Next Article in Journal
Complementary Currencies for Humanitarian Aid
Next Article in Special Issue
Dimension Reduction via Penalized GLMs for Non-Gaussian Response: Application to Stock Market Volatility
Previous Article in Journal
Bank Risk Capital and Its Effectiveness in Selected Euro Area Banking Sectors
Previous Article in Special Issue
Predicting Bank Failures: A Synthesis of Literature and Directions for Future Research
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Review

Order Routing Decisions for a Fragmented Market: A Review

Department of Finance, College of Business, Florida International University, Miami, FL 33199, USA
*
Authors to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2021, 14(11), 556; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14110556
Submission received: 30 September 2021 / Revised: 29 October 2021 / Accepted: 11 November 2021 / Published: 17 November 2021

Abstract

:
This paper reviews the up-to-date theoretical, empirical, and experimental literature related to the trading venue choice in the context of the fragmented equity markets. We provide a brief background on the history of trading fragmentation in the equity market and its determinants. We discuss the direct and indirect impacts of the market fragmentation on market quality in various dimensions, including liquidity, volatility, and price efficiency. Next, we identify possible determinants and channels from theoretical and empirical studies that could explain order routing decisions and present the possible directions for future research. Finally, we discuss the major regulatory reforms in the U.S. equity market on routing venue decisions. This topic is relevant in current times when phenomena such as “GameStop Frenzy” have drawn significant attention to commission-free trading venues.

1. Introduction

The evolution of the United States stock exchange started in 1790 with the birth of the Philadelphia stock exchange. After more than 200 years of the evolutionary process, equity trading in the U.S. is currently dispersed across 16 national exchanges, more than thirty alternative trading systems, and numerous broker-dealers and wholesalers (SEC 2021). The market has never had such fragmentation before, and traders nowadays have many options in choosing venue to execute their orders. Each trading venue competes against the other in terms of fee structure and trading protocols. Moreover, strong trading volume growth, technology innovation, and policy initiatives intensify the competition among exchanges. An exchange must adopt ever more advanced trading technology or update pricing models and trading rules to attract more market share. Ultimately, market fragmentation1 has increased. By merging with and acquiring regional exchanges, three groups, namely the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) group, Nasdaq group, and the CBOE Global market, together dominate the trading volume in the U.S. equity market. Meanwhile, the competition is explicitly enforced by the US Regulation National Market System (Reg-NMS) regulatory policy that allows new trading venues. Newly launched exchanges, such as the Investor Exchange in 2016, Members Exchange (MEMX), Miami International Securities Pearl Exchange (MIAX), and Long-Term Stock Exchange (LTSE) in 2020, foster diversity through innovation in pricing features.
Market fragmentation impacts the investor and market as well. On the one hand, intensified competition lowers transaction fees and ultimately benefits market participants. On the other hand, varying levels of venue transparency and the heterogeneity in transaction speeds change information asymmetry among investors, thus raising adverse selection concerns. Especially, the recent increase in retail trading gamification phenomena such as “Game Stop” has drawn significant attention to commission-free trading brokers and the payment for order flow (PFOF) practice by market makers in off-exchanges. Therefore, examining the routing order decision is extremely relevant in the current time and is worth exploring.
In this paper, we concentrate on the portion of the microstructure literature that addresses order flow fragmentation, specifically, order routing decisions2. We provide an up-to-date survey of the main theoretical developments and empirical studies of the determinants of venue routing choice. We also identify several promising directions for future research.
The routing decision is directly affected by the market design, which decides the venue’s pricing structure, levels of transparency, and execution quality. We document the changes in the studies from examining features of call vs. continuous markets to limit order vs. hybrid market. Remarkably, studies such as Venkataraman (2001) and Brogaard et al. (2021) highlight the role of human intermediates and show that floor trading service by humans is irreplaceable because of their expertise. The experience that floor-traders have allows them to deal with highly complex issues related to liquidity provision situations more efficiently than an algorithm. Therefore, human floor trading service ultimately improves market quality by narrowing the spreads and decreasing pricing errors. Moreover, the routing venue decision involves the trade-offs among transaction cost, execution risk, and adverse selection risk. In fact, types of traders matter as well in terms of the trade-off. Informed traders are concerned more with the trade-off between cost and execution risk as they already have the profitable private information, while uninformed traders focus more on the trade-off between the cost and adverse selection risk. Meanwhile, the routing venue decision is also influenced by technology. The nano-second response speed allows high-frequency traders to quickly react to new information and send orders across venues to harvest the information arbitrage profit. At the same time, exchanges must continually invest in low-latency technology, including co-location, to attract order flow.
In the end, we discuss the major regulatory reforms in the U.S. equity market that impact the market trading environment and the routing venue decision. Overall, the routing venue decision shapes the direction of the exchanges’ evolution and the policy attention, and the changes in the exchanges’ design and policy reforms again alter the routing venue decision.
The rest of the survey is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the development of U.S. trading venues and the consequences of increased fragmentation and venue competition. Section 3 describes the possible determinants and channels that could explain the order routing choice. Section 4 reviews the impact of policy reforms on the routing decision, and Section 5 concludes.

2. Market Fragmentation

This section briefly shows the evolution of U.S. equity exchanges and discusses the related theoretical and empirical literature that focus on the impact of market fragmentation and venue competition. First, we show that the development of the U.S. trading venues results in a highly fragmented market. Next, we review related studies on market fragmentation and show that fragmented market changes venue competition and market quality such as liquidity and volatility.

2.1. The Evolution of U.S. Equity Trading Venues

The modern U.S. equity market has been evolving from floor trading by brokers who read the ticker tape and bid on offer to purely electric trading coded into computer algorithms. Table 1 presents the timeline in the evolution of U.S. equity national exchanges. Notably, the electronic communications network (ECN) was developed in the 1990s to allow direct-matched trading between buyer and seller without an intermediary. The big ECNs, such as Archipelago and Instinet, started gaining popularity as alternative trading systems.
Market participants benefit from the evolution of the technology. First, the stock trading process became much easier with the proliferation of the internet and personal computer. Second, the reduction in the brokerage commission due to enhanced competition also incentivized traders to participate in the equities market. Figure 1 shows the changes in total equities trading volume (in a million shares) in the U.S. market from 2011 to 2021. The average trading volume in the U.S. equities market increased by half, from 160 billion shares per month in 2011 to 250 billion shares per month in 2021.
Moreover, equity trading volume steadily increased by greater participation from retail investors induced by zero brokerage commissions and the widely adopted “working from home” policy under the Coronavirus disease (COVID-19) pandemic. In consequence, the market makers in off-exchange such as Citadel and Virtu gained significant volume share. Figure 2 depicts the change in the market share from 2011 to 2021 in the U.S. equity market. Combined with the increased trading volume shown in Figure 1, it is clearly implicit that the volume in the U.S. equity market has significantly increased in the past ten years, while the markets also have become highly fragmented. Moreover, Figure 2 suggests two trends in terms of fragmentation: first, the competition among exchanges intensified as the number of securities exchanges increased from 13 to 16 within ten years. The merger and acquisition activity has blown in the past ten years, as many regional exchanges such as Boston Stock Exchange (BEX) and Chicago Exchange (CHX) were acquired by the big national exchange groups. In addition, other new independent exchanges, such as the Investors Exchange, MIAX Pearl exchange and Members exchanges, and the Long-Term Stock Exchange, were launched in recent years to increase the competition. Second, the off-exchange trading gained a significant proportion (increased from 30.28% to 44.24%), while the volume share for traditional primary exchanges steadily decreased during the past two years. For example, the market share for NYSE and NASDAQ dropped 3.64% and 2.35%, respectively.

2.2. The Conequences of the Market Fragmentation

The equilibrium in the early theoretical market microstructure studies does not incorporate the multiple venue consideration. Early theoretical studies, such as the multi-markets strategic trading model by Chowdhry and Nanda (1991) and the limit order auction markets model by Glosten (1994), assume that the liquidity supply is competitive. Therefore, combined with the order matching system and large tick size, these models imply that a fragmented market should not affect the quotes. However, many empirical studies in the same period disagreed with the theoretical suggestions. For instance, Easley et al. (1996) and Hasbrouck (1995) observe that different markets obtain significant differences in information contents of order flow, hence arguing that the market fragmentation impacts market quality. Still, the theoretical predictions and empirical findings on market fragmentation are mixed. The conclusions about fragmentation on market quality are diverse and differ according to the factors considered.
The directive consequence of market fragmentation is the intensified competition across trading venues. Several studies suggest that the competition that raised from the fragmentation can improve the market quality by reducing fees, promoting innovation, and hence improving quality (Chao et al. 2017). For example, Macey and O’Hara (1997) suggest that the multi-venues environment allows traders to have a chance to compare the execution quality under each venue, and ultimately the trader could achieve the best execution. Biais et al. (2000) theoretically examine competition among liquidity suppliers and limit order trading in a decentralized market. Their model assumes that market makers are risk-neutral, and the model predicts that the trading volume increases under a high decentralized market. Furthermore, Buti et al. (2017) analyze competition between a limit order book and a dark pool. Their model implies that the introduction of a dark pool increases trading volume. Overall, both Biais et al. (2000) and Buti et al. (2017) predict that the fragmentation could increase overall market volume.
Nevertheless, there is still an ongoing debate on whether market fragmentation improves or harms liquidity. The supporters who discuss the impact of fragmentation on liquidity mainly focus on the competition perspective, given that the fragmented market increase the competition, hence it could push the exchanges to lower their fee, thus promote the liquidity (see the theorical prediction by Colliard and Foucault (2012); Pagnotta and Philippon (2018), and empirical supports by Boehmer and Boehmer (2003); De Fontnouvelle et al. (2003); Nguyen et al. (2007); O’Hara and Ye (2011); Menkveld (2013); He et al. (2015); Foucault and Menkveld (2008)). Conversely, the negative view of the impact of fragmentation on liquidity stresses the information asymmetry perspective. A fragmented market increases adverse selection, hence harms liquidity. The theories were developed by Chowdhry and Nanda (1991) and Dennert (1993) and supported empirical studies can be found in Bessembinder and Kaufman (1997b); Amihud et al. (2003); Hendershott and Jones (2005); and Bennett and Wei (2006). For instance, recent theoretical work by Baldauf and Mollner (2021) examines the market relegation effects by allowing exchanges to adjust the trading fees in responding to competition and adverse selection, and their empirical tests in the Australian market support theoretical predictions that fragmentation increases the arbitrage opportunities, hence increases adverse selection. In addition, a theoretical model by Yin (2005) postulates that increased search costs due to fragmentation decrease competition among liquidity providers and harm liquidity and price discovery.
Alongside the two contradictory views above, several studies argue that the relationship between fragmentation and liquidity should be U-shaped. Degryse et al. (2015) suggest that market fragmentation improves the liquidity in lit-exchanges while harming liquidity in off-exchanges3. Gresse (2017) empirically tests whether positive or negative effects dominate the fragmentation on liquidity. The results show the spreads substantially decrease in both lit fragmentation and dark trading venues after the implementation of MiFID in Europe4, suggesting the benefits from market competition outweigh the negative effect from information asymmetry. Wittwer (2021) studies the welfare effects of connecting the disconnected markets and the model predicts that market fragmentation decreases market depth. Chen and Duffie (2021) extend Wittwer’s model by increasing the number of exchanges in the equilibrium. Chen and Duffie (2021) confirm Wittwer’s (2021) prediction and further show that market fragmentation also alters trader’s strategy to submit a more aggressive order, hence increasing allocative efficiency. Ultimately, overall price informativeness increases.
To sum up, there are exhaustive discussions about the impact of fragmentation on liquidity. However, as suggested by Barardehi et al. (2019), traditional liquidity measures may underestimate the liquidity provision under the current fast-trading environment. Therefore, to better estimate trading cost and understanding the impact of the liquidity under the fragmented market, it is still worthy to compare the liquidity among lit- and off-exchanges by using the new liquidity measures, such as the average per-dollar price impacts of fixed-dollar volume that was proposed by Barardehi et al. (2019).
Alongside liquidity, market volatility by fragmentation is another important dimension that is worth emphasizing. Prices under fragmented markets are more disposed to order imbalances, while increase transitory volatility. The Biais (1993) model conducts theoretical research comparing centralized and fragmented markets and provides two predictions: first, the fragmented markets should increase stock price volatility since the information is fragmented. Second, the spread should be less volatile in fragmented market. Easley et al. (1996) and Bessembinder and Kaufman (1997a) assume heterogeneous information in the model and show that trading fragmentation leads to information fragmentation, which in turn results in higher volatility and wider spreads. Ultimately, both of the works suggest that fragmentation leads to cream-skimming effects and harms markets. In empirical tests, Madhavan (2012) examines the Flash Crash and finds that more fragmented stocks had a more significant negative impact during the Flash Crash in 2010. By contrast, Boneva et al. (2016) empirically tests the effect of fragmentation on volatility for the London Stock Exchange and finds that fragmentation lowers overall volatility. In addition, Boneva et al. (2016) further separates the overall fragmentation into dark trading and visible fragmentation and suggests that the effects of dark trading and visible fragmentation on market quality are different. For further discussion towards venue competition under a fragmented trading environment, readers may refer to a literature survey by Gomber et al. (2017), who review the literature that focus on examining the economic arguments and motivations underlying market fragmentation.

3. The Determinants of the Trading Venue Choice

This section reviews a body of theoretical and empirical studies about possible determinants of the trading venue choice. This overview emphasizes that the trader’s routing choice is influenced by many factors other than simply by transaction cost. Table 2 provides the information on the fee model for U.S. National Exchanges. Table 3 at end of this section summarizes studies on potential determinants of order routing decisions and Appendix A presents market microstructure empirical studies on order routing decisions.
First of all, trading venue choice is fundamentally influenced by the trading system structure (market design) in each exchange. The focus of the studies on the type of the trading system has evolved along with the trading system itself. Early papers on trading system structure mainly compare call markets vs. continuous markets and suggest that the call markets improve the information efficiency of overall market welfare, while continuous markets could be complements for call auction markets. The theoretical discussion can be found in Brennan and Cao (1996) and Vayanos (1999), and empirical studies can be found in Amihud and Mendelson (1991); Neal (1992); Biais et al. (1999); and Corwin and Lipson (2000). With the market innovation through time, the discussion of market design shifts to the limit order market and hybrid market. Some theoretical studies include Foucault (1999); Parlour and Rajan (2003); Foucault et al. (2005); Goettler et al. (2005); Hendershott and Moulton (2011), and the recent work by Budish et al. (2019). Notably, there is an uptrend discussion about the role of human intermediation in market design. For example, Venkataraman (2001) argues that the floor-based market structure with human intermediation (ex. NYSE) has lower execution costs than an automated limit order market. Additionally, Bessembinder and Venkataraman (2004) suggest that a central market (downstairs market) has relatively more information and smaller trades than the dealership market (upstairs trading), and traders strategically choose across markets to minimize the expected execution costs. Brogaard et al. (2021) examine the market quality around the COVID-19 pandemic when NYSE suspended floor trading and show that floor trading improves liquidity and price discovery.
Figure 3 shows the current U.S. equity structure. Based on pre-trade opacity, the trading venues can be separated into lit- and off-exchanges. A lit-exchange refers to an exchange where quote information (bid and ask) are posted publicly. Currently, all U.S. national securities exchanges are lit-exchanges. In contrast, an off-exchange refers to a venue that does not provide price quotation information. Based on pricing structure, lit-exchanges can be further separated into maker–taker, taker–maker and other pricing structure. Maker–taker exchanges can also be referred to as “traditional exchanges”, where the exchange charges fees for traders who take away liquidity (market order) and provides a rebate for traders who provide liquidity (limited order). A taker–maker exchange is also called an “inverted exchange” or “inverted fee exchange”, where exchanges charge fees for traders who provide liquidity and provide a rebate for traders who take away liquidity. Besides maker–taker and taker–maker exchanges, some exchanges, such as the Investors Exchange (IEX), adopt a flat-fee model that charges a fixed fee regardless the type of order.
Alternative Trading System (ATS) is an off-exchange that matches the buyer and seller without going through an intermediary. It includes several types, and the most prevalent one is the Electronic Communication Network (ECN), which pairs the buyer and seller directly by a computer algorithm. A dark pool is a type of ATS that provides anonymity for trading large orders with automated execution. It is generally used by institutional investors. Crossing networks (CNs) are similar to dark pools for large trading. Unlike other venues, where buyer and seller determine price, call markets execute buyer and seller orders at a predetermined price at predetermined time intervals. Alongside ATSs, wholesalers (market makers) can also be broadly included in the off-exchange definition, and they provide liquidity by buying and selling stocks as a counterparty. The Financial Industry Regulatory Authority (FINRA) classifies wholesalers as over-the-counter (OTC) non-ATS dealers.
Overall, different trading system structures provide different degrees of transparency and execution quality. This is associated with different levels of the execution costs5 and investors always seek for maximizing profit with minimized execution costs (Bertsimas and Lo 1998).
In the following subsection, we discuss studies on the trading venue choice and execution costs from three dimensions: direct transaction cost, execution quality cost and adverse selection cost.

3.1. Execution Cost

3.1.1. Transaction Fee

Perhaps the most important determinant for trading venue choice is the direct transaction fee. Intuitively, order routing decisions should be negatively affected by the fee that exchanges charge.
Table 2 demonstrates the fees structure across competing exchanges. Due to competition, exchanges usually modify their pricing on a monthly basis6. The national exchanges in the U.S. are operated under three types of pricing model: (1) the maker–taker (MT) model or traditional model, where the traders pay a certain fee for taking liquidity and getting a rebate for generating liquidity; (2) the taker–maker (TM) model or inverted model, in which offering rebates to the liquidity taker and charging a fee to liquidity maker; and (3) the flat fee model, where traders pay for transactions despite taking or providing liquidity. Angel et al. (2015) point out that in order to maximize profit, brokers strategically send their marketable orders to inverted fee exchanges to gain taker rebates or sell to wholesale dealers to capture the spread and send their limit orders to traditional exchanges to gain maker rebates. Unlike the lit-exchanges, the Alternative Trading System (ATS)7 operator and market makers in off-exchanges operate either by negotiating fees individually with the participants or under the payment for order flow (PFOF) model.
In theoretical development, Colliard and Foucault (2012) propose limit order trading models with a fixed or endogenized fees, and their model predicts that the change in total execution fees should affect trading volume. Foucault et al. (2013) extend the model by differentiating fees between makers and takers. Hendershott and Mendelson (2000) show that dark pools8 obtain a relative cost advantage. Cimon (2021) develop a theoretical model to support the empirical study of broker’s routing incentives by Battalio et al. (2016b) and confirm that brokers’ route order decision is primarily based on the fee, rather than execution quality.
Many empirical studies have tested the effect of the fee schedule on trading activities (Clapham et al. 2021; Comerton-Forde et al. 2018). For example, Cardella et al. (2017) suggest that although the take fee and make fee both reduce trading activities, the magnitudes in reduction are different. Battalio et al. (2016b) examine the fee schedule on broker routing decision and find that brokers have incentives to route the order to the venue which provides the highest rebate. The effect of fee and rebate on liquidity provider incentives on volume is also confirmed in other national markets. For example, Malinova and Park (2015) examine the introduction of the liquidity incentive program (maker-taker fee) on the Toronto Exchange, and Jørgensen et al. (2018) investigate the induction of the fee on Oslo Stock Exchange.

3.1.2. Execution Quality

Alongside direct transaction costs, routing decisions may also be influenced by the execution quality, such as the liquidity, price discovery, spreads, fill rate, execution speed, and order cancellation rate. Many studies compare the execution quality and cost for electronic and traditional exchanges9. Maglaras et al. (2015) focus on investors who queue orders and propose a multiclass queueing model of the limit order book (LOB) to investigate the trading optimization decision. Boehmer et al. (2007) examines the exchanges’ market execution quality report on the trading volume and finds that the exchange with better execution quality (lower cost and higher fill rate) subsequently attracts more order flow. The recent study by Ernst et al. (2021) also reaches the same conclusion by examining the effect of publishing off-exchange trade reports.
Liquidity perhaps is the key component in the execution quality because it directly measures execution risk, and greater liquidity reduces information asymmetry and improves price accuracy (Fox et al. 2019). A low liquidity venue could imply a low probability to execute the order (high execution risk). Many studies suggest the off-exchange with pre-trade opacity should have a relatively higher degree of execution risk than the lit-exchange, which displays the quote information on the order book. Degryse et al. (2009) build a dynamic multi-period model to examine the competition between dealer markets and dark pools and analyze the routing choice for dark pool orders under different transparency requirements. In addition, Degryse et al. (2009) incorporate endogenous liquidity supply and demand in their model, and their model predicts that the order flow depends on the degree of transparency. Biais (1993) incorporates transparency into a one-period inventory model to examine the market performance for fragmented and centralized market structures under the Bertrand price competition assumption. De Frutos and Manzano (2002) extend the Biais (1993) model by lifting the restriction to allow the dealer to be risk-aversion. De Frutos and Manzano (2002) show that the risk-averse dealer has less incentive to compete in a high pre-trade transparency market when the counterparty’s ex-ante quote is available. Overall, both Biais (1993) and De Frutos and Manzano (2002) suggest that the posted quotes reduce uncertainty, and the greater pre-trade transparency may have detrimental effects on liquidity.
In contrast, Pagano and Röell (1996) predict that greater transparency in the market mechanism should enhance the liquidity and lower the trading cost for uninformed traders. The experimental study by Flood et al. (1999) presents a different finding that the reduced search costs by pre-trade transparency reduces uncertainty, thus it facilitates trading, and improves liquidity. Menkveld et al. (2017) suggest that the pre-trade opacity for off-exchanges raises the execution uncertainty. For that reason, lowering pre-trade transparency may result in a higher execution risks when there is a liquidity shock.
Boehmer et al. (2005) empirically study pre-trade transparency by examining the introduction of the NYSE’s OpenBook service, and their results indicate that improvement in pre-trade transparency enhances liquidity. Garvey et al. (2016) find the time-to-execution is much longer in dark venues than in lit venues, and the average fill rate of marketable order executed at dark venues is lower than at lit venues. Thomas et al. (2021) show that dark trading decreases liquidity and increases the post-earnings-announcement drift (PEAD). Battalio et al. (2016a) empirically investigate the trading cost differences between payment for order flow (PFOF) and the maker–taker models in the option markets and suggest that the maker–taker model provides a better unadjusted relative effected spread than the PFOF model. Peterson and Sirri (2003) compare the exchanges execution quality in 1996 within a four-week sample by analyzing the effect of order preferencing. Their results show that NYSE, which was the primary market, obtains better quotation and execution quality for market orders with smaller effective spreads than other regional exchanges. Moreover, Peterson and Sirri (2003) further show that the preferencing regional exchanges have narrow effective spreads and higher execution probability than no preferencing regional exchanges.
Furthermore, Colliard and Foucault (2012) developed a theoretical model, showing that investors may shift their preference to limit orders with less fill rate in response to lower trading cost. Ultimately, the investor can be worse off. He et al. (2006) modeled and empirically examined the impact of internalization procedure (preferencing) on execution quality, and critics that the overall market order execution quality worsens as more uninformed order flow routed and internalized in off-exchanges.

3.1.3. Information Risk (Adverse Selection)

One of the distinguishing features among trading systems is anonymity. Exchanges with anonymity features should be preferred by traders who do not want to publicly disclose their position. For example, institutional investors utilize ATSs to place large size order for preventing information leakage. Theoretical models predict that anonymity attracts more informed orders and thus aggravates the adverse selection problem (Benveniste et al. 1992; Fishman and Longstaff 1992; Forster and George 1992; Röell 1990). Lipson (2003) suggests that the information of the order flow is not similar across venues. Foucault et al. (2007) propose a limit order trading model that explicitly connects anonymity with information asymmetry. Foucault et al. (2007) show that anonymity improves liquidity when the fraction of informed trading is small. Grammig et al. (2001) empirically test stocks that are simultaneously traded at both the floor trading system and anonymous electronic cross-network on the Frankfurt Stock Exchange and find that the non-anonymous floor trading system has less informed trading than the anonymous electronic market.
There are rich studies that explicitly compare the order informativeness in lit- vs. off- exchanges. The current theoretical studies provide two different predictions10: Ye (2011) uses a strategic trading model developed by Kyle (1985) to examine the impact of split informed trades across venues and suggests that the introduction of dark pools reduces volatility and price discovery. In contrast, Zhu (2014) uses the sequential trade model developed by Glosten and Milgrom (1985) to explore the relation between the dark pool participation with adverse selection and argue that the introduction of the dark pool should improve price discovery. Ye (2011) assumes that that only informed traders can select venues. Zhu (2014) extends the model of Ye (2011) by allowing both informed and uninformed traders under a self-selection mechanism in choosing venues. Zhu (2014) shows that the execution risk in the dark pool is high for informed traders as they tend to trade in the same direction. As a result, lit-exchanges should be a better choice for the informed investor. Based on the above prediction, Zhu (2014) suggests that the lit-exchanges should have more informed order flow, and dark exchanges should attract more uninformed order flow.
The empirical evidence points towards a different conclusion. Grammig et al. (2001) examine the relationship between anonymity and informed trading in the German stock market, and show how anonymity attracts informed trading. In contrast, Jiang et al. (2012) investigate the information quality of the order flow in lit- and off-exchanges and find that the order flow executed in off-exchanges is less informed than in lit-exchanges. Garvey et al. (2016) examine the information contents in marketable orders executed in both lit and dark venues, and their results reveal that the trade at lit-exchange contains information towards future price direction while the trade at off-exchange does not. Nevertheless, Hatheway et al. (2017) argue that as dark venues segment the market by attracting the uninformed order flow away from lit markets, dark venues may engage in cream-skimming, harming market quality.
Conversely, Jain et al. (2003) argue that the probability of informed trading is no different on the anonymous market than on the non-anonymous market since the informed traders may split orders and send them to multiple venues. The empirical test by Nimalendran and Ray (2014) supports Jain et al. (2003) in that the informed trader tends to split orders between lit and off-exchanges. In addition, Nimalendran and Ray (2014) find that the order executed in lit-exchanges provides some price discovery.
The above studies discuss the information asymmetry based on the nature of the market design, while the information asymmetry changes with the new information dissemination. For example, the announcement reveals new information to the market, changes the information asymmetry, and updates the investors’ belief towards the estimated investment future cash flow (Bamber et al. 1997; Barron et al. 2005; Choi 2019; Chung et al. 2013; Dugast 2018; Kim and Verrecchia 1994). The changes in belief can be reflected in stock price, volume, and volatility around the macroeconomic and firm news (Chae 2005; Kurov et al. 2019). Menkveld et al. (2017) document the shift of trading volume from dark pools to lit-exchanges after macroeconomic news announcements. Indriawan (2020) shows the difference in the trading volume and market quality for ASX and Chi-X in the Australian market around macroeconomic news announcements. Cox (2020) examines the dynamics of the market fragmentation around earnings announcements and finds that the proportion of the off-exchange volume increases around the earnings announcements. Mishra et al. (2021) confirm Cox (2020), and further show that the dynamic of the fragmentation is different around earnings and repurchasing announcements. The off-exchanges trading volume share increases around scheduled earnings announcements, but it does not change around unscheduled repurchasing announcements.

3.1.4. Summary and Further Discussions

The evidence discussed in the above sections suggest that the trader’s routing order decision is directly influenced by the execution cost, and the execution cost can be viewed from three dimensions: the transaction cost, the execution quality, and the information asymmetry cost. Traders may strategically choose the venue for profit maximization. McAleer et al. (2017) review the theoretical, econometric and statistical models that connect the decision sciences and financial economics.
In fact, several studies suggest that the final venue choice decision may depend on multiple trade-offs between the cost, execution probability, and information asymmetry risk. For instance, Boehmer (2005) compares the SEC rule 1Ac1-5 execution quality report for NYSE and Nasdaq and finds that Nasdaq has a greater execution cost but faster execution speed than NYSE. The findings in Boehmer (2005) infer that the final venue choice decision may depend on multiple trade-offs between cost, execution probability, and information asymmetry risk. Friederich and Payne (2007) examine the trade-off on routing decisions and suggest that the investor’s routing decision is driven by execution and information risks. The order routing decreases when the venue has a high execution risk, high asymmetry information risk, and/or low liquidity. An influential paper by Menkveld et al. (2017) proposes a pecking order hypothesis in explaining the routing decision. Menkveld et al. (2017) suggest that the investor prefers to trade at low-cost-low-immediacy venues (ex. dark pools) on days without information shocks and will switch to high-cost but high-immediacy venues (ex. lit-exchanges) if there is an information shock with increased liquidation urgency. Yet, Brolley (2020) argues that the trade-off between cost vs. immediacy has already existed through marketable vs. limit orders in lit-exchanges, and the limit orders are a natural substitute to dark orders. Thereby, the trade-off consideration for the investor is between immediacy vs. price improvement. Instead of choosing venues, investors strategically choose order types to limit the execution risk. For further discussion about the microstructure models about the information asymmetry and liquidity, we refer the reader to Madhavan (2000) and Biais et al. (2005) for a comprehensive microstructure literature survey.

3.2. Trader Type and Trading Strategies

In the previous section, we discussed how the routing venue choice is influenced by the market design and associated varieties of risk. This section moves our discussion to the market participant and presents theoretical and empirical papers about the role of trader type and trader strategy on the routing decision.

3.2.1. Informed vs. Uninformed Trader

Based on the information that traders could obtain, theories separate the traders as informed and uninformed traders. Traditional microstructure models tend to view individuals and institutions differently based on the level of information that traders could obtain. The institutions are viewed as informed investors, while individuals hold heterogeneity beliefs and are often thought of as uninformed traders. Kavajecz and Odders-White (2004) and Garvey and Wu (2011) suggest the focus of trade-offs among the transaction cost, the execution risk, and the adverse selection risk are different based on the types of the investor. Informed traders should be more concerned with the trade-off between the cost and execution risks as they already have the private profit information, while uninformed traders may focus more on the trade-off between the cost and adverse selection risk. Jones and Lipson (2004) examine the retail order flow in NYSE and find that retail order flow has better execution quality than non-retail order flow.
Earlier research focuses on examining the impact of informed trades, proxied by institutional trades, on the market. According to the strategic trade model developed by Kyle (1985), informed traders camouflage their trading by breaking their trade sizes. Ye and Zhu (2020) extend Kyle’s (1985) strategic model to examine the informed trader’s choice between lit- and off-exchanges by allowing order splitting for the informed investor. Ye and Zhu (2020) show that informed traders increase dark pool utilization to hide the information. Ready (2014) empirically examines the institutional orders in two block dark pools and finds that those with high information have less probability of executing in dark pools. In practice, the institutions generally make the soft dollar agreement with a particular broker to minimize execution costs. These soft dollar brokerage firms will be more favored by institutional investors (Conrad et al. 2001). In addition, Chakravarty et al. (2012) show that the informed institutional investor applies the intermarket sweep order (ISO) by breaking up large orders and sending them over to multiple trading venues to maximize fragmentation arbitrage profits and hide information.
On the other hand, under most microstructure theoretical discussions, the retail investors were treated as uninformed noise traders and it is assumed that the trade direction from the retail traders would be equally distributed (Shleifer and Summers 1990; Easley et al. 2002; Foucault et al. 2011; Zhu 2014). However, much empirical evidence points out that retail trading also conveys information about future stock prices11. The empirical studies show that retail investors have less liquidity constraints, lower agency costs, and smaller trades than institutional investors (Barber et al. 2008; Chevalier and Ellison 1999; Coval and Stafford 2007). Notably, retail investors are attracted by stocks with lottery features (Gao and Lin 2015; Han and Kumar 2013).
In addition, as many behavioral finance and asset pricing papers discuss12, retail investors’ trading also obtains a strong herding pattern. Readers may refer to Patel et al. (1991); Wermers (1999); Barber et al. (2008) and McAleer et al. (2018a) for more discussion towards herding behaviors. Hasso et al. (2021) exploit an exogenous 2021 GameStop frenzy event and confirm that retail investors prefer highly volatile stocks with lottery features. Moreover, Dimpfl and Jank (2016) show that the retail investor’s attention further subsequently raises stock market volatility.
Given the critical role of retail trading flow, one natural question that is raised: where does the retail trading volume go? In the U.S. market, the orders placed by retail investors are not directly reaching the limit order book. Retail investors mainly place orders through retail brokers, and retail brokers make the routing decision. At the same time, retail brokers have the incentives to route order based on size of the commission and rebates (Battalio et al. 2016b; Cimon 2021). As a result, O’Hara (2015) and Boehmer et al. (2021) document most marketable orders placed by retail investors in the U.S. equity market are either internalized or executed by wholesale market makers, which belong to off-exchanges. Jain et al. (2021) study the impact of the zero-commission event for retail brokers on the routing, and they find that the retail brokers which newly announced zero commission policytend to route more orders to the off-exchange market maker in order to gain the payment for order flow. Significantly, given the GameStop trading frenzy by the retail investors in 202113, the role of retail trading on the overall market quality and price discovery has raised attention. A promising direction for future research may explore the interaction between the retail investor’s attention, market fragmentation, and routing order decisions.

3.2.2. Fast vs. Slow Trader

Based on trading speed, microstructure theories separate the traders as fast and slow traders14. Traders compete with each other by the reaction speed to new information. Fragmentation induces high-frequency trading in order to take the information advantage. In particular, with technology innovation, some traders utilize algorithmic trading to respond to a market event at the millisecond level (referred as the high-frequency trader).
Many theoretical studies focus on discussing the impact of high-frequency trading on market quality and overall welfare. For instance, Üslü (2019) applies the search-and-bargaining model to discuss the impact of exogenous heterogeneity in investors’ search speed. The model by Biais et al. (2015) allows the interaction between fast and slow traders and shows that the information advantages from faster traders could result in adverse selection for the slower traders. Budish et al. (2015) provide a model to examine the high-frequency trading on the market design and social welfare. Baldauf and Mollner (2020) extend Budish et al. (2015) to include high-frequency trading into the information acquisition procedure by endogenizing the informed trading and HFT reaction. Furthermore, the theoretical model proposed by Roşu (2019) allows one to examine informed trading at different speeds.
Many empirical studies show the positive relationship between high-frequency trading (HFT) and market quality in lit- and off-exchanges. The HFT could potentially lower the adverse selection cost, improve market quality under liquidity, price discovery, and the short-term volatility dimensions (Brogaard et al. 2015; Hasbrouck and Saar 2013; Hendershott et al. 2011). Van Kervel (2015) argues that increased number of faster traders could result in more order cancellations in a relatively high-latency venue, creating frictions and harming slow traders. Shkilko and Sokolov (2020) show that the differential in a traders’ trading speed harms market quality.
With technology enabling faster speeds, fast traders can actively seek latent liquidity across venues to make an arbitrage profit. Hasbrouck and Saar (2009) document a trading “fleeting orders” phenomenon, namely submitting a limit order and quickly canceling within a second. Hasbrouck and Saar (2009) explain that increased numbers of “fleeting orders” results from new dynamic trading strategies. Additionally, some studies point out that venues with a maker–taker pricing structure may be more favored by faster traders as they could place the limited order to earn the rebates faster than anyone else, and venues with a taker–maker pricing structure may be less attractive to fast traders since the taker–maker venues allow slow trader to pay the maker fee and jump to the head of the queue (O’Hara 2015; Ye and Yao 2014).

3.2.3. Trader’s Behavior and Strategy

Trading strategies could also affect the order routing decision since the trade timing and the selected trade venue can materially affect the trader strategy’s success and estimated return. Theoretical models generally use the CAAR model to formalize an investor’s optimal trading strategy to maximize the expected utility, and the reader may refer to McAleer et al. (2016b) who summarize the investors’ utility models and related implications. An experimental work by Frydman et al. (2014) confirms the disposition effect and find that the investor’s decision-making procedure is consistent with the predictions of realization utility. Therefore, the effect of changes in trading behavior on routing preference could be a promising direction for future research.
Parlour and Seppi (2003) propose a limit order trading model to incorporate the strategic behavior of traders. Their model assumes trader’s strategies depend on the market current state, and they predict that widened spread leads traders to place more limit orders and fewer market orders. Kyle et al. (2018) propose a symmetric continuous-time model to incorporate the heterogeneity belief among investors and trade speed to trade strategies. Glode and Opp (2020) endogenizes the trader’s expertise in the model and show that the trader’s expertise matters in choosing between the limit-order markets and over-the-counter (OTC) markets15. Garvey et al. (2016) empirically examine the trader’s expertise on the routing venue choice and suggest that traders with better skill are more likely to participate in off-exchange trading.

3.2.4. Summary and Further Discussion

Alongside the execution cost, studies suggest that the order route decision is also influenced by the types of traders and their trading behavior. On the dimension of the trading information. The studies suggest informed traders prefer to trade in dark pools to hide information, and they are more likely to split orders to smaller sizes and send them over to multiple venues to maximize profits. On the other hand, most orders placed by uninformed traders (retail investors) are internalized or executed in off-exchanges by market makers. On the dimension of the trading speed, the studies show that the fast trader uses a technological advantage to fleet across venues to seek latent liquidity and get arbitrary profit.
Traders’ expertise and their trading behavior may influence the order routing decision as well. However, connecting trader’s behavior with the routing venue choice is an important question and yet has not been well explored. Investors’ sentiment is widely studied through the lens of behavioral finance, as much as the anomalies germane to the asset pricing literature16. Thus, it will be worthwhile for future research to link sentiment with the trader’s behavior on the routing venue choice. Especially, as discussed in McAleer et al. (2016a), there are not many theoretical models developed to link behavioral and financial economics to health and medical science. McAleer (2020) discusses risk management measures, such as Global Health Security Index, which could potentially link the market uncertainty with the country’s health security. Still, given the ongoing COVID-19 Pandemic, the health condition and environment’s impact on risk aversion and trading behavior remains largely undefined and is an important direction for future research.

3.3. Market and Stock Characteristics

3.3.1. Market Condition

Changes in the market condition alter the order routing decision. McAleer et al. (2016c) examines the global financial crisis in the past two decades and observe a positive relationship between the volatility of stock returns and crisis. Theoretical prediction suggests that the informed trading increases in off-exchanges while overall off-exchange volume share decreases when the bid-ask spread is wider and market volatility is higher (Zhu 2014). Several empirical studies support the predictions in Zhu (2014)17. Vuorenmaa (2014) explicitly discusses the lit and dark liquidity around the Global Financial Crisis. Jiang et al. (2012) find that the trading volume shifts from off-exchange to lit-exchanges when the prices are volatile. Furthermore, He et al. (2015) confirm Jiang et al.’s (2012) finding under the international context.
Barclay et al. (2003) show that ECNs attract more informed trades in the active and volatile markets. Jurich (2021) shows a negative relation between market volatility and the off-exchange trading volume share. Anselmi et al. (2021) examines the dynamics of the market fragmentation during the COVID-19 pandemic period and find that orders are trading in a more concentrated way and they are moving to a venue with high transparency in the time of market stress. They also observe the overall order flow shifts from the dark to lit-exchanges.

3.3.2. Stock Characteristics

Baruch and Saar (2009) develop a model linking asset returns with a firm optimal listing choice. The model shows that on which primary market to list matters for the asset returns. Furthermore, Baruch and Saar (2009) suggest that listing stocks in a market where similar stocks are traded could substantially reduce the information asymmetry, increasing stock value. Harris (2003) suggests that the exchanges operate under ECNs attract more NASDAQ-listed securities. Nguyen et al. (2005) examines the launch of the Archipelago Exchange, which was an ECN, and find that it captures fewer NYSE-listed stocks but more NASDAQ-listed stocks.
He and Lepone (2014) show that the dark pools trading volume is positively related to trade size and negatively related to price. Garvey et al. (2016) confirm that the order size is an important influence for a trader’s decision to choose off-exchanges and argues that trading large orders in off-exchanges may present front-running.

3.3.3. Summary and Further Discussion

Market condition and stock characteristics potentially affect investor’s routing order decision. Theory suggests that higher market volatility reduces trading at off-exchanges and the listing venue and order size matters for routing decision. The evidence is largely in line with these predictions.

3.4. Trading Technologies

The technology innovation on trading speed significantly reduces the latency of information transmission and execution. In this section, we will start with the literature on the fragmentation with trading technology innovation and briefly discuss the theoretical prediction and empirical studies about the impact of the technology on the exchanges18, namely speed competition and colocation, on the market quality. For a broad discussion on the impact of technology on the financial market, readers may refer to comprehensive reviews by McAleer et al. (2015) about econometrics with informatics and data mining and by Menkveld (2016) and Zaharudin et al. (2021) about HFT trading.
Menkveld (2014) argues that both high-frequency trading (HFT) and market fragmentation resulted from technology innovation. With improved technology, search costs decrease, making the trading floor’s operation more profitable, facilitating more venues to enter the market, thus increasing fragmentation. Technology innovation also lowers the information latency, along with the fragmented markets, makes HFT possible.

3.4.1. Speed Race (Low Latency)

To increase the market share, exchanges also compete on the speed to respond to submitted orders. A decrease in communication response speed decreases latency arbitrage, attracting more volumes (Chakrabarty et al. 2021). The limit order book model by Baldauf and Mollner (2020) incorporates the random communication latency within the exchange system. Brolley and Cimon (2020) extend a model from Baldauf and Mollner (2020) by assuming that the market makers were endogenously affected by latency delay. Biais et al. (2015) predict that speed arms race pushes venues to extensively invest in speed technology innovation,

3.4.2. Co-Location

With the development of technology and algorithm trading, introducing the colocation services by securities exchanges becomes necessary due to competition. Hau (2001) explains that traders located close to the financial center will have more information advantages than those who do not. The introduction of co-location allows an exchange to reduce latency further, attracts more algorithm trading volumes, and enhances liquidity (Aitken et al. 2017; Brogaard et al. 2015; Frino et al. 2014).

3.4.3. Summary and Further Discussion

So far, many studies on the relation between technology innovation and orders routing have focused on the interaction with high-frequency trading and market quality. The effect of big data on trader behavior is still unexplored. A review of the theoretical models, econometrics, as well as statistical models about the connection on the big data, computation science, psychology, decision-making, and finance is well beyond the scope of our paper, and we refer the reader to the excellent survey by McAleer et al. (2018b), who provide a comprehensive review of the literature that connects big data, finance, and psychology in both theoretical and empirical way.

4. Regulatory Reforms

Implementation of any equity market regulations could facilitate the fragmentations, change venue’s execution quality, and alter traders routing venue preference. In this section, we discuss the major regulatory reforms in the U.S. equity market that impact the market trading environment and present the studies examining the impact of these policies on the routing venue decision.

4.1. Order Handling Rules in 1997

In order to promote the quote competition, the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) implemented new order handling rules (OHRs) on NASDAQ’s dealer market in 1997, requiring market makers to display customer limit orders in their quotes19. Barclay et al. (1999) and Weston (2000) show that implementing OHRs reduced spreads and dealers’ rent, suggesting improved market quality. However, Rhee and Tang (2013) argue that, in the long-term, forcing quote competition by policy results in dealers altering their competition strategy from quote competition to payment for order flow competition. They observe a weaker correlation between the trading volume and quote competitiveness after the implementation of the OHRs.

4.2. Decimalization in 2000

In order to promote the price competition, the SEC mandated all exchanges to adopt the decimalization system in 2000, with a reduction in minimum tick size from the previous $1/16 ($0.0625) to $0.0120.
The implementation of the decimalization results reduced the trade execution costs, increased quote competition among the exchanges, and narrowed the spreads, thus improving market quality. Under the revenue maximization model developed by Chordia and Subrahmanyam (1995), the reduction in tick size will negatively impact the volume internalization. Kandel and Marx (1999) extend Chordia and Subrahmanyam (1995) by treating spreads, preference trades, and vertical integration as equilibrium outcomes. Their models suggest the decrease in tick size results in asymmetric effects on endogenous variables, such as numbers of market makers, due to the change in the equilibrium.
Decimalization changes trader’s order submission strategies as well. Changes in minimum tick size alter traders’ behavior by lowering trader’s ex-ante cost, resulting in more market orders and fewer limit orders. Traders now place fewer large limit order sizes and cancel limit orders more frequently (Bacidore et al. 2003; Bessembinder 2003; Chakravarty et al. 2005; Chung et al. 2004; Huang et al. 2010).
Goldstein et al. (2010) examine the effects of decimalization on venue competition and suggests that the impact is heterogeneous across venues. The quote competition further weakens, and the competition among venues switches to best quote improvements. Tang et al. (2011) further support Goldstein et al. (2010) about the decline in the quote competitiveness and point out the reason is the reduction in the number of 100-share NBBO-matching quotes posted by NASDAQ. Garvey et al. (2016) find that traders are more likely to route to off-exchanges venue after the decimalization as the cost aspect of routing decision is now marginalized.

4.3. Reg NMS Rule 611 “The Order Protection Rule (OPR)” and Reg NMS Rule 612 “Minmum Pricing Increment” in 2005

To encourage competition among traders and to improve market liquidity, the SEC implemented the Order Protection Rule (OPR) for intermarket price protection21. Based on OPR requirements, each exchange has to “establish, maintain, and enforce written policies and procedures reasonably designed to prevent the execution of trades at prices inferior to protected quotations displayed by other trading centers, subject to an applicable exception”. OPR differentiates exchanges based on the execution speed. The rule classifies electronic exchanges, such as NASDAQ, as the fast market and prohibits it to trade through better prices on other fast markets. At the same time, the restriction does not apply to slow market, which is floor-based exchanges. Many studies raised concerns that the implementation of OPR may negatively impact the market quality (Blume 2007; O’Hara 2004). As OPR fundamentally changes exchanges’ execution probability and speed. Chung and Chuwonganant (2012) find OPR negatively impacts the execution quality in NYSE and AMEX; as a result, they observe an increased trading volume in NASDAQ. Meanwhile, OPR alters trader’s trading strategies. Spatt (2018) points out that OPR encourages traders to split orders across venues to achieve the best execution.
The Reg NMS rule 612 “Minimum Pricing Increment” rule prohibits all trading venues to display, rank, or accept orders priced at more than two decimal places for stocks that trade greater or equal to $1.00, while allowing the broker-dealers who operate in off-exchanges (OTC non-ATS markets) to offer price improvement in sub-penny increments22. As a result, traders can now utilize off-exchanges to bypass existing limit order queues and execute orders more quickly. Kwan et al. (2015) empirically document a remarkable gain in the market share for off-exchanges after the implementation of the Reg NMS rule 612, suggesting minimum pricing increment policy yields a significant competitive advantage for off-exchanges.

4.4. SEC Tick Size Pilot Program in 2015

To examine the impact of the tick sizes on the market quality for small-capitalization firms, in 2016, SEC and FINRA jointly launched a 2-year pilot program, which increases the minimum tick size from $0.01 to $0.05 for three pilot groups23. The main interest of the pilot focuses on whether the changes in tick size improves liquidity. In contrast, many empirical studies and the SEC report find that this pilot resulted in a negative impact on market liquidity and cost (Albuquerque et al. 2020; Griffith and Roseman 2019; SEC 2018). Given the operational concerns, the SEC issued a termination of the Pilot two days before the planned expiration date24.
However, from the venue competition perspective, several studies show that the tick size pilot has a heterogeneous impact on exchanges. For instance, Comerton-Forde et al. (2019) study the effect of the tick size pilot for inverted fee exchanges and finds that the price discovery process is improved in inverted fee exchanges under the trade-at rule. Consequently, the trading volume share shift to inverted fee exchanges. Cox et al. (2019) reach the same conclusion as Comerton-Forde et al. (2019) that inverted fee exchanges gain more volume share under the tick size pilot. Additionally, Cox et al. (2019) observe that the shift in volume share was from both traditional fee exchanges (maker–taker) and off-exchanges, suggesting that the tick size changes reduce the risk of an informed trader exposing an order.

5. Conclusions

With the rapid development of technology and the regulation reforms, trading in the U.S. equities markets is increasingly fragmented. Equity trading in the U.S. is dispersed across 16 national exchanges, more than thirty alternative trading systems, and numerous broker-dealers and wholesalers. On the one hand, the intensified competition lowers the transaction fee and ultimately benefits market participants. On the other hand, varying levels of venue transparency and the heterogeneity in the transaction speeds have raised the risk of adverse selection. Thus, examining routing order decisions is an important topic that is worth exploring. This paper provides a better understanding of the potential driving factors underlying routing order decisions under fragmented markets and identifies several promising directions for future research.
We survey a large and growing theoretical and empirical literature about the channels and determinants of routing venue choice under a highly fragmented equity market. The literature referenced in this paper carries important implications for policymakers, regulators, and exchange operators: under highly fragmented markets, routing order decisions are complex and influenced by many factors. First, the routing order decision is fundamentally affected by the market structure design. Different trading system structures provide different liquidity provisions and different degrees of transparency, resulting in differences in terms of execution quality. Execution decisions could be influenced by transaction costs, execution quality, and adverse selection concerns. Moreover, the decision procedure involves multiple trade-offs among the transaction costs, execution quality, and the risk of adverse selection. The nature of the trade-off varies by the type of investor. The informed trader pays more attention to the trade-off between transaction cost and execution quality, while the uninformed trader focuses on the trade-off between the transaction cost and the adverse selection cost. Second, the routing venue choice is influenced by the types of traders as well as their strategies. Informed traders are more likely to split their orders and send them across exchanges to camouflage their trading and maximize their profits. Meanwhile, in the U.S. market, uninformed retail investors mainly place orders through retail brokers, and retail brokers’ routing order decisions are influenced by the order-processing cost. Due to the practice of payment for order flow, most retail uninformed marketable orders are routed in off-exchanges by market makers. Third, the routing order decision depends on market conditions and stock characteristics. Order flow moves to exchanges with higher transparency during periods of high market volatility. In addition, stock listing venues and trade size substantially affect routing choices. Finally, the routing order decision is systematically shaped by technological development and regulatory reforms. We have shown that regulatory reform changes the venue’s execution quality and hence alters traders’ routing venue preference.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, S.M. and L.Z.; methodology, S.M. and L.Z.; validation, S.M. and L.Z.; formal analysis, L.Z.; investigation, L.Z.; resources, L.Z.; writing—original draft preparation, L.Z.; writing—review and editing, S.M.; visualization, L.Z.; supervision, S.M.; project administration, S.M. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

All used data are mentioned in the list of references.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Summary of market microstructure empirical studies on order routing decisions.
Table A1. Summary of market microstructure empirical studies on order routing decisions.
AuthorsYearData SourceSample PeriodMethodologyFindings
Cardella, Hao and Kalcheva2017SEC Filings and NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ)1 January 2008–31 December 2010 Multivariate regression analysisThe magnitudes of decreasing in trading activities of take fee and make fee are different
Malinova and Park2015A proprietary trader-level dataset from Toronto Stock Exchange (TSX)1 August 2005–30 November 2005Panel regression analysisAn increase in the total exchange fee on Toronto Stock Exchange increases its cum fee effective spread and lowers the limit order fill rate
Battalio, Corwin and Jennings2016Order data from major broker–dealer’s smart order routing systems and NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ)1 October 2012–30 November 2012Univariate analysis and multivariate regression analysisBrokers’ route order decision is primarily based on the fee rather than execution quality
Jørgensen, Skjeltorp and Ødegaard2018Orderbook from Oslo Stock Exchange (OSE) and Thomson Reuters Tick History database1 January 2010–31 December 2011Difference in differences analysisThe introduction of a fee on excessive order-to-ratios at the Olso Stock Exchange does not affect the market quality
Comerton-Forde, Malinova and Park2018A proprietary transaction-broker level dataset from Investment Industry Regulatory Organization of Canada (IIROC)1 August 2012–30 November 2012Multivariate regression analysis and two-stage least squares regressionReducing retail order segmentation enhances liquidity in lit-exchanges
Clapham, Gomber, Lausen and Panz2021Refinitiv Tick History database1 May 2016–28 February 2017Difference in differences analysisThe order routing decisions are influenced by fee rebates
Boehmer, Jennings and Wei2007NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ) and the SEC Dash-5 reports1 June 2001–31 June 2004Fixed effects regressionThe routing decisions are associated with execution quality
Battalio, Shkilko and Van Ness2016Options Price Reporting Authority (OPRA) and NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ)1 March 2010–31 June 2010Fixed effects regressionRetail brokers have the incentives to route order based on size of the commission and rebates
Peterson and Sirri2003NYSE SOD file, BSE BEACON system, CHX order data, CSE preferencing dealers, PSE trading floors and PHLX’s market surveillance department1 October 1996–30 November 1996Univariate analysis and ordered probit regressionNYSE, which was the primary market, obtains better quotation and execution quality for market orders with smaller effective spreads than other regional exchanges
Boehmer, Saar and Yu2005NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ), System Order Data (SOD) and Consolidated Equity Audit Trail Data (CAUD)1 January 2001–31 May 2001Wilcoxon signed rank test and multivariate regression analysisImprovement in pre-trade transparency enhances market liquidity
Garvey, Huang and Wu2016A proprietary data from a U.S. direct market access (DMA) broker1 October 1999–31 May 2006Two-stage hackman modelThe time-to-execution is much longer in dark venues than in lit venues, and the average fill rate of marketable order executed at dark venues is lower than at lit venues
Ernst, Sokobin and Spatt2021NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ)1 January 2019–31 December 2020Fixed effects regressionThe exchange with better execution quality (lower cost and higher fill rate) subsequently attracts more order flow
Thomas, Zhang and Zhu2021NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ)1 January 2019–31 June 2018OLS regression and two-stage least squares regressionThe dark trading decreases liquidity and increases the post-earnings announcement drift (PEAD)
Grammig, Schiereck and Theissen2001Transaction-level dataset from IBIS and Frankfurt Stock Exchange1 June 1997–31 July 1997Private information (PIN) model by Easley and O’Hara (2004)The non-anonymous floor trading system has less informed trading than the anonymous electronic market
Jain, Jiang, Mclnish and Taechapiroontong 2003Transaction-level dataset from London Stock Exchange1 January 2000–31 December 2000Private information (PIN) model by Easley et al. (1996) and cross-sectional regressionThe probability of informed trading is no different on the anonymous market than on the non-anonymous market since the informed traders may split orders and send them to multiple venues
Jiang, Mclnish and Upson2012NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ)1 January 2008–30 June 2008MRR regression by Madhavan et al. (1997)Trading volume shifts from off-exchange to lit-exchanges when the prices are vola-tile
Nimalendran and Ray2014NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ)1 June 2009–31 December 2009Multivariate regression analysisInformed trader tend to split order between lit and off-exchanges and the order executed in lit-exchanges provides some price discovery
Hatheway, Kwan and Zheng2017Thomson Reuters DataScope database1 January 2011–31 March 2011Two-stage hackman modelDark venues may harm the market quality by attracting uninformed order flow away form lit market
Kavajecz and Odders-White2004NYSE SuperDOT dataset1 July 1997–30 September 1997Univariate analysis and multivariate regression analysisTechnical analysis and moving average indicators are significantly related to the state of liquidity on the limit order book
Garvey and Wu2011A proprietary order-level data from a U.S. broker-dealer and Thomson Reuters Tick History database1 October 1999–31 July 2003OLS regressionThe focus of trade-offs among transaction cost, execution risk, and adverse selection risk are different based on the types of the investor
Jones and Lipson2004A proprietary order-level data from NYSE1 November 2002–30 November 2002Vector autoregressionRetail order flow has better execution quality than non-retail order flow
Ready2014NASDAQtrader.com, Ancerno database and NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ)1 July 2005–30 September 2007Panel regression analysisInstitutional orders with high information have less probability of executing in dark pools
Chakravarty, Jain, Upson and Wood2012NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ)1 August 2007–31 May 2008MRR regression by Madhavan et al. (1997)The informed institutional investor applies the intermarket sweep order (ISO) by breaking up large orders and sending them over to multiple trading venues to maximize fragmentation arbitrage profits and hide information
Barber, Odean and Zhu2008NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ) and Institute for the Study of Security Markets (ISSM) transaction data1 January 1983–31 December 2001Univariate portfolio analysis and Fama-Macbeth cross-sectional regressionThe signed smaller trades provide a reasonable proxy for individual investor’s activity, and over both short and long horizons, retail trade imbalances forecast future returns
Chevalier and Ellison1999Morningstar1 January 1992–31 December 1994Multivariate regression analysisThe agency issues within the mutual fund companies can be attributed to career concerns
Coval and Stafford2007Spectrum mutual fund holdings database1 January 1980–31 December 2004Fama-Macbeth cross-sectional regressionThe institutional price press creates an incentive to front-run
Gao and Lin2015Website of the bank that holds the rights to administer the lottery and trading data from Taiwan Economic Journal1 January 2002–31 December 2009OLS regressionIndividual investor tends to trade stocks as a gambling activity
Han and Kumar2013NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ) and Institute for the Study of Security Markets (ISSM) transaction data1 January 1983–31 January 2000Fama-Macbeth cross-sectional regressionStocks with lottery features (high volatility, high skewness, and low prices) are heavily traded by retail investors
Boehmer, Jones, Zhang and Zhang2021NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ)1 January 2010–31 December 2015Fama-Macbeth cross-sectional regressionMost marketable orders placed by retail investors in the U.S. equity market are either internalized or executed in by wholesale market makers in off-exchange
Jain, Mishra, O’Donoghue and Zhao2021SEC Rule 605, SEC Rule 606 and NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ)1 June 2019–29 February 2020Univariate analysis and multivariate regression analysisRetail brokers who newly announced zero-commission policy tends to route more orders to the off-exchange market maker in order to gain the payment for order flow
Brogaard, Hagströmer, Nordén and Riordan2015A proprietary dataset for the exchange colocation service subscription and Thomson Reuters’ Tick History database1 August 2012–31 October 2012Probit regression and panel regressionEnhanced speed from colocation upgrade benefits market liquidity
Hasbrouck and Saar2013NASDAQ OMX ITCH dataset1 October 2007–31 December 2007 and 1 June 2008–30 June 2008Multivariate regression analysisIncreased low-latency activity improves traditional market quality measures
Hendershott, Jones and Menkveld2011NYSE System Order Data (SOD)1 December 2002–31 July 2003Two-stage regressionImproving in market’s automation and speed reduces cost of immediacy and improves price discovery
He, Jarnecic and Liu2015Thomson Reuters Tick Historydatabase1 March 2007–31 October 2011Fixed effects regressionTrading volume shift from off-exchange to lit-exchanges when the prices are volatile
Barclay, Hendershott and McCormick2003Nasdaq National Market1 June 2000–30 June 2000Variance decomposition by Hasbrouck (1991)ECNs attract more informed trades in the active and volatile markets
Jurich2021Cboe Global Markets and NYSE’s Trade and Quote (TAQ)1 September 2018–30 SeptemberMultivariate regression analysisThere is a negative relation between market volatility and off-exchange trading volume share
Anselmi, Nimalendram and Petrella2021Fidessa database1 July 2019–31 July 2020Fixed effects regressionMarket order flow at the COVID-19 pandemic is more concentrated and moves to a venue with high transparency
Nguyen, Van Ness and Van Ness2005The SEC Dash-5 reports, Transaction Auditing Group (TAG) and Market System Inc.1 April 2002–31 October 2002Multivariate regression analysisA launch of the Archipelago exchange, which is an ECN, captures fewer NYSE-listed stocks but more NASDAQ-listed stocks
He and Lepone2014A proprietary dataset from the Australian Securities Exchange (ASX) and Thomson Reuters Tick History database1 July 2010–31 December 2010Multivariate regression analysisThe dark pools trading volume is positively related to trade size and negatively related to price
Hau2001A proprietary transaction-level dataset from the German Securities Exchange1 September 1998–31 December 1998Spectral Decomposition and multivariate regression analysisTraders located close to the financial center will have more information advantages than those who do not
Aitken, Cumming and Zhan2017Capital Market Cooperative Research Centre (CMCRC)1 January 2003–31 December 2011Univariate analysis and multivariate regression analysisThere is a positive relationship between colocation and high-frequency trading
Frino, Mollica and Webb2014Thomson Reuters Tick History Database1 August 2011–31 August 2012Multivariate regression analysisThe introduction of col-location enhances liquidity on the Australian Securities Exchange

Notes

1
Market fragmentation in this paper refers to trading fragmentation such that one equity could trade simultaneously on multiple exchanges.
2
Order routing is a handling order process by which an order is sent to a selected exchange.
3
Lit-exchange or lit venue refers to an exchange where quote information (bid and ask) are posted in publicly. Whereas off-exchange or dark venue refers to a venue that does not provide quote information. Trading at off-exchange can be refer as “dark trading”.
4
The Markets in the Financial Instruments Directive (MiFID) was created by the European Union in 2004 to promote the of European financial markets.
5
6
See Nasdaq 2018 10K report, available at http://ir.nasdaq.com/financials/annual-reports, accessed on 23 August 2021.
7
Alternative Trading System (ATS) is a type of off-exchange that matches buyer and seller without going through a middleman.
8
Dark pools are a type of ATS that provide anonymity for trading large orders with automated execution. It is generally used by intitutioanl investors.
9
10
Theoretical discussion can be found in Hendershott and Mendelson (2000); Ye (2011); Degryse et al. (2009); Zhu (2014) and Buti et al. (2017).
11
12
See McAleer et al. (2020) for the survey of anomalies in stock market.
13
In January 2021, GameStop’s stock (GME) experienced a surge in demand from retail investors who were influenced by the discussion in social media platforms such as Reddit. GameStop’s share price jumped 2000% in a few days (from $16 to $347 within one month).
14
For example, Zhu (2014) assumes the liquidity investors face heterogeneous delay costs.
15
OTC market is a type of the off-exchange, where the buyer and seller trade with each other directly, often non-anonymous.
16
17
18
The impact of the technology on the trader is discussed on Trader Type and Trading Strategies section.
19
See https://www.sec.gov/rules/sro/nd9821o.htm, accessed on 23 August 2021.
20
See https://www.sec.gov/rules/other/decimalp.htm#seci, accessed on 23 August 2021.
21
See https://www.sec.gov/rules/final/34-51808.pdf, accessed on 23 August 2021.
22
23
See https://www.sec.gov/ticksizepilot, accessed on 23 August 2021.
24
Statement on the Expiration of the Tick Size Pilot can be found in https://www.sec.gov/news/public-statement/tm-dera-expiration-tick-size-pilot, accessed on 23 August 2021.

References

  1. Aitken, Michael, Douglas Cumming, and Feng Zhan. 2017. Trade size, high-frequency trading, and colocation around the world. The European Journal of Finance 23: 781–801. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Albuquerque, Rui, Shiyun Song, and Chen Yao. 2020. The price effects of liquidity shocks: A study of the SEC’s tick size experiment. Journal of Financial Economics 138: 700–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Amihud, Yakov, and Haim Mendelson. 1991. Volatility, Efficiency, and Trading: Evidence from the Japanese Stock Market. The Journal of Finance 46: 1765. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Amihud, Yakov, Beni Lauterbach, and Haim Mendelson. 2003. The value of trading consolidation: Evidence from the exercise of warrants. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 38: 829–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Angel, James J., Lawrence E. Harris, and Chester S. Spatt. 2015. Equity trading in the 21st century: An update. The Quarterly Journal of Finance 5: 1550002. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Anselmi, Giulio, Mahendrarajah Nimalendran, and Giovanni Petrella. 2021. Order flow fragmentation and flight-to-transparency during stressed market conditions: Evidence from COVID-19. Finance Research Letters, 102101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Atkins, Allen B., and Edward A. Dyl. 1997. Market structure and reported trading volume: NASDAQ versus the NYSE. Journal of Financial Research 20: 291–304. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Bacidore, Jeffrey, Robert H. Battalio, and Robert H. Jennings. 2003. Order submission strategies, liquidity supply, and trading in pennies on the New York Stock Exchange. Journal of Financial Markets 6: 337–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Baker, Malcolm, and Jeffrey Wurgler. 2006. Investor sentiment and the cross-section of stock returns. The Journal of Finance 61: 1645–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Baker, Scott R., Nicholas Bloom, and Steven J. Davis. 2016. Measuring Economic Policy Uncertainty. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 131: 1593–636. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Baldauf, Markus, and Joshua Mollner. 2020. High-Frequency Trading and Market Performance. The Journal of Finance 75: 1495–526. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Baldauf, Markus, and Joshua Mollner. 2021. Trading in fragmented markets. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 56: 93–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Bamber, Linda Smith, Orie E. Barron, and Thomas L. Stober. 1997. Trading volume and different aspects of disagreement coincident with earnings announcements. Accounting Review 72: 575–97. [Google Scholar]
  14. Barardehi, Yashar H., Dan Bernhardt, and Ryan J. Davies. 2019. Trade-Time Measures of Liquidity. The Review of Financial Studies 32: 126–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Barber, Brad M., Terrance Odean, and Ning Zhu. 2008. Do retail trades move markets? The Review of Financial Studies 22: 151–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Barclay, Michael J., William G. Christie, Jeffrey H. Harris, Eugene Kandel, and Paul H. Schultz. 1999. Effects of market reform on the trading costs and depths of Nasdaq stocks. The Journal of Finance 54: 1–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Barclay, Michael J., Terrence Hendershott, and Tim McCormick. 2003. Competition among Trading Venues: Information and Trading on Electronic Communications Networks. The Journal of Finance 58: 2637–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  18. Barron, Orie E., David G. Harris, and Mary Stanford. 2005. Evidence that investors trade on private event-period information around earnings announcements. The Accounting Review 80: 403–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Baruch, Shmuel, and Gideon Saar. 2009. Asset Returns and the Listing Choice of Firms. Review of Financial Studies 22: 2239–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Battalio, Robert H., Andriy Shkilko, and Robert A. Van Ness. 2016a. To Pay or Be Paid? The Impact of Taker Fees and Order Flow Inducements on Trading Costs in U.S. Options Markets. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 51: 1637–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Battalio, Robert, Shane A. Corwin, and Robert Jennings. 2016b. Can Brokers Have It All? On the Relation between Make-Take Fees and Limit Order Execution Quality. The Journal of Finance 71: 2193–238. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Bennett, Paul, and Li Wei. 2006. Market structure, fragmentation, and market quality. Journal of Financial Markets 9: 49–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Benveniste, Lawrence M., Alan J. Marcus, and William J. Wilhelm. 1992. What’s special about the specialist? Journal of Financial Economics 32: 61–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Bertsimas, Dimitris, and Andrew W. Lo. 1998. Optimal control of execution costs. Journal of Financial Markets 1: 1–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Bessembinder, Hendrik. 2003. Trade Execution Costs and Market Quality after Decimalization. The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 38: 747. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Bessembinder, Hendrik, and Herbert M. Kaufman. 1997a. A comparison of trade execution costs for NYSE and NASDAQ-listed stocks. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 32: 287–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Bessembinder, Hendrik, and Herbert M. Kaufman. 1997b. A cross-exchange comparison of execution costs and information flow for NYSE-listed stocks. Journal of Financial Economics 46: 293–319. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Bessembinder, Hendrik, and Subhrendu Rath. 2008. Does Market Structure Matter? Trading Costs and Return Volatility around Exchange Listings. School of Economics and Finance Working Paper Series: No. 08:06; Bentley: Curtin University of Technology, School of Economics and Finance, Available online: http://hdl.handle.net/20.500.11937/6543 (accessed on 23 August 2021).
  29. Bessembinder, Hendrik, and Kumar Venkataraman. 2004. Does an electronic stock exchange need an upstairs market? Journal of Financial Economics 73: 3–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Biais, Bruno. 1993. Price formation and equilibrium liquidity in fragmented and centralized markets. The Journal of Finance 48: 157–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Biais, Bruno, Pierre Hillion, and Chester Spatt. 1999. Price Discovery and Learning during the Preopening Period in the Paris Bourse. Journal of Political Economy 107: 1218–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  32. Biais, Bruno, David Martimort, and Jean-Charles Rochet. 2000. Competing Mechanisms in a Common Value Environment. Econometrica 68: 799–837. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Biais, Bruno, Larry Glosten, and Chester Spatt. 2005. Market microstructure: A survey of microfoundations, empirical results, and policy implications. Journal of Financial Markets 8: 217–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  34. Biais, Bruno, Thierry Foucault, and Sophie Moinas. 2015. Equilibrium fast trading. Journal of Financial Economics 116: 292–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Blume, Marshall. 2007. Competition and Fragmentation in the Equity Markets: The Effect of Regulation NMS. Philadelphia: The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Available online: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=959429 (accessed on 23 August 2021).
  36. Boehmer, Ekkehart. 2005. Dimensions of execution quality: Recent evidence for US equity markets. Journal of Financial Economics 78: 553–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Boehmer, Beatrice, and Ekkehart Boehmer. 2003. Trading your neighbor’s ETFs: Competition or fragmentation? Journal of Banking & Finance 27: 1667–703. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Boehmer, Ekkehart, Gideon Saar, and Lei Yu. 2005. Lifting the Veil: An Analysis of Pre-trade Transparency at the NYSE. The Journal of Finance 60: 783–815. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  39. Boehmer, Ekkehart, Robert Jennings, and Li Wei. 2007. Public Disclosure and Private Decisions: Equity Market Execution Quality and Order Routing. Review of Financial Studies 20: 315–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  40. Boehmer, Ekkehart, Charles M. Jones, Xiaoyan Zhang, and Xinran Zhang. 2021. Tracking Retail Investor Activity. The Journal of Finance 76: 2249–305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Boneva, Lena, Oliver Linton, and Michael Vogt. 2016. The Effect of Fragmentation in Trading on Market Quality in the UK Equity Market. Journal of Applied Econometrics 31: 192–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  42. Brennan, Michael J., and H. Henry Cao. 1996. Information, trade, and derivative securities. The Review of Financial Studies 9: 163–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Brogaard, Jonathan, Björn Hagströmer, Lars Nordén, and Ryan Riordan. 2015. Trading Fast and Slow: Colocation and Liquidity. Review of Financial Studies 28: 3407–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Brogaard, Jonathan, Matthew C. Ringgenberg, and Dominik Roesch. 2021. Does Floor Trading Matter? Available online: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3609007 (accessed on 23 August 2021).
  45. Brolley, Michael. 2020. Price Improvement and Execution Risk in Lit and Dark Markets. Management Science 66: 863–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Brolley, Michael, and David A. Cimon. 2020. Order-Flow Segmentation, Liquidity, and Price Discovery: The Role of Latency Delays. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 55: 2555–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Budish, Eric, Peter Cramton, and John Shim. 2015. The High-Frequency Trading Arms Race: Frequent Batch Auctions as a Market Design Response. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 130: 1547–621. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  48. Budish, Eric, Robin S. Lee, and John J. Shim. 2019. Will the Market Fix the Market?: A Theory of Stock Exchange Competition and Innovation. Working Paper. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
  49. Buti, Sabrina, Barbara Rindi, and Ingrid M. Werner. 2017. Dark pool trading strategies, market quality and welfare. Journal of Financial Economics 124: 244–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Cardella, Laura, Jia Hao, and Ivalina Kalcheva. 2017. Liquidity-based Trading Fees and Exchange Volume. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2149302 (accessed on 23 August 2021).
  51. Chae, Joon. 2005. Trading volume, information asymmetry, and timing information. The Journal of Finance 60: 413–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Chakrabarty, Bidisha, Pankaj K. Jain, Andriy Shkilko, and Konstantin Sokolov. 2021. Speed of Market access and Market Quality: Evidence from the SEC Naked Access Ban. Management Science. Forthcoming. [Google Scholar]
  53. Chakravarty, Sugato, Venkatesh Panchapagesan, and Robert A. Wood. 2005. Did decimalization hurt institutional investors? Journal of Financial Markets 8: 400–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Chakravarty, Sugato, Pankaj Jain, James Upson, and Robert Wood. 2012. Clean Sweep: Informed Trading through Intermarket Sweep Orders. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 47: 415–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  55. Chao, Yong, Chen Yao, and Mao Ye. 2017. Discrete Pricing and Market Fragmentation: A Tale of Two-Sided Markets. The American Economic Review 107: 196–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Chen, Daniel, and Darrell Duffie. 2021. Market Fragmentation. The American Economic Review 111: 2247–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Chevalier, Judith, and Glenn Ellison. 1999. Career concerns of mutual fund managers. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 389–432. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  58. Choi, Hae Mi. 2019. Market uncertainty and trading volume around earnings announcements. Finance Research Letters 30: 14–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Chordia, Tarun, and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam. 1995. Market making, the tick size, and payment-for-order flow: Theory and evidence. Journal of Business 68: 543–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Chowdhry, Bhagwan, and Vikram Nanda. 1991. Multimarket Trading and Market Liquidity. Review of Financial Studies 4: 483–511. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Chung, Kee H., and Chairat Chuwonganant. 2012. Regulation NMS and Market Quality. Financial Management 41: 285–317. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Chung, Kee H., Chairat Chuwonganant, and D. Timothy McCormick. 2004. Order preferencing and market quality on NASDAQ before and after decimalization. Journal of Financial Economics 71: 581–612. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Chung, Kee H., John Elder, and Jang-Chul Kim. 2013. Liquidity and information flow around monetary policy announcement. Journal of Money Credit and Banking 45: 781–820. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Cimon, David A. 2021. Broker routing decisions in limit order markets. Journal of Financial Markets 54: 100602. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Clapham, Benjamin, Peter Gomber, Jens Lausen, and Sven Panz. 2021. Liquidity provider incentives in fragmented securities markets. Journal of Empirical Finance 60: 16–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Colliard, Jean-Edouard, and Thierry Foucault. 2012. Trading Fees and Efficiency in Limit Order Markets. Review of Financial Studies 25: 3389–421. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Comerton-Forde, Carole, and Tālis J. Putniņš. 2015. Dark trading and price discovery. Journal of Financial Economics 118: 70–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  68. Comerton-Forde, Carole, Katya Malinova, and Andreas Park. 2018. Regulating dark trading: Order flow segmentation and market quality. Journal of Financial Economics 130: 347–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Comerton-Forde, Carole, Vincent Grégoire, and Zhuo Zhong. 2019. Inverted fee structures, tick size, and market quality. Journal of Financial Economics 134: 141–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Conrad, Jennifer, Kevin M. Johnson, and Sunil Wahal. 2001. Institutional Trading and Soft Dollars. The Journal of Finance 56: 397–416. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Conrad, Jennifer, Kevin M. Johnson, and Sunil Wahal. 2003. Institutional trading and alternative trading systems. Journal of Financial Economics 70: 99–134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Corwin, Shane A., and Marc L. Lipson. 2000. Order Flow and Liquidity around NYSE Trading Halts. The Journal of Finance 55: 1771–801. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Coval, Joshua, and Erik Stafford. 2007. Asset fire sales (and purchases) in equity markets. Journal of Financial Economics 86: 479–512. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  74. Cox, Justin. 2020. Market fragmentation and post-earnings announcement drift. Journal of Economics and Finance 44: 587–610. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Cox, Justin, Bonnie Van Ness, and Robert Van Ness. 2019. Increasing the Tick: Examining the Impact of the Tick Size Change on Maker-Taker and Taker-Maker Market Models. Financial Review 54: 417–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. De Fontnouvelle, Patrick, Raymond P. H. Fishe, and Jeffrey H. Harris. 2003. The behavior of bid-ask spreads and volume in options markets during the competition for listings in 1999. The Journal of Finance 58: 2437–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. De Frutos, M. Ángeles, and Carolina Manzano. 2002. Risk Aversion, Transparency, and Market Performance. The Journal of Finance 57: 959–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  78. Degryse, Hans, Mark Van Achter, and Gunther Wuyts. 2009. Dynamic order submission strategies with competition between a dealer market and a crossing network. Journal of Financial Economics 91: 319–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  79. Degryse, Hans, Frank De Jong, and Vincent van Kervel. 2015. The Impact of Dark Trading and Visible Fragmentation on Market Quality. Review of Finance 19: 1587–622. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  80. Dennert, Jürgen. 1993. Price competition between market makers. The Review of Economic Studies 60: 735–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Dimpfl, Thomas, and Stephan Jank. 2016. Can Internet Search Queries Help to Predict Stock Market Volatility? European Financial Management 22: 171–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  82. Dorn, Anne Jones, Daniel Dorn, and Paul Sengmueller. 2015. Trading as gambling. Management Science 61: 2376–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Dugast, Jérôme. 2018. Unscheduled news and market dynamics. The Journal of Finance 73: 2537–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Easley, David, Nicholas M. Kiefer, and Maureen O’Hara. 1996. Cream-skimming or profit-sharing? The curious role of purchased order flow. The Journal of Finance 51: 811–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Easley, David, Soeren Hvidkjaer, and Maureen O’hara. 2002. Is information risk a determinant of asset returns? The Journal of Finance 57: 2185–221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. Ernst, Thomas, Jonathan Sokobin, and Chester Spatt. 2021. The Value of Off-Exchange Data. Available online: http://people.stern.nyu.edu/jhasbrou/SternMicroMtg/SternMicroMtg2021/Papers/TRF_NYU%20Conference.pdf (accessed on 23 August 2021).
  87. Fishman, M. J., and F. A. Longstaff. 1992. Dual trading in futures markets. The Journal of Finance 47: 643–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Flood, Mark D., Ronald Huisman, Kees G. Koedijk, and Ronald J. Mahieu. 1999. Quote disclosure and price discovery in multiple-dealer financial markets. The Review of Financial Studies 12: 37–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Forster, Margaret M., and Thomas J. George. 1992. Anonymity in securities markets. Journal of Financial Intermediation 2: 168–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Foucault, Thierry. 1999. Order flow composition and trading costs in a dynamic limit order market. Journal of Financial Markets 2: 99–134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Foucault, Thierry, and Albert J. Menkveld. 2008. Competition for Order Flow and Smart Order Routing Systems. The Journal of Finance 63: 119–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Foucault, Thierry, Ohad Kadan, and Eugene Kandel. 2005. Limit Order Book as a Market for Liquidity. Review of Financial Studies 18: 1171–217. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  93. Foucault, Thierry, Sophie Moinas, and Erik Theissen. 2007. Does Anonymity Matter in Electronic Limit Order Markets? Review of Financial Studies 20: 1707–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. Foucault, Thierry, David Sraer, and David J. Thesmar. 2011. Individual Investors and Volatility. The Journal of Finance 66: 1369–406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. Foucault, Thierry, Ohad Kadan, and Eugene Kandel. 2013. Liquidity Cycles and Make/Take Fees in Electronic Markets. The Journal of Finance 68: 299–341. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  96. Fox, Merritt B., Lawrence Glosten, and Gabriel Rauterberg. 2019. The New Stock Market. Columbia: Columbia University Press. [Google Scholar]
  97. Friederich, Sylvain, and Richard Payne. 2007. Dealer Liquidity in an Auction Market: Evidence from the London Stock Exchange. The Economic Journal 117: 1168–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  98. Frino, Alex, Vito Mollica, and Robert I. Webb. 2014. The Impact of Co-Location of Securities Exchanges’ and Traders’ Computer Servers on Market Liquidity. Journal of Futures Markets 34: 20–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  99. Frydman, Cary, Nicholas Barberis, Colin Camerer, Peter Bossaerts, and Antonio Rangel. 2014. Using Neural Data to Test a Theory of Investor Behavior: An Application to Realization Utility. The Journal of Finance 69: 907–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  100. Gao, Xiaohui, and Tse-Chun Lin. 2015. Do individual investors treat trading as a fun and exciting gambling activity? Evidence from repeated natural experiments. The Review of Financial Studies 28: 2128–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  101. Garvey, Ryan, and Fei Wu. 2011. Information, speed vs. cost trade-offs, and order routing decisions in U.S. equity markets. Journal of Empirical Finance 18: 408–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  102. Garvey, Ryan, Tao Huang, and Fei Wu. 2016. Why do traders choose dark markets? Journal of Banking & Finance 68: 12–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  103. Glode, Vincent, and Christian C. Opp. 2020. Over-the-Counter versus Limit-Order Markets: The Role of Traders’ Expertise. The Review of Financial Studies 33: 866–915. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  104. Glosten, Lawrence R. 1994. Is the electronic open limit order book inevitable? The Journal of Finance 49: 1127–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  105. Glosten, Lawrence R., and Paul R. Milgrom. 1985. Bid, ask and transaction prices in a specialist market with heterogeneously informed traders. Journal of Financial Economics 14: 71–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  106. Goettler, Ronald L., Christine A. Parlour, and Uday Rajan. 2005. Equilibrium in a Dynamic Limit Order Market. The Journal of Finance 60: 2149–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  107. Goldstein, Michael A., Andriy V. Shkilko, Bonnie F. Van Ness, and Robert A. Van Ness. 2010. Inter-market competition for NYSE-listed securities under decimals. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 35: 371–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  108. Gomber, Peter, Satchit Sagade, Erik Theissen, Moritz Christian Weber, and Christian Westheide. 2017. Competition between Equity Markets: A Review of The Consolidation Versus Fragmentation Debate. Journal of Economic Surveys 31: 792–9814. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  109. Grammig, Joachim, Dirk Schiereck, and Erik Theissen. 2001. Knowing me, knowing you. Journal of Financial Markets 4: 385–412. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  110. Gresse, Carole. 2017. Effects of lit and dark market fragmentation on liquidity. Journal of Financial Markets 35: 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  111. Griffith, Todd G., and Brian S. Roseman. 2019. Making cents of tick sizes: The effect of the 2016 US SEC tick size pilot on limit order book liquidity. Journal of Banking & Finance 101: 104–21. [Google Scholar]
  112. Han, Bing, and Alok Kumar. 2013. Speculative retail trading and asset prices. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 48: 377–404. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  113. Harris, Larry. 2003. Trading and Exchanges: Market Microstructure for Practitioners. New York: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  114. Hasbrouck, Joel. 1991. Measuring the information content of stock trades. The Journal of Finance 46: 179–207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  115. Hasbrouck, Joel. 1995. One Security, Many Markets: Determining the Contributions to Price Discovery. The Journal of Finance 50: 1175–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  116. Hasbrouck, Joel, and Gideon Saar. 2009. Technology and liquidity provision: The blurring of traditional definitions. Journal of Financial Markets 12: 143–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  117. Hasbrouck, Joel, and Gideon Saar. 2013. Low-latency trading. Journal of Financial Markets 16: 646–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  118. Hasso, Tim, Daniel Müller, Matthias Pelster, and Sonja Warkulat. 2021. Who participated in the GameStop frenzy? Evidence from brokerage accounts. Finance Research Letters, 102140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  119. Hatheway, Frank, Amy Kwan, and Hui Zheng. 2017. An Empirical Analysis of Market Segmentation on U.S. Equity Markets. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 52: 2399–427. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  120. Hau, Harald. 2001. Location Matters: An Examination of Trading Profits. The Journal of Finance 56: 1959–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  121. He, William Peng, and Andrew Lepone. 2014. Determinants of liquidity and execution probability in exchange operated dark pool: Evidence from the Australian Securities Exchange. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 30: 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  122. He, Chen, Elizabeth Odders-White, and Mark J. Ready. 2006. The impact of preferencing on execution quality. Journal of Financial Markets 9: 246–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  123. He, William Peng, Elvis Jarnecic, and Yubo Liu. 2015. The determinants of alternative trading venue market share: Global evidence from the introduction of Chi-X. Journal of Financial Markets 22: 27–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  124. Hendershott, Terrence, and Charles M. Jones. 2005. Island Goes Dark: Transparency, Fragmentation, and Regulation. Review of Financial Studies 18: 743–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  125. Hendershott, Terrence, and Haim Mendelson. 2000. Crossing Networks and Dealer Markets: Competition and Performance. The Journal of Finance 55: 2071–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  126. Hendershott, Terrence, and Pamela C. Moulton. 2011. Automation, speed, and stock market quality: The NYSE’s Hybrid. Journal of Financial Markets 14: 568–604. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  127. Hendershott, Terrence, Charles M. Jones, and Albert J. Menkveld. 2011. Does Algorithmic Trading Improve Liquidity? The Journal of Finance 66: 1–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  128. Hu, Edwin, and Dermot Murphy. 2021. Vestigial Tails? Floor Brokers at the Close in Modern Electronic Markets. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3600230 (accessed on 23 August 2021).
  129. Huang, Wei, S. Ghon Rhee, and Ning Tang. 2010. Preferenced Trading, Quote Competition, and Market Quality: Evidence from Decimalization on the NYSE. Financial Review 45: 523–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  130. Indriawan, Ivan. 2020. Market quality around macroeconomic news announcements: Evidence from the Australian stock market. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 61: 101071. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  131. Jain, Pankaj K. 2005. Financial market design and the equity premium: Electronic versus floor trading. The Journal of Finance 60: 2955–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  132. Jain, Pankaj K., Christine Jiang, Thomas H. McInish, and Nareerat Taechapiroontong. 2003. Informed Trading in Parallel Auction and Dealer Markets: An Analysis on the London Stock Exchange. Manuscript: Indiana University. [Google Scholar]
  133. Jain, Pankaj K., Suchismita Mishra, Shawn O’Donoghue, and Le Zhao. 2021. Trading Volume Shares and Market Quality in a Zero Commission World. Available online: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3741470 (accessed on 23 August 2021).
  134. Jiang, Christine X., Thomas H. McInish, and James Upson. 2012. Market Fragmentation and Information Quality: The Role of TRF Trades. Available online: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1960115 (accessed on 23 August 2021).
  135. Jones, Charles M., and Marc L. Lipson. 2004. Are Retail Orders Different. New York: Columbia University, Athens: University of Georgia, Unpublished paper. [Google Scholar]
  136. Jørgensen, Kjell, Johannes Skjeltorp, and Bernt Arne Ødegaard. 2018. Throttling hyperactive robots – Order-to-trade ratios at the Oslo Stock Exchange. Journal of Financial Markets 37: 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  137. Jurich, Stephen N. 2021. Does off-exchange trading decrease in the presence of uncertainty? The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 81: 201–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  138. Kandel, Eugene, and Leslie M. Marx. 1999. Payments for Order Flow on Nasdaq. The Journal of Finance 54: 35–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  139. Kaniel, Ron, Gideon Saar, and Sheridan Titman. 2008. Individual Investor Trading and Stock Returns. The Journal of Finance 63: 273–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  140. Kaniel, Ron, Shuming Liu, Gideon Saar, and Sheridan Titman. 2012. Individual Investor Trading and Return Patterns around Earnings Announcements. The Journal of Finance 67: 639–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  141. Kavajecz, Kenneth A., and Elizabeth R. Odders-White. 2004. Technical Analysis and Liquidity Provision. Review of Financial Studies 17: 1043–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  142. Kelley, Eric K., and Paul C. Tetlock. 2013. How Wise Are Crowds? Insights from Retail Orders and Stock Returns. The Journal of Finance 68: 1229–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  143. Kim, Oliver, and Robert E. Verrecchia. 1994. Market liquidity and volume around earnings announcements. Journal of Accounting and Economics 17: 41–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  144. Kurov, Alexander, Alessio Sancetta, Georg Strasser, and Marketa Halova Wolfe. 2019. Price drift before US macroeconomic news: Private information about public announcements? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 54: 449–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  145. Kwan, Amy, Ronald Masulis, and Thomas H. McInish. 2015. Trading rules, competition for order flow and market fragmentation. Journal of Financial Economics 115: 330–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  146. Kyle, A. S. 1985. Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading. Econometrica 53: 1315. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  147. Kyle, Albert S., Anna A. Obizhaeva, and Yajun Wang. 2018. Smooth Trading with Overconfidence and Market Power. The Review of Economic Studies 85: 611–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  148. Lipson, Marc L. 2003. Competition among Market Centers. Available online: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=470882 (accessed on 23 August 2021).
  149. Macey, Jonathan R., and Maureen O’Hara. 1997. The law and economics of best execution. Journal of Financial Intermediation 6: 188–223. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  150. Madhavan, Ananth. 2000. Market microstructure: A survey. Journal of Financial Markets 3: 205–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  151. Madhavan, A. 2012. Exchange-Traded Funds, Market Structure, and the Flash Crash. Financial Analysts Journal 68: 20–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  152. Madhavan, Ananth, Matthew Richardson, and Mark Roomans. 1997. Why do security prices change? A transaction-level analysis of NYSE stocks. The Review of Financial Studies 10: 1035–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  153. Maglaras, Costis, Ciamac C. Moallemi, and Hua Zheng. 2015. Optimal Execution in a Limit Order Book and an Associated Microstructure Market Impact Model. Columbia Business School Research Paper No. 15-60. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2610808 (accessed on 23 August 2021).
  154. Malinova, Katya, and Andreas Park. 2015. Subsidizing Liquidity: The Impact of Make/Take Fees on Market Quality. The Journal of Finance 70: 509–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  155. McAleer, Michael. 2020. Prevention Is Better Than the Cure: Risk Management of COVID-19. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13: 46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  156. McAleer, Michael, Chia-Lin Chang, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2015. Informatics, data mining, econometrics and financial economics: A connection. Journal of Informatics and Data Mining 1: 1–5. [Google Scholar]
  157. McAleer, Michael, Chia-Lin Chang, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2016a. Behavioural, financial, and health & medical economics: A connection. Journal of Health & Medical Economics 2: 1–4. [Google Scholar]
  158. McAleer, Michael, Chia-Lin Chang, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2016b. Management science, economics and finance: A connection. International Journal of Economics and Management Sciences 5: 1–19. [Google Scholar]
  159. McAleer, Michael, John Suen, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2016c. Profiteering from the Dot-Com Bubble, Subprime Crisis and Asian Financial Crisis. The Japanese Economic Review 67: 257–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  160. McAleer, Michael, Chia-Lin Chang, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2017. Management information, decision sciences, and financial economics: A connection. Journal of Management Information and Decision Sciences 20: 1–33. [Google Scholar]
  161. McAleer, M., M.-U. Batmunkh, M. Moslehpour, and W.-K. Wong. 2018a. Confucius and Herding Behaviour in the Stock Markets in China and Taiwan. SSRN Electronic Journal. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  162. McAleer, Michael, Chia-Lin Chang, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2018b. Big Data, Computational Science, Economics, Finance, Marketing, Management, and Psychology: Connections. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 11: 15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  163. McAleer, Michael, David E. Allen, and Abhay K. Singh. 2019. Daily market news sentiment and stock prices. Applied Economics 51: 3212–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  164. McAleer, Michael, Kai-Yin Woo, and Wing-Keung Wong. 2020. Review on Efficiency and Anomalies in Stock Markets. Economies 8: 20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  165. Menkveld, Albert J. 2013. High frequency trading and the new market makers. Journal of Financial Markets 16: 712–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  166. Menkveld, Albert J. 2014. High-Frequency Traders and Market Structure. Financial Review 49: 333–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  167. Menkveld, Albert J. 2016. The economics of high-frequency trading: Taking stock. Annual Review of Financial Economics 8: 1–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  168. Menkveld, Albert J., Bart Zhou Yueshen, and Haoxiang Zhu. 2017. Shades of darkness: A pecking order of trading venues. Journal of Financial Economics 124: 503–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  169. Mishra, Suchismita, Vinh Huy Nguyen, and Le Zhao. 2021. Trading Venue Preference: Critical Role of Institutional Ownership. Miami: Florida International University, Unpublished manuscript. [Google Scholar]
  170. Neal, Robert. 1992. A comparison of transaction costs between competitive market maker and specialist market structures. Journal of Business 65: 317–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  171. Nguyen, Van T., Bonnie F. Van Ness, and Robert A. Van Ness. 2005. Archipelago’s move towards exchange status: An analysis of Archipelago trading in NYSE and NASDAQ stocks. Journal of Economics and Business 57: 541–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  172. Nguyen, Vanthuan, Bonnie F. Van Ness, and Robert R. Van Ness. 2007. Inter-market competition for exchange traded funds. Journal of Economics and Finance 31: 251–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  173. Nimalendran, Mahendrarajah, and Sugata Ray. 2014. Informational linkages between dark and lit trading venues. Journal of Financial Markets 17: 230–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  174. O’Hara, Maureen. 2004. Searching for a new center: US securities markets in transition. Economic Review 89: 37–52. [Google Scholar]
  175. O’Hara, Maureen. 2015. High frequency market microstructure. Journal of Financial Economics 116: 257–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  176. O’Hara, Maureen, and Mao Ye. 2011. Is market fragmentation harming market quality? Journal of Financial Economics 100: 459–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  177. Pagano, Marco, and Ailsa Röell. 1996. Transparency and liquidity: A comparison of auction and dealer markets with informed trading. The Journal of Finance 51: 579–611. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  178. Pagnotta, Emiliano S., and Thomas Philippon. 2018. Competing on Speed. Econometrica 86: 1067–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  179. Parlour, Christine A., and Uday Rajan. 2003. Payment for order flow. Journal of Financial Economics 68: 379–411. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  180. Parlour, Christine A., and Duane J. Seppi. 2003. Liquidity-Based Competition for Order Flow. Review of Financial Studies 16: 301–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  181. Patel, Jayendu, Richard Zeckhauser, and Darryll Hendricks. 1991. The Rationality Struggle: Illustrations from Financial Markets. The American Economic Review 81: 232–36. [Google Scholar]
  182. Peterson, Mark A., and Erik R. Sirri. 2003. Order Preferencing and Market Quality on U.S. Equity Exchanges. Review of Financial Studies 16: 385–415. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  183. Ready, Mark. 2014. Determinants of Volume in Dark Pool Crossing Networks. Unpublished working paper. University of Wisconsin-Madison. Available online: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1361234 (accessed on 4 December 2020).
  184. Rhee, S. Ghon, and Ning Tang. 2013. Can quote competition reduce preferenced trading? A reexamination of the SEC’s 1997 order handling rules. Accounting & Finance 53: 243–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  185. Röell, Ailsa. 1990. Dual-capacity trading and the quality of the market. Journal of Financial Intermediation 1: 105–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  186. Roşu, Ioanid. 2019. Fast and slow informed trading. Journal of Financial Markets 43: 1–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  187. SEC. 2018. Assessment of The Plan To Implement A Tick Size Pilot Program. US Securities and Exchange Commission. Available online: https://www.sec.gov/files/TICK%20PILOT%20ASSESSMENT%20FINAL%20Aug%202.pdf (accessed on 4 December 2020).
  188. SEC. 2021. Fast Answer: National Securities Exchanges. US Securities and Exchange Commission. Available online: https://www.sec.gov/fast-answers/divisionsmarketregmrexchangesshtml.html (accessed on 1 September 2021).
  189. Shkilko, Andriy, and Konstantin Sokolov. 2020. Every Cloud Has a Silver Lining: Fast Trading, Microwave Connectivity, and Trading Costs. The Journal of Finance 75: 2899–927. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  190. Shleifer, Andrei, and Lawrence H. Summers. 1990. The Noise Trader Approach to Finance. Journal of Economic Perspectives 4: 19–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  191. Spatt, Chester. 2018. The new realities of market structure and liquidity: Where have we been? Where are we going? In Public Policy & Financial Economics: Essays in Honor of Professor George G Kaufman for His Lifelong Contributions to the Profession. Singapore: World Scientific Publishing Co., pp. 247–63. [Google Scholar]
  192. Tang, Ning, Andriy Shkilko, and Gregory Stone. 2011. Quote Competitiveness, 100-share Quotes, and Decimalization. Financial Review 46: 89–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  193. Thomas, Jacob, Frank Zhang, and Wei Zhu. 2021. Dark Trading and Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift. Management Science. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  194. Üslü, Semih. 2019. Pricing and Liquidity in Decentralized Asset Markets. Econometrica 87: 2079–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  195. Van Kervel, Vincent. 2015. Competition for Order Flow with Fast and Slow Traders. The Review of Financial Studies 28: 2094–127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  196. Vayanos, Dimitri. 1999. Strategic Trading and Welfare in a Dynamic Market. Review of Economic Studies 66: 219–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  197. Venkataraman, Kumar. 2001. Automated Versus Floor Trading: An Analysis of Execution Costs on the Paris and New York Exchanges. The Journal of Finance 56: 1445–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  198. Vuorenmaa, Tommi. 2014. Lit and Dark Liquidity with Lost Time Data: Interlinked Trading Venues Around the Global Financial Crisis. New York: Springer. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  199. Wermers, Russ. 1999. Mutual fund herding and the impact on stock prices. The Journal of Finance 54: 581–622. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  200. Weston, James P. 2000. Competition on the Nasdaq and the impact of recent market reforms. The Journal of Finance 55: 2565–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  201. Wittwer, Milena. 2021. Connecting Disconnected Financial Markets? American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 13: 252–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  202. Ye, Mao. 2011. A Glimpse into the Dark: Price Formation, Transaction Cost and Market Share of the Crossing Network (9 June 2011). Available online: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1521494 (accessed on 1 September 2021).
  203. Ye, Mao, and Chen Yao. 2014. Tick Size Constraints, Market Structure, and Liquidity. WBS Finance Group Research Paper No. 212. Available online: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2359000 (accessed on 1 September 2021).
  204. Ye, Mao, and Wei Zhu. 2020. Strategic Informed Trading and Dark Pools. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3292516 (accessed on 1 September 2021).
  205. Yin, Xiangkang. 2005. A comparison of centralized and fragmented markets with costly search. The Journal of Finance 60: 1567–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  206. Zaharudin, Khairul Zharif, Martin R. Young, and Wei-Huei Hsu. 2021. High-frequency trading: Definition, implications, and controversies. Journal of Economic Surveys. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  207. Zhu, Haoxiang. 2014. Do Dark Pools Harm Price Discovery? The Review of Financial Studies 27: 747–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Change in trading volume in 2011 vs. 2021. This figure plots the average number of shares executed in the overall market per month in 2011 and 2021. The data was taken from the CBOE’s U.S. Equities Market Volume Summary (https://www.cboe.com/us/equities/market_share, accessed date: 20 August 2021).
Figure 1. Change in trading volume in 2011 vs. 2021. This figure plots the average number of shares executed in the overall market per month in 2011 and 2021. The data was taken from the CBOE’s U.S. Equities Market Volume Summary (https://www.cboe.com/us/equities/market_share, accessed date: 20 August 2021).
Jrfm 14 00556 g001
Figure 2. The average market share by venue in 2011 vs. 2021. This figure presents the changes in the market share by venue in 2011 (panel a) vs. 2021 (panel b). The market share is calculated as the volume executed on a particular market venue divided by the total volume on all venues. The volume data by the exchange is obtained from the CBOE’s U.S. Equities Market Volume Summary (https://www.cboe.com/us/equities/market_share, accessed date: 20 August 2021).
Figure 2. The average market share by venue in 2011 vs. 2021. This figure presents the changes in the market share by venue in 2011 (panel a) vs. 2021 (panel b). The market share is calculated as the volume executed on a particular market venue divided by the total volume on all venues. The volume data by the exchange is obtained from the CBOE’s U.S. Equities Market Volume Summary (https://www.cboe.com/us/equities/market_share, accessed date: 20 August 2021).
Jrfm 14 00556 g002
Figure 3. The U.S. Equity Market Structure.
Figure 3. The U.S. Equity Market Structure.
Jrfm 14 00556 g003
Table 1. Timeline of the evolution for U.S. equity national exchanges.
Table 1. Timeline of the evolution for U.S. equity national exchanges.
YearTimeline
1790Philadelphia Stock Exchange founded (PHLX)
1817New York Stock and Exchange Board (NYSE) was officially founded
1835Boston Stock Exchange (BEX) founded
1882San Francisco Stock Exchange founded
Chicago Stock Exchange (CHX) founded
1885Cincinnati Stock Exchange founded (renamed as National Stock Exchange in 2003)
1899Los Angeles Oil Exchange founded
1924The New York Curb Market created (renamed as New York Cub Exchange in 1929, and renamed as American Stock Exchange in 1953)
1956Pacific Coast Stock Exchange was created by the merge of San Francisco Stock Exchange and Los Angeles Oil Exchange (rename as Pacific Stock Exchange in 1973)
1971Nasdaq founded
1996Archipelago created
2005Bats Global Markets (BATS) founded
Archipelago purchased Pacific Stock Exchange (PCX)
2006Archipelago was acquired by NYSE and the exchange renamed as NYSE Arca
2007Boston Stock Exchange (BSE) was acquired by Nasdaq and renamed as Nasdaq OMX BX
Philadelphia Stock Exchange (PHLX) was acquired by Nasdaq and renamed as Nasdaq PHLX
2008American Stock Exchange (AMEX) was acquired by NYSE and renamed as NYSE American
BATS launched BZX exchange
2010Direct Edge launched EDGA and EDGX exchanges
BATS launched BYX Exchange
2014BATS merged with Direct Edge
2016Cboe acquired Bats Global Markets
Investors Exchange launched
2017National Stock Exchange (NSX) was acquired by NYSE and renamed as NYSE National
2018Chicago Stock Exchange (CHX) was acquired by NYSE and renamed as NYSE Chicago
2020Members Exchange (MEMX) launched
MIAX Peral’s Exchange (MIAX) launched
Long-term Stock Exchange (LTSE) launched
Table 2. U.S. national exchanges fee schedule.
Table 2. U.S. national exchanges fee schedule.
ExchangeFee ModelAdding LiquidityRemoving LiquidityNet Fee
NYSE AmericaMaker–Taker(0.0045)–0.00020.0002(0.0043)–0.0002
Bats EDGXMaker–Taker(0.0017)0.002650.00095
NYSE ChicagoMaker–Taker(0.002)0.0030.001
NYSEMaker–Taker(0–0.0029)0.00275–0.0030.00015–0.003
NYSE ArcaMaker–Taker(0.0015) Tape A0.0030.0015
(0.002) Tape C0.0030.001
NasdaqMaker–Taker(0–0.00305+)0.003<0.003
Bats BZXMaker–Taker(0.002) Tape A0.0030.001
(0.0025) Tape C0.0030.0005
Nasdaq OMX PSXMaker–Taker(0.0023)0.0030.0007
IEXFlat0.00030.00030.0006
Bats BYXTaker–Maker0.0019(0.0005)0.0014
Nasdaq OMX BXTaker–Maker0.00240.0003–(0.0027)(0.003)–0.0027
NYSE NationalTaker–Maker$0.001–$0.0028(0.0002–0.003)(0.002)–0.0026
Bats EDGATaker–Maker0.003(0.0024)0.0006
Note: 1. Tape A is NYSE-listed stocks. Tape C is NASDAQ-listed stocks; 2. ATS fees are individually negotiated between the ATS operator and the participant. This table presents all 13 U.S. national exchange fee schedules for per share price $1.00 or above at 8 January 2019. Rebate indicated by parentheses. For some exchanges, the fee and rebates vary based on the trading volume per order. Data are from each exchange’s respective website.
Table 3. Overview of studies on potential determinants of order routing decisions.
Table 3. Overview of studies on potential determinants of order routing decisions.
Determinants of Order Routing DecisionsTheorical StudiesEmpirical Tests
Execution CostTransaction FeeLimit order trading model with fixed or endogenized feeColliard and Foucault (2012)Cardella et al. (2017); Malinova and Park (2015);
Battalio et al. (2016b); Jørgensen et al. (2018);
Comerton-Forde et al. (2018); Clapham et al. (2021)
Limit order trading model with differentiating maker & taker feeFoucault et al. (2013)
Limit order trading model with fee exogenouslyCimon (2021)
Execution QualityInventory modelBiais (1993); De Frutos and Manzano (2002)Boehmer et al. (2007); Battalio et al. (2016a); Peterson and Sirri (2003); Thomas et al. (2021); Boehmer et al. (2005);
Garvey et al. (2016); Ernst et al. (2021); Thomas et al. (2021)
Single period strategic trade modelHe et al. (2006)
Dynamic modelPagano and Röell (1996); He et al. (2006); Degryse et al. (2009); Maglaras et al. (2015); Colliard and Foucault (2012)
Information RiskTwo-period strategic trade modelYe (2011)Grammig et al. (2001); Jain et al. (2003);
Jiang et al. (2012); Nimalendran and Ray (2014); Garvey et al. (2016); Hatheway et al. (2017)
Two-period sequential trade modelZhu (2014)
Limit order trading modelFoucault et al. (2007)
Trader TypeInformed vs. Uninformed TradersStrategic trade modelKyle (1985)Kavajecz and Odders-White (2004); Garvey and Wu (2011); Jones and Lipson (2004); Ready (2014); Chakravarty et al. (2012); Barber et al. (2008); Chevalier and Ellison (1999); Coval and Stafford (2007); Gao and Lin (2015); Han and Kumar (2013); O’Hara (2015); Boehmer et al. (2021); Jain et al. (2021)
Two-period strategic trade modelYe and Zhu (2020)
Fast vs. Slow TradersSearch and bargaining modelÜslü (2019)Brogaard et al. (2015); Hasbrouck and Saar (2013); Hendershott et al. (2011)
Sequential trade modelBiais et al. (2015)
Continuous limit order trading modelBudish et al. (2015); Baldauf and Mollner (2020)
Dynamic modelRoşu (2019)
Trader’s Behavior and StrategyLimit order trading modelParlour and Seppi (2003)Garvey et al. (2016)
Symmetric continuous limit order trading modelKyle et al. (2018)
Market Condition and Stock CharacteristicsMarket ConditionTwo-period sequential trade modelZhu (2014)Jiang et al. (2012); Vuorenmaa (2014); He et al. (2015); Barclay et al. (2003); Jurich (2021); Anselmi et al. (2021)
Stock CharacteristicsStrategic trade modelBaruch and Saar (2009)Harris (2003); Nguyen et al. (2005); He and Lepone (2014); Garvey et al. (2016)
Trading TechnologiesContinuous limit order trading modelBaldauf and Mollner (2020); Brolley and Cimon (2020)Hau (2001); Aitken et al. (2017); Brogaard et al. (2015); Frino et al. (2014)
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Mishra, S.; Zhao, L. Order Routing Decisions for a Fragmented Market: A Review. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2021, 14, 556. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14110556

AMA Style

Mishra S, Zhao L. Order Routing Decisions for a Fragmented Market: A Review. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2021; 14(11):556. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14110556

Chicago/Turabian Style

Mishra, Suchismita, and Le Zhao. 2021. "Order Routing Decisions for a Fragmented Market: A Review" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 14, no. 11: 556. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14110556

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop