. It will be interesting to readdress all the above issues and other important issues in finance and economics by using the theory developed in our paper, in order to check whether investors’ preferences change when they adopt our proposed model.

5. Conclusions

In this paper, we extend the need hierarchy theory developed in [15] and the two-level optimization approach developed by Colson et al. in [17] to obtain the framework of the Maslow portfolio selection (Variance-CVaR MPSM) model by solving the two optimization problems to meet the need of individuals with low financial sustainability who prefer to satisfy their lower-level (safety) needs first, and, thereafter, look for higher-level (self-actualization) needs. Investors with low financial sustainability pay more attention to the safety of their financial investment. Investors are more concerned about the basic or lower level needing to be satisfied first, and, thereafter, care about their upper level needs to gain a higher return. In particular, investors like to use diversified strategy to obtain an efficient instrument to manage risk so that they could make the risk level affordable. To do so, we first solve the optimization problem to minimize the risk first, and, thereafter, solve the optimization problem to maximize the optimal return.
Further study includes the extension of our new portfolio selection model to the multi-period case because investors tend to adjust their investment strategies with the emergence of new information, especially for the investors with strong financial sustainability to adopt long-term investment. In this paper, we use variance or CVaR as risk. Extensions could use other risk measures to represent risk, including the Sharpe Ratio in [36], mixed Sharpe ratio in [37], mean-variance-ratio in [38], Omega ratio in [39], Kappa Ratios in [40], and Farinelli and Tibiletti ratio in [41] to represent risk.

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Professor Zhidong Bai and Professor Zhiping Chen for their guidance. The fourth author would also like to thank Robert B. Miller and Howard E. Thompson for their continuous guidance and encouragement. The research is partially supported by Xi’an Jiaotong University, Asia University, China Medical University Hospital, Hang Seng Management College, Lingnan University, the National Science Foundation of China (11401461 and 11690011), the Ministry of Science and Technology of China (2015DFA81780), the Research Grants Council (RGC) of Hong Kong (projects No. 12500915), and the Ministry of Science and Technology (MOST), R.O.C.

Author Contributions

Formal analysis: Zongxin Li, Xinge Li, Yongchang Hui, Wing-Keung Wong; Methodology: Zongxin Li, Yongchang Hui; Project administration: Yongchang Hui, Wing-Keung Wong; Software: Zongxin Li, Xinge Li; Writing-original draft: Zongxin Li, Xinge Li, Yongchang Hui, Wing-Keung Wong; Writing-review and editing: Zongxin Li, Xinge Li, Yongchang Hui, Wing-Keung Wong.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Canadian Institute of Chartered Accountants (CICA). Indicators of Government Financial Condition; CICA: Toronto, ON, Canada, 1997. [Google Scholar]
  2. Bath, P. Resource for Success Series, 2nd ed.; USA Nature Conservancy Arlington: Arlington, VA, USA, 2001. [Google Scholar]
  3. Stavins, R.; Wagner, A.; Wagner, G. Interpreting sustainability in economic terms: Dynamic efficiency plus intergenerational equity. Econ. Lett. 2003, 79, 339–343. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Crombrugghe, A.; Tenikue, M.; Sureda, J. Performance analysis for a sample of microfinance institutions in India. Ann. Public Cooper. Econ. 2008, 79, 269–299. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Cull, R.; Demirguc-Kunt, A.; Morduch, J. Does microfinance regulation curtail profitability and outreach? World Dev. 2011, 39, 949–965. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Hermes, N.; Lensink, R.; Meesters, A. Outreach and efficiency of microfinance institutions. World Dev. 2011, 39, 938–948. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Nurmakhanova, M.; Kretzschmar, G.; Fedhila, H. Trade-off between financial sustainability and outreach of microfinance institutions. Eurasian Econ. Rev. 2015, 5, 231–250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Markowitz, H.M. Portfolio selection. J. Financ. 1952, 7, 77–91. [Google Scholar]
  9. Szego, G. Measures of risk. J. Bank. Financ. 2002, 26, 1253–1272. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Artzner, P.; Delbaen, F.J.; Eber, M.; Health, D. Coherent measures of risk. Math. Financ. 1999, 9, 203–228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Morgan, J.P. Risk Metrics Technical Document, 4th ed.; Morgan Guaranty Trust Company: New York, NY, USA, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  12. Ma, C.; Wong, W.K. Stochastic dominance and risk measure: A decision-theoretic foundation for VaR and C-VaR. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2010, 207, 927–935. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Rockafellar, R.T.; Uryasev, S. Conditional value-at-risk for general loss distributions. J. Bank. Financ. 2002, 26, 1443–1471. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Dobrovolskiene, N.; Tamosiuniene, R. Sustainability-oriented financial resource allocation in a project portfolio through multi-criteria decision-making. Sustainability 2016, 8, 485. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Maslow, A.H. A theory of human motivation. Psychol. Rev. 1943, 50, 370–396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. De Brouwer, P.J.S. Maslowian portfolio theory: An alternative formulation of the behavioural portfolio theory. J. Asset Manag. 2009, 9, 359–365. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Colson, B.; Marcotte, P.; Savard, G. An overview of two-level optimization. Ann. Oper. Res. 2007, 59, 617–630. [Google Scholar]
  18. Acerbi, A.; Tasche, D. On the coherence of expected shortfall. J. Bank. Financ. 2002, 26, 1487–1503. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Chen, Z.; Hu, Q. On coherent risk measures induced by convex risk measures. Methodol. Comput. Appl. Probab. 2017, 1, 1–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Rockafellar, R.T.; Uryasev, S. Optimization of conditional value-at-risk. J. Risk 2000, 2, 21–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Chen, W.; Sim, M.; Sun, J.; Teo, C.P. From CVaR to uncertainty set: Implications in joint chance-constrained optimization. Oper. Res. 2010, 58, 470–485. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Frost, P.A.; Savarino, J.E. For better performance, constraint portfolio weights. J. Portf. Manag. 1988, 15, 29–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Li, D.; Yang, J.B.; Biswal, M.P. Quantitative parametric connections between methods for generating noninferior solutions in multiobjective optimization. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 1999, 117, 84–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. DeMiguel, V.; Garlappi, L.; Uppal, R. Optimal versus naive diversification: How inefficient is the 1/N portfolio strategy? Rev. Financ. Stud. 2009, 22, 1915–1953. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Michaud, R.O. The Markowitz optimization enigma: Is ‘optimized’ optimal? Financ. Anal. J. 1989, 45, 31–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Bai, Z.D.; Lui, H.X.; Wong, W.K. Enhancement of the applicability of markowitz’s portfolio optimization by utilizing random matrix theory. Math. Financ. 2009, 19, 639–667. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Leung, P.L.; Ng, H.Y.; Wong, W.K. An improved estimation to make markowitz’s portfolio optimization theory users friendly and estimation accurate with application on the US stock market investment. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2012, 222, 85–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Bai, Z.D.; Lui, H.X.; Wong, W.K. On the markowitz mean-variance analysis of self-financing portfolios. Risk Decis. Anal. 2009, 1, 35–42. [Google Scholar]
  29. Abid, F.; Mroua, M.; Wong, W.K. Should americans invest internationally? The mean-variance portfolios optimization and stochastic dominance approaches. Risk Decis. Anal. 2013, 4, 89–102. [Google Scholar]
  30. Abid, F.; Leung, P.L.; Mroua, M.; Wong, W.K. International Diversification versus Domestic diversification: Mean-variance portfolio optimization and stochastic dominance approaches. J. Risk Financ. Manag. 2014, 7, 45–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Hoang, T.H.V.; Lean, H.H.; Wong, W.K. Is gold good for portfolio diversification? A stochastic dominance analysis of the Paris stock exchange. Int. Rev. Financ. Anal. 2015, 42, 98–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Hoang, T.H.V.; Wong, W.K.; Zhu, Z.Z. Is gold different for risk-averse and risk-seeking investors? An empirical analysis of the Shanghai Gold Exchange. Econ. Model. 2015, 50, 200–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Qiao, Z.; Wong, W.K. Which is a better investment choice in the Hong Kong residential property market: A big or small property? Appl. Econ. 2015, 47, 1670–1685. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Tsang, C.K.; Wong, W.K.; Horowitz, I. Arbitrage opportunities, efficiency, and the role of risk preferences in the Hong Kong property market. Stud. Econ. Financ. 2016, 33, 735–754. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Bouri, E.; Gupta, R.; Wong, W.K.; Zhu, Z.Z. Is wine a good choice for investment? Pac. Basin Finance J. 2018, in press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Leung, P.L.; Wong, W.K. On testing the equality of the multiple Sharpe Ratios, with application on the evaluation of iShares. J. Risk 2008, 10, 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Wong, W.K.; Wright, J.A.; Yam, S.C.P.; Yung, S.P. A mixed sharpe ratio. Risk Decis. Anal. 2012, 3, 37–65. [Google Scholar]
  38. Bai, Z.D.; Hui, Y.C.; Wong, W.K.; Zitikis, R. Evaluating prospect performance: Making a case for a non-asymptotic UMPU test. J. Financ. Econ. 2012, 10, 703–732. [Google Scholar]
  39. Guo, X.; Jiang, X.J.; Wong, W.K. Stochastic dominance and omega ratio: Measures to examine market efficiency, arbitrage opportunity, and anomaly. Economies 2017, 5, 38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Niu, C.Z.; Wong, W.K.; Xu, Q.F. Kappa ratios and (higher-order) stochastic dominance. Risk Manag. 2017, 19, 245–253. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Niu, C.Z.; Wong, W.K.; Zhu, L.X. Farinelli and Tibiletti Ratio and Stochastic Dominance; MPRA Paper No. 82737; University Library of Munich: Munich, Germany, 2017. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. The cumulative return rates of the optimal portfolios got under different portfolio selection models. Note: MV, M-CVaR, Maslow (0.008) and Maslow (0.010) stand for the optimal portfolios obtained under the MV model, M-CVaR model, as well as our proposed model (13)–(21) with δ = 0.008 and δ = 0.010 , respectively.
Figure 1. The cumulative return rates of the optimal portfolios got under different portfolio selection models. Note: MV, M-CVaR, Maslow (0.008) and Maslow (0.010) stand for the optimal portfolios obtained under the MV model, M-CVaR model, as well as our proposed model (13)–(21) with δ = 0.008 and δ = 0.010 , respectively.
Sustainability 10 01128 g001
Table 1. Stock pool (in alphabetical order).
Table 1. Stock pool (in alphabetical order).
No.NameNo.NameNo.Name
1AAPL11DUK21MCD
2AEP12F22MDT
3AIG13FDX23MSFT
4AMGN14GE24NKE
5AXP15HD25PG
6BA16HON26SLB
7BAC17INTC27T
8CAT18JNJ28UNH
9CMCSA19JPM29WMT
10CVX20KO30XOM
Note: These 30 stocks are numbered in alphabetical order. They are the leading ones in their corresponding industries. The time period is from 6 October 2011 to 5 October 2017.
Table 2. The characteristics of the stocks and the optimal portfolios under different models.
Table 2. The characteristics of the stocks and the optimal portfolios under different models.
No.MeanVarianceCVaR0.95MVMaslow (0.008)Maslow (0.010)M-CVaR
10.004040.001510.079370.04441000
20.002920.000500.045680000
30.004780.001200.071030000
40.005060.000980.0557700.0396800
50.002030.000810.064500.01195000
60.003900.000920.063740000
70.004930.001860.084230000
80.001780.001230.070270000
90.004970.000720.0469000.186950.094000
100.001460.000890.062050000
110.002040.000450.045900.20159000
120.001840.001310.072790000
130.003990.000930.060510000
140.003270.000760.053180000
150.005850.000670.0474700.595550.813971.00000
160.004060.000670.051450000
170.003170.000950.067520000
180.003190.000330.035770.16204000
190.004140.001090.071210000
200.001700.000440.044020000
210.001830.000410.044450.17576000
220.004400.000540.044560.03585000
230.004090.001040.072100000
240.003980.000870.058990000
250.002110.000370.042060.14469000
260.002050.001300.074100000
270.002440.000460.042810.07682000
280.004960.000760.054130.039140.177830.092030
290.001710.000550.054340.09760000
300.001470.000570.052890.01016000
Note: MV, M-CVaR, Maslow (0.008), and Maslow (0.010) stand for the optimal portfolios obtained under the MV model, M-CVaR model, and as our proposed model (13)–(21) with δ = 0.008 and δ = 0.010 , respectively.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Li, Z.; Li, X.; Hui, Y.; Wong, W.-K. Maslow Portfolio Selection for Individuals with Low Financial Sustainability. Sustainability 2018, 10, 1128. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10041128

AMA Style

Li Z, Li X, Hui Y, Wong W-K. Maslow Portfolio Selection for Individuals with Low Financial Sustainability. Sustainability. 2018; 10(4):1128. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10041128

Chicago/Turabian Style

Li, Zongxin, Xinge Li, Yongchang Hui, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2018. "Maslow Portfolio Selection for Individuals with Low Financial Sustainability" Sustainability 10, no. 4: 1128. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10041128

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop